1 Introduction

Agency theory suggests that boards design efficient compensation schemes to provide chief executive officers (CEOs) with incentives to maximize shareholder value (Murphy, 1999; Core et al. 2002). In a traditional optimal contracting framework, shareholders should not compensate CEOs for firm performance driven by exogenous factors (luck) (Holmström, 1979). However, several papers show evidence of pay for luck, that is, pay that is due to observable lucky events, such as industry or market performance, and not under the CEO’s control (Bertrand and Mullainathan 1998, 2001; Bebchuk and Fried 2003; Garvey and Milbourn 2006; Bizjak et al. 2008). More recent agency models suggest that pay for luck can be optimal if the principal wants to incentivize the agent to forecast or respond to lucky events on the basis of her or his informational advantages (Axelson & Baliga, 2008; Göx, 2008; Noe & Rebello, 2011) or to reinforce effort incentives (Chaigneau et al. 2014). In these models, pay for luck can be interpreted as the CEO being rewarded for his or her response to a lucky event (which we refer to as pay for action).Footnote 1 Empirical studies have not distinguished between pay for luck from pay for responses to luck. In this paper, we propose a new setting that enables us to make this distinction and study the sensitivity of CEO compensation to responses to luck.Footnote 2

We use the variation in the value of firm’s real estate as well as CEO’s actions in response to this variation to identify pay for luck versus pay for action. In the absence of financial frictions, actions related to real estate assets (buying or selling) are value neutral for firms since all transactions are made at fair value and therefore have zero net present value (NPV). However, when firms are financially constrained, these transactions can be NPV positive, and firms may be expected to respond to the favorable real estate market conditions to alleviate these constraints (Chaney et al. 2012; Cvijanović, 2014).

We estimate the sensitivity of CEO pay to lucky events and responses to these events. Building on the identification strategy used in the collateral channel literature (Balakrishnan et al. 2014), we compare how changes to real estate prices impact CEO pay for firms that have different amounts of real estate assets on their balance sheets in 1992. We measure exposure to real estate price changes prior to our estimation period to alleviate concerns that exposure is endogenously chosen by the manager. Our empirical models include CEO-firm fixed effects to deal with the endogeneity of CEO-firm matching and omitted variables at the firm, CEO, and CEO-firm levels, which implies that time-invariant characteristics of the firm or the manager, such as talent, are unlikely to drive our results. Consistent with the empirical literature, we find that CEOs are rewarded for luck. The magnitude of the effect is economically significant: the sensitivity of CEO pay to real estate luck suggests that a one standard deviation change in the value of firm real estate is associated with an increase in CEO compensation of $57,052, evaluated at the mean.

We proceed to estimate the sensitivity of CEO compensation to actions, focusing on three specific responses to real estate luck: sales of real estate assets, debt issuance, and sale-and-leaseback (SLB) transactions. We also use changes in accounting returns to comprehensively capture any action the CEO might have taken in response to changes in real estate prices. We exploit the fact that, under US accounting principles (GAAP), real estate asset values are not marked-to-market to identify CEO responses in a firm’s financial statements. In response to changes in the value of firms’ real estate holdings, one should expect to observe changes in firm accounting performance only if the CEO takes action.Footnote 3 Using this procedure, we capture the sensitivity of pay to action by testing the sensitivity of pay to changes in accounting returns associated with changes in real estate prices.

Controlling for peer effects (Albuquerque et al. 2013; Bizjak et al. 2008), we find that the sensitivity of CEO compensation to responses to real estate price changes is positive and significant, which suggests that CEOs are rewarded for these responses. The economic magnitude of these rewards is relevant: for instance, a one standard deviation increase in real estate value induced change in return on assets (ROA) is associated with an increase of $32,733 in total CEO compensation. After considering CEOs’ responses to real estate value changes, our estimates of pay for luck remain overall economically and statistically significant. Note that, in cases when the optimal response of the manager to changes in real estate value is “no action,” say, not selling a property, the “no action” response to luck is still embedded in the estimate of pay for luck. For this reason, our measure is conservative in capturing actions associated with real estate value changes.Footnote 4

