Advertisement

The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics

, Volume 43, Issue 4, pp 491–504 | Cite as

Valuing Homeownership

  • Khalid SekkatEmail author
  • Ariane Szafarz
Article

Abstract

Housing tenure decision combines financial, economic and socio-psychological factors. This paper considers the global premium associated to homeownership. On the one hand, homeownership is associated to private benefits of being an owner. On the other hand, overinvestment in housing is harmful to diversification and distorts portfolio management. This trade-off, similar to the one associated to corporate private benefits of control, is the cornerstone of our theoretical model based on the expected utility maximization. The originality of the model comes from its simplicity. Furthermore, the empirical implementation of the model, using price and rent data normalized by square-meter, exhibits a homeownership premium for houses in the Brussels Region reaching at least 9% of the housing price. The findings are robust to several methodological refinements. In particular, they confirm the link between liquidity constraints and house prices documented in the literature. However, the premium may largely vary from one place to another, according to tax laws, cultural habits and social status associated to tenure.

Keywords

Homeownership Tenure choice Housing Real-estate 
JEL Classification R21 E21 G11 

Notes

Acknowledgments

The authors thank Carlos Garriga and anonymous referees for very useful comments.

References

  1. Aaronson, D. (2000). A Note on the Benefits of Homeownership. Journal of Urban Economics, 47(3), 356–369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Adam, M. C., & Szafarz, A. (1992). Speculative bubbles and financial markets. Oxford Economic Papers, 44(4), 626–640.Google Scholar
  3. Benito, A., & Mumtaz, H. (2009). Excess sensitivity, liquidity constraints and the collateral role of housing. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 13(3), 305–326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Brueckner, J. K. (1997). Consumption and investment motives and the portfolio choices of homeowners. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 15(2), 159–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Case, K. E., & Shiller, R. J. (1989). The efficiency of the market for single-family homes. American Economic Review, 79(1), 125–137.Google Scholar
  6. Chan, K. C., Hendershott, P. H., & Sanders, A. B. (2003). Risk and return on real estate: evidence from equity REITs. Real Estate Economics, 18(4), 431–452.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Chiuri, M. C., & Jappelli, T. (2003). Financial market imperfections and homeownership: a comparative study. European Economic Review, 47(5), 857–875.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Coulson, N. E. (1999). Why are Hispanic and Asian-American homeownership so low: immigration and other factors. Journal of Urban Economics, 45(2), 209–227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Dekeuleneer, M. (2005). Les indices UGEB-ULEB de l’évolution du marché immobilier de la Région bruxelloise. Revue UBG, 329, 22–48.Google Scholar
  10. Díaz, A., & Luengo-Prado, M. J. (2008). On the user cost and homeownership. Review of Economic Dynamics, 11(3), 584–613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Dupuis, A., & Thorns, D. C. (2002). Home, home ownership and the search for ontological security. Sociological Review, 46(1), 24–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Dyck, A., & Zingales, L. (2004). Private benefits of control: an international comparison. Journal of Finance, 59(2), 537–600.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Englund, P. (1985). Taxation of capital gains on owner-occupied homes: accrual vs realization. European Economic Review, 27(3), 311–334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Englund, P., Hwang, M., & Quigley, J. M. (2002). Hedging housing risk. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 24(1/2), 167–200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Flavin, M. (1985). Excess sensitivity of consumption to current income: liquidity constraints or myopia? The Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'Economique, 18(1), 117–136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Flavin, M., & Yamashita, S. (2002). Owner-occupied housing and the composition of the household portfolio. American Economic Review, 92(1), 345–362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  17. Garriga C., Gavin, W. T., & Schlagenhauf, D. (2006). Recent trends in homeownership. Review of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Sep, 397–412.Google Scholar
  18. Geltner, D. (1993). Estimating market values from appraised values without assuming an efficient market. Journal of Real Estate Research, 8(3), 325–45.Google Scholar
  19. Glaeser, E. L., Gyourko, J., & Saiz, A. (2008). Housing supply and housing bubbles. Journal of Urban Economics, 64(2), 198–217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Green, R. K., & White, M. J. (1997). Measuring the benefits of homeowning: effects on children. Journal of Urban Economics, 41(3), 441–461.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Goetzmann, W. (1993). The single family home in the investment portfolio. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 6(3), 201–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Goodman, A. C. (1978). Hedonic prices, price indices and housing markets. Journal of Urban Economics, 5, 471–484.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Grossman, S. J., & Laroque, G. (1990). Asset pricing and optimal portfolio choice in the presence of illiquid durable consumption goods. Econometrica, 58(1), 25–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Gyourko, J., & Keim, D. B. (2003). What does the stock market tell us about real estate returns? Real Estate Economics, 20(3), 457–485.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Haurin, D. R., Hendershott, P. H., & Wachter, S. M. (1996) Borrowing Constraints and the Tenure Choice of Young Households. NBER Working Paper No. W5630.Google Scholar
  26. Henderson, J. V., & Ioannides, Y. M. (1983). A model of housing tenure choice. American Economic Review, 73(1), 98–113.Google Scholar
  27. Hennessey, S. M. (2003). The impact of housing choice on future household wealth. Financial Services Review, 12(2), 143–164.Google Scholar
  28. Iacoviello, M. (2004). Consumption, house prices and collateral constraints: a structural econometric analysis. Journal of Housing Economics, 13(4), 305–321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  29. Linneman, P. (1985). An economic analysis of homeownership decision. Journal of Urban Economics, 17(2), 230–246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Linneman, P., Megbolugbe, I. F., Wachter, S. M., & Cho, M. (1997). Do borrowing constraints change U.S. homeownership rates? Journal of Housing Economics, 6(4), 318–333.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Megbolugbe, I. F., & Cho, M. (1996). Racial and ethnic differences in housing demand: an econometric investigation. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 12(3), 295–318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Raponi, M., & Sak, B. (2002). Housing statistics in the European Union: 2002. Walloon Region of Belgium, http://mrw.wallonie.be/dgatlp/HousingStats. Accessed 30 March 2009.
  33. Ross, S. A., & Zisler, R. C. (1991). Risk and return in real estate. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 4(2), 175–190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Shelton, J. P. (1968). The cost of renting versus owning a home. Land Economics, 44(1), 59–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Sinai, T., & Souleles, N. S. (2005). Owner-occupied housing as a hedge against rent risk. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 763–789.Google Scholar
  36. Weiss, Y. (1978). Capital gains, discriminatory taxes, and the choice between renting and owning a house. Journal of Public Economics, 10(1), 45–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2009

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.Solvay Brussels School of Economics and Management (SBS-EM), DulbeaUniversité Libre de Bruxelles (ULB)BrusselsBelgium
  2. 2.Solvay Brussels School of Economics and Management (SBS-EM), Centre Emile BernheimUniversité Libre de Bruxelles (ULB)BrusselsBelgium

Personalised recommendations