Next we investigate whether the responses to luck are valuable for shareholders. Shareholders are expected to reward a CEO for responding to a lucky event when that action increases shareholder value (Murphy, 1999; Core et al. 2002). Even though it is arguably difficult to evaluate and directly test whether actions are optimal, because we cannot observe the counterfactual in our setting, we can still evaluate whether, on average, common responses to real estate luck add value for shareholders. To do this, we explore cross-sectional variation in firms’ financing constraints and the quality of their corporate governance. The rationale is that most actions taken as a response to real estate luck, such as debt issuance using real estate as collateral, are more valuable for financially constrained firms. We find that rewarding CEOs for responses to real estate luck is more pronounced for financially constrained firms and for well-governed ones, suggesting that these firms incentivize their CEOs to respond to lucky real estate events or compensate them ex post for their actions. We also run an event study on SLB transactions. We find that these transactions are associated with significant positive cumulative abnormal returns (CARs) around the announcement date, suggesting that these CEO actions are value increasing. Taken together, these results suggest that these actions create value for shareholders.

To address the concern that real estate prices are correlated with an unobserved variable not under the CEO’s control but correlated with CEO compensation (e.g., aggregate demand), we use the inelasticity of land supply as an exogenous regressor for real estate prices. To mitigate measurement error related to real estate holdings outside the headquarters’ location, which we use to capture real estate value changes, we use data on a firm’s location-specific real estate holdings from García and Norli (2012). This test also addresses the concern that exposure to real estate markets is time-invariant in our baseline analysis by creating a time-varying measure from 1994 onward. Our results remain unchanged. In addition, we propensity-score match our treatment and control observations, based on industry and real estate exposure in 1992, and use the Bertrand and Mullainathan (2001) approach to estimate pay for luck and pay for actions. These two different approaches provide consistent empirical results. Overall, our results are robust with respect to alternative methodologies and measurement concerns. Lastly, we explore how our results vary with types of real estate news. We find that our results are mostly driven by good real estate luck and large real estate price changes. Taken together, the totality of evidence suggests that managers are compensated for responding to real estate luck.

We build on the work of Gopalan et al. (2010), who show, in the context of sector performance, that managerial decisions relate to sector-performance luck. We also contribute to the debate between the managerial-power and competitive-market views of CEO compensation (Murphy, 1999; Core et al. 2002). Pay for luck is typically used as an argument in favor of the managerial-power hypothesis, as it occurs mostly in weakly governed firms (Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2001; Chhaochharia & Grinstein, 2009; Garvey & Milbourn, 2006; Bebchuk et al. 2010). Our paper is one of the first to show that CEOs are rewarded for taking value-enhancing actions in response to luck.

The fact that real estate assets are not marked-to-market provides some assurance that a change in accounting returns associated with a change in the value of real estate only occurs if the manager acts. We rely on the assumption that, in the context of real estate assets, accounting returns can be informative about managerial actions beyond market returns. Absent frictions, market returns are fully informative about managerial action as well as any information contained in accounting returns. However, in a setting such as the one proposed by Axelson and Baliga (2008), where managers can have an informational advantage, this is not necessarily the case. In our setup, all managers observe the same public signal (an aggregate real estate market change) but are assumed to interpret that signal differently and respond accordingly. Because the manager can choose whether and how to respond, contracts are expected to incentivize optimal responses. We propose that earnings-based performance measures better capture the individual response of the manager to these lucky events, which is consistent with the notion that accounting returns and market returns are not perfect substitutes and that the former may, in some cases, offer a better signal-to-noise ratio (Sloan, 1993) to capture actions. Interestingly, we find that most evidence of pay for luck is observed through equity compensation, while evidence of pay for action is mostly observed in cash compensation, which tends to be more linked to accounting measures of performance.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we provide the theoretical and institutional background to our analysis. In Section 3, we explain the data and methodology and, in Section 4, discuss the main findings. In Section 5, we address robustness tests and, in Section 6, we conclude.

2 Theoretical and institutional background

2.1 Theoretical background

Given the extensive empirical evidence on pay for luck (Bertrand & Mullainathan, 2001; Garvey & Milbourn, 2006), a number of studies offer a rationale for this phenomenon. Several studies propose pay for luck as an incentive, for instance, for effort to generate informative signals about the market. Axelson and Baliga (2008) argue that, when managers receive private signals about industry or market performance, it is optimal to pay them for exogenous performance, so that they act on the private signal in a way to maximize firm value. Gopalan et al. (2010) similarly argue that pay for industry performance is optimal when the principal wants to incentivize an optimal exposure to sector movements and this exposure is under the CEO control. Empirically, they find that pay for industry performance is mostly found in firms in which the CEO has greater strategic flexibility with respect to sector exposure.

Our paper supports the theory of Gopalan et al. (2010) by showing that pay for luck might be optimal when the board wants to provide incentives for an optimal response to a lucky event that is presumably under the CEO’s control, as evidenced, for example, by SLB transactions or sales of real estate. Evidence of pay for luck can also be rationalized by the CEO being compensated for responding optimally to a lucky event, assuming the response is observable to the board. We explicitly identify these responses and test whether managers are paid for responding to changes in the real estate market conditions.

Similar to Axelson and Baliga (2008), in our setup, all managers observe a public signal (aggregate real estate price changes); however, managers have different private interpretations of the same public signal. Depending on the managers’ private interpretation, they then choose whether to respond to a (positive) exogenous (real estate) event in such a way as to improve the firm’s performance. This is consistent with the argument of Axelson and Baliga (2008): contracts should tie compensation not only to measures that relate to pure effort but also to those about which the manager is likely to have better information than the market. This is precisely the case in our setting: because the manager can choose whether and how to respond to the exogenous events, contracts should incentivize optimal responses.Footnote 5

2.2 Institutional background

2.2.1 Accounting treatment of long-lived assets under US GAAP

Real estate assets are typically recognized on the balance sheet as property, plant, and equipment, at acquisition cost, and depreciated systematically. Changes to the value of firm real estate are reflected in its market and accounting performance in different ways. When the value of a firm’s real estate changes as a result of an increase in real estate prices, this change in firm value should be reflected in its market capitalization (and therefore in its stock market performance) immediately, assuming markets are efficient. However, according to US GAAP, the exact same change should not be reflected in the firm’s accounting performance. Based on the historical-cost principle, under GAAP, long-lived assets (such as real estate) are recorded on the balance sheet at historical cost, even if their values have significantly increased over time. Historical cost is a measure of value in which the price of an asset on the balance sheet is based on its nominal or original cost when acquired by the company. Given that the value of a firm’s real estate is not marked-to-market, any changes to the firm’s accounting performance due to a real estate value change must come from a firm (or its CEO) reacting to that change in some way: for instance, selling the real estate and realizing a capital gain (or loss). The US GAAP historical-cost principle thus provides a setting that allows us to estimate the sensitivity of CEO pay to responses to luck, because accounting performance is unaffected by real estate value changes, unless the CEO acts.Footnote 6

2.2.2 Reactions to events that are not under CEO control

Following an increase in the value of the firm’s real estate holdings, the CEO can respond in several ways. As an example, the CEO can sell the real estate assets and relocate. Alternatively, the CEO can sell the real estate assets and lease them back (to perform an SLB) or change the financing policy of the firm by issuing more debt while exploiting the increase in collateral value. In this section, we discuss the institutional details behind SLBs, as the process of issuing debt following an increase in real estate values is well understood in the collateral channel literature (Chaney et al. 2012; Cvijanović, 2014).

As argued by Whitby (2013), the choice to enter into an SLB is an example of an instance where the manager decides to change the way the firm finances its assets. In an SLB, an asset is sold to a third party at a gain, usually a real estate investment trust (REIT), and then simultaneously leased back with little or no impact to the daily operations of the firm and the use of that asset. For an SLB under ASC 840 the accounting treatment requires that the amount of the gain recorded at the time of the sale depends on the significance of the lease in comparison to the fair value of the property.Footnote 7

Most corporate SLBs involve real estate (Whitby, 2013). Ben-David (2005) reports that the most common assets involved in SLB transactions in his sample were the company’s headquarters, followed by retail locations. As he shows, the top two declared motives for entering into an SLB are to use the cash proceeds to reduce debt and for expansion.

As anecdotal evidence, Sotheby’s announced in a press release in 2002 that it had entered into an SLB deal involving its New York headquarters. The CEO, Bill Ruprecht, was clear about the motivation: “This is an outstanding opportunity for Sotheby’s. ... The attractive price of $175 million reflects the high asset quality, desirable location and Sotheby’s bright future prospects. Sotheby’s ... decided to enter into an SLB transaction as a means of financing to provide long-term liquidity for our business. It will also allow Sotheby’s to pay down $100 million in short-term debt. ...”

Studies show that corporate real estate SLBs add value to shareholders (see, for instance, Slovin et al. (1990), and Rutherford (1990) and, for more recent evidence, Ben-David (2005) and Whitby (2013)). In addition, shareholder activists often push firms to monetize the increase in value of their real estate by entering into SLBs, which allow firms to generate cash for stock buybacks, dividends, investments in valuable projects, or debt repayment. Additional evidence that SLBs can be value increasing for firms is the fact that compensation committees explicitly mention their completion when evaluating CEOs’ performance.

To assess whether CEOs are rewarded for pursuing SLBs, we parsed all DEF 14A filings (proxy statements) obtained from the SEC website for our sample firms. We devised an algorithm to classify a firm-year observation as mentioning an SLB if, in the company’s proxy statement, we found the word “leaseback.” This resulted in a sample of 1,167 firm-year observations. Given that firms are expected to enter into SLBs following increases in real estate value, this means that about 38% of the firm-year observations with an yearly change in real estate prices in the top quartile (good real estate luck) in our sample mention an SLB in their proxy statements. We then read the proxy statements to confirm that CEO compensation was associated with an SLB. We found that, for 113 firm-year observations, SLBs were mentioned when discussing CEO performance and, for 13 firm-year observations, the fact that the CEO was being compensated for such a transaction was mentioned. (See Appendix B for examples.) Similar to the findings of Ben-David (2005), the most often cited reason mentioned by firms in our sample for doing an SLB was the use of cash proceeds to repay debt.Footnote 8

3 Data and methodology

Many studies analyzed whether CEOs are rewarded for luck. The standard approach by Bertrand and Mullainathan (2001) consists of estimating the sensitivity of CEO compensation to changes in firm performance driven by luck, using exogenous determinants of firm performance, such as oil prices or exchange rates. However, when estimating the sensitivity of compensation to luck in this framework, one cannot disentangle the sensitivity of pay to luck from the sensitivity of pay to responses to luck (actions) because the luck and responses are empirically indistinguishable.

The accounting treatment of real estate assets described in Section 2.2.1 allows us to distinguish luck from responses to it: given that any changes to the value of a firm’s real estate should only be reflected in the firm’s financial statements if there was an action in response to the change. Thus we can identify the sensitivity of CEO pay to luck (measured by the change in the market value of its real estate assets) as well as the sensitivity of pay to reactions to luck (measured by the changes in accounting outcomes).

3.1 Data

Our initial sample consists of a CEO-firm year panel of Standard and Poor’s (S&P) 1,500 firms drawn from the Execucomp database, from 1992-2016. We then match this sample to the CRSP and Compustat databases to obtain stock returns and accounting data and to the Federal Housing Finance Association’s (FHFA) database of CBSA-level house price data. We exclude firms in the finance, insurance, real estate, construction, and mining industries as well as those involved in a major takeover operation, following the literature (Chaney et al. 2012). By excluding these firms, we ensure real estate assets are not marked-to-market, which is key to our identification. Our SLB data corresponds to the data in Whitby (2013).

A key construct in our research design is the effect of changes in real estate prices on the value of a firm’s real estate holdings. To construct this variable, we first measure the market value of a firm’s real estate assets. There are three major categories of property, plant, and equipment included in the definition of real estate assets: buildings, land and improvement, and construction in progress. To arrive at the measure of a firm’s real estate assets, we follow two steps. In Step 1, we measure a firm’s owned real estate assets in 1992 as the total net book value of property, plant, and equipment (Compustat variable PPENT) less the net book value of leased assets (Compustat PPENLS), less the net book value of equipment and machinery (Compustat PPENME), thus yielding the total net book value of a firm’s land and improvements, buildings, and construction in progress. Under US GAAP, these items represent the respective capitalized values, less accumulated depreciation. Net book value of property, plant and equipment (Compustat variable PPENT) excludes land and property held for sale. We replace missing observations with zeros. This variable is scaled by total assets to obtain the portion of the firm’s assets related to its real estate holdings, as measured in 1992. In Section 5.1, we explicitly follow Chaney et al. (2012) and Balakrishnan et al. (2014) to construct a more precise measure of the firm’s real estate holdings that accounts for the acquisition year and discuss the trade-offs we consider.

In Step 2 and following Balakrishnan et al. (2014), we use real estate price indices to estimate the market value of real estate assets in 1992 and then track the change in the market value of these assets over the sample period as a function of changes in real estate prices. We obtain the house price data from the Federal Housing Finance Association (FHFA). These data are calculated at the level of a core-based statistical area (CBSA).Footnote 9 The data contains a quarterly CBSA-level house-price index for 369 CBSAs from 1986 to 2016. The choice to use residential prices, instead of commercial real estate prices, is driven by the lack of availability of reliable commercial real estate data at MSA level for the period in question. Most publicly available sources report state prices indexes for offices, excluding other types of commercial real estate.

We estimate the market value of real estate assets in 1992 as the book value of real estate assets in 1992 from Step 1 multiplied by the value of the MSA real estate price index of the firm’s headquarters.Footnote 10 We then estimate the market value of real estate assets in each subsequent year as the market value of a firm’s real estate assets in 1992 multiplied by the cumulative real estate price increase from 1992 to a given year. The CEO-firm year data is merged to the house price data by linking each firm’s headquarters zip code (from Compustat) with its particular CBSA using data from US Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD) database. HUD provides HUD-USPS crosswalk files, which allocate zip codes to CBSAs.

We use ExecuComp to obtain or calculate the following variables used in our analysis: cash compensation, equity compensation, total compensation, tenure, and age. Our primary dependent variable is total pay, which consists of salary, bonus, non-equity incentive payout, value of restricted stock granted, value of options granted, and other compensation (ExecuComp item TDC1). In our regressions, we control for firm size using the logarithm of firm total assets, firm growth opportunities using Tobin’s Q, accounting profitability using ROA and stock return, and stock price volatility. Following Bertrand and Mullainathan (2001), we also control for CEO age and CEO age squared. Finally, we obtain blockholder data from Thomson Reuters.

The final dataset includes 14,838 CEO-firm year observations from 1992–2016. All variables are winsorized at the first and 99th percentile values. Appendix A provides variable definitions and data sources.

3.2 Methodology

3.2.1 Pay for luck

In the spirit of the literature (Aggarwal & Samwick, 1999; Bertrand & Mullainathan, 2001; Garvey & Milbourn, 2006; Chhaochharia & Grinstein, 2009), we start by testing whether CEOs are compensated for lucky events, as proxied by changes in real estate values. We estimate the following baseline specification.

$$ \log({TotalComp}_{c,i,t}) = \alpha + \beta_{1}{RE\_Value}_{i,t} + \beta_{2}{HPI}_{m,t-1} +{\sum}_{x}\beta_{X} X_{i,t} + \gamma_{i,c} + \delta_{j,t} + \varepsilon_{c,i,t}, $$
(1)

where TotalCompc,i,t is total CEO compensation of CEO c in firm i at time t. RE_V aluei,t is the market value of real estate in 1992 multiplied by the MSA-level real estate price index from 1992 to year t:

$$ {RE\_Value}_{i,t} = ({RE\_Value}_{i,1992} \mathrm{x} {HPI}_{m,t}). $$
(2)

Following Chaney et al. (2012) and Balakrishnan et al. (2014), we measure the value of a firm’s real estate in 1992, RE_V aluei,1992, prior to our estimation sample, thus excluding any acquisitions or dispositions in subsequent years. An advantage of this approach is that it mitigates potential endogeneity concerns in that the variation in market value of a firm’s real estate is driven solely by changes in real estate prices (which are outside the manager’s control) and not by firm’s investments (which are under the manager’s control). A disadvantage of this approach is that it creates a potential measurement bias, since the value of a firm’s real estate in any given year will not be precisely estimated. We address this issue and use a time-varying exposure measure in Section 5.2.Footnote 11

The variable RE_V aluei,t has two sources of variation, given that firms had different exposure to real estate market fluctuations in 1992, as indicated by different amounts of real estate assets in that year. The first source is cross-sectional variation stemming from the initial value of real estate assets in 1992. The second source is driven by time-series variation in the market value of these assets due to time-variation in real estate prices. Our identification uses this source of variation to capture events that are outside of the CEO’s control. Since real estate prices are not under managerial control, RE_V aluei,t in Eq. 1 thus represents the firm-specific luck measure.Footnote 12

To control for changes in real estate prices in an MSA where the firm is located, we include HPIm,t− 1 in Eq. 1. This variable also serves as a control for MSA-level economic conditions, which might be driving our variable of interest. Xi,t are firm and CEO-specific controls, such as ROA, total assets, market-to-book of assets ratio, stock return volatility, stock return, CEO age, and CEO age squared. Following prior studies (Faulkender and Yang, 2010), we also control for lagged performance metrics: ROA and stock returns.

To address a potential concern that there is matching between a firm’s real estate exposure and CEO type or between its location and CEO type that might be driving our results, we include firm-CEO fixed effects, γi,c, as noted above. In this way, our main source of variation comes from tracking the same CEO-firm pair over time. In addition, the inclusion of firm-CEO fixed effects controls for time-invariant unobservable characteristics of the CEO, such as talent or risk preferences, that have been shown to explain much of the variation in CEO compensation (Graham et al. 2012).

As noted by Albuquerque et al. (2013), Bizjak et al. (2008), and Cadman and Carter (2013), boards tend to structure CEO compensation contracts based on peer CEO (firm) compensation. The inclusion of industry-year fixed effects, δj,t, serves as a control for peer effects: thus β1 captures the general sensitivity of pay to (real estate) luck, relative to other CEO-firm pairs that operate in the same industry.Footnote 13 By including industry-year fixed effects δj,t, we also implicitly control for macroeconomic conditions that vary across industry and time. Note that, since our model includes firm-CEO fixed effects, this gives the coefficients a changes interpretation. The coefficient of interest is β1, which captures the sensitivity of CEO pay to (real estate) luck for a given firm-CEO pair over time, controlling for time-varying industry-specific characteristics that might be driving our results.Footnote 14

Without the appropriate cross-sectional and inter-temporal fixed effects (e.g., firm and year effects), the correlation between CEO pay and real estate values could simply be driven by industry or time series variation. For example, tests without these controls would compare relatively lower pay for executives in the utilities industry away from the coasts, where real estate prices are low, with relatively higher pay for executives in the technology industry in Northern California, where real estate prices are high. Further, CEO compensation and real estate prices increase through time. This would deliver a positive correlation between the two, but we cannot interpret that correlation as pay for luck. At the same time, finding a negative correlation between compensation and market value of real estate would not be incompatible with CEOs being paid more when real estate prices increase (pay for luck) or CEOs being paid more when they respond to luck, as this correlation could be driven by variation across firms and not within the firm.

3.2.2 Pay for action

As described in Section 2.2.1, given that any changes to the value of a firm’s real estate are reflected in its financial statements only if there is an action in response to the change, we can disentangle the sensitivity of CEO pay to luck (measured by the change in market value of its real estate assets) from the sensitivity of pay to reactions to luck. Given that the value of a firm’s real estate assets is not marked-to-market in financial statements, any changes to the firm’s accounting performance associated with a change in real estate value must come from a firm (or its CEO) responding to that change in some way: for instance, the CEO buys or sells real estate and realizes a gain (or a loss) for the firm. This motivates the following specification.

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \log({TotalComp}_{c,i,t}) &=& \alpha + \beta_{1}{RE\_Value}_{i,t} + \beta_{2}{RE\_Value}_{i,t} x {Action}_{i,t} \\ && + \beta_{3}{Action}_{i,t} + \beta_{4}{HPI}_{m,t-1} \\ && + \sum\limits_{x}\beta_{X} X_{i,t} + \gamma_{i,c} + \delta_{j,t} + \varepsilon_{c,i,t}, \end{array} $$
(3)

where Actioni,t is one of our four proxies for responses to luck: return on assets (ROA), real estate sales, debt issuance, and SLB transactions. The coefficient of interest is β2, which captures the sensitivity of CEO pay to reactions to real estate luck, as proxied by the interaction of one of the action measures (Actioni,t) with firm-specific real estate luck (RE_V aluei,t). As in Eq. 1, we include a vector of time-varying firm- and CEO-specific controls. The inclusion of time-varying industry-specific characteristics δj,t ensures that we are comparing the CEO pay sensitivity to responses to luck, relative to other CEO-firm pairs that operate in the same industry and year. As above, we also include firm-CEO fixed effects, γi,c.

Following Chaney et al. (2012) and Balakrishnan et al. (2014), we cluster standard errors at the MSA and year level. Our clustering is appropriate because executive pay levels and real estate values are likely (serially) correlated within an MSA (Bertrand et al. 2004). Clustering the standard errors addresses the concern that the error term is correlated within groups. Because we use two-way clustering (MSA and year), our inferences are robust to the possibility of correlation in the error term within MSAs over time and within each year across MSAs.

Note that real estate price changes could proxy for changes in growth opportunities. If a company’s real estate ownership decision is correlated with its expected growth opportunities, the estimated sensitivity of CEO pay to real estate prices will be biased upward. To address this, we conduct a series of tests. First, we exclude from our estimation sample firms that operate in real estate and construction industries. Second, we include controls for future growth opportunities in our baseline estimation: Tobin’s q, MSA-level real estate prices, and year fixed effects. Further, in Section 5.4, we explicitly control for a firm’s decision to own real estate.

3.2.3 Measures of responses to real estate luck

We use four alternative proxies to capture managerial responses (or actions) to real estate luck (Actioni,t). We measure our first proxy, real estate asset sales (RE_Sales), based on RE_Change, which is calculated using the difference in the balance sheet value of a firm’s real estate assets between year t and year t − 1 plus depreciation, scaled by lagged total assets:

$$ {RE\_Change} = ({RE\_Assets}_{t} - {RE\_Assets}_{t-1} + Depreciation Expense_{t}) / {TotalAssets}_{t-1}, $$

where RE_Assets is the sum of the balance sheet values for buildings, land and improvement, and construction in progress net of accumulated depreciation (RE_Assets = (PPENT - PPENLS - PPENME)). We add back depreciation to ensure that decreases in net real estate assets do not capture instances where depreciation expense exceeds capital expenditures. Variable RE_Sales then takes RE_Change and assumes either a value of zero (when RE_Change > 0) or the assumed value of the real estate sale (absolute value of RE_Change if negative). Because this is a conservative measure of real estate sales, as depreciation expense also includes depreciation for nonreal-estate assets, we also rely on the value of Compustat variable SPPE “Sale of Property” scaled by lagged total assets to measure sales when RE_Sales = 0.Footnote 15

We calculate our second proxy, long term debt issues (LT_Debt_Issues), as the change in long-term debt (Compustat item DLTIS), scaled by lagged total assets. Cvijanović (2014) shows that there is a spillover effect of real estate markets on firm investment through the value of the firm’s collateral, which influences its debt capacity. Issuing new debt is therefore a possible response of the CEO to a positive real estate shock. In our tests, we focus on long-term net debt issuance, since changes in firm collateral values are more likely to affect long-term borrowing secured by real estate assets.

Our third proxy is a sale and leaseback (SLB) transaction, which is another possible response to real estate shocks. Using data from Whitby (2013), which covers the period of 1992 to 2011, we identify firms that used an SLB in a particular year. We construct an indicator variable SLB that takes the value of one if a firm used an SLB in a particular year and zero otherwise.

Finally, we perform an additional test that examines changes in accounting performance of the firm, our fourth proxy, as measured by its ROA, in a catchall approach that can include gains from sales of real estate or a decrease in interest expense.Footnote 16ROA is defined as net income divided by total assets. We use net income to ensure we capture any type of action that the manager might have taken in response to real estate value changes. Since changes in value of a firm’s real estate assets are not marked-to-market, we should only observe changes in its ROA associated with real estate changes if a CEO responds to the real estate luck. All continuous variables are winsorized at the first and 99th percentiles, and their detailed descriptions are provided in Appendix A.

4 Results

4.1 Descriptive statistics

Table 1 reports summary statistics for CEO compensation, firm characteristics, and real estate market variables. The average CEO in this sample has a total compensation of $5.3 million. The average cash component is $2.2 million, while the average equity component is $3.1 million. These numbers comport with the literature on CEO compensation using similar data (Chhaochharia and Grinstein, 2009; Fahlenbrach, 2008; Gopalan et al. 2010). The average real estate holdings as a percentage of assets is 30.4%.

Table 1 Descriptive statistics

4.2 Pay for luck

Table 2 Panel A presents our initial test of the effect of real estate value changes on CEO pay. The independent variable of interest is the market value of real estate assets RE_V alue, as defined in Eq. 2. The baseline specification includes CEO-firm fixed effects, which means that identification is achieved through within firm-CEO variation. Thus the variation in the variable of interest results from changes in the market value of the real estate assets over time for the same firm-CEO pair. The estimated coefficient is 0.065 in Column 1 and 0.028 in Column 2. This suggests that, for a one standard deviation change in the value of a firm’s real estate holdings, CEO compensation increases by between approximately $132,443 and $57,052, evaluated at the mean.Footnote 17 In Column 2, we estimate pay for luck in a specification that includes industry-year fixed effects.Footnote 18 The coefficients reported are obtained using heteroscedasticity-adjusted standard errors, which are double clustered at the MSA and year levels (Balakrishnan et al. 2014).Footnote 19

Table 2 Pay for luck - total compensation

4.3 Pay for action or responses to luck

In Table 3, we test whether CEO compensation is correlated with specific responses to changes in real estate asset value (luck). In Column 1, the coefficient of interest is the interaction between ROA and real estate value: RE_V alue x ROA. The estimated coefficient is 0.105, and it is significant at the 5% level, which means that, for a one standard deviation increase in RE_V alue x ROA, CEO compensation increases by $32,733, when evaluated at the mean. This result suggests that CEOs are rewarded for their responses to changes in real estate prices, as proxied by ROA. Our interpretation is that this variable can capture, in a more comprehensive manner, responses to changes in real estate prices.Footnote 20

Table 3 Pay for action - total compensation

In Column 2, the coefficient of interest is the interaction between real estate asset sales and the value of real estate RE_V alue x RE_Sales. This term captures real estate asset sales associated with changes in the market value of the firm’s real estate assets. Since real estate assets are not marked-to-market but held at book values, negative changes in a firm’s real estate assets only occur if there is a managerial response to real estate prices (sale of real estate assets). Therefore we interpret the coefficient of this variable as the sensitivity of pay to responses to real estate luck. The estimated coefficient is 0.085, but it is not precisely estimated (the associated t-stat is 1.57). In Column 3, we estimate the same specification without the non-interacted RE_Sales term, since the Pearson (Spearman rank) correlation between this variable and the interacted term is 0.78 (0.99), as reported in Panel B, Table 1. The estimated coefficient is now 0.056 and statistically significant at the 1% level. The estimated monetary effect for a one standard deviation increase in RE_V alue x RE_Sales when evaluated at the mean is between $2,996 and $4,548.

Due to high correlation between action variables (RE_Sales, LT_Debt_Issues, and SLB) and their interaction with RE_V alue, we do not include the non-interacted terms in the rest of the analysis. As shown in Table 1, the Pearson (Spearman) correlation between these action variables and their interaction with RE_V alue ranges between 0.74 and 0.78 (0.97 and 1.00). Untabulated results show that the correlation between the action variables demeaned by CEO-firm and industry-year and their interaction with the demeaned RE_V alue resemble raw Pearson (Spearman) correlations. The exception is LT_Debt_Issues where the Pearson (Spearman) correlation drops from 0.74 (0.97) to 0.55 (0.57) for the demeaned variables, likely due to the fact that leverage tends to be industry and year specific. In addition, likelihood ratio tests (whether a model without the non-interacted term provides as good a fit to the data as the model that includes it) suggest that the inclusion of the non-interacted term does not provide a statistically significant improvement to the model.

Columns 4 and 5 show similar results for LT_Debt_Issues: the estimated coefficients on the interaction term RE_V alue x LT_Debt_Issues range between 0.017 in Column 5 and 0.037 in Column 4. The economic effect of a one standard deviation increase in the interacted term on total compensation is estimated to be between $3,931 and $8,595. Column 5 shows the results without the non-interacted debt term LT_Debt_Issues.

Lastly, Columns 6 to 7 show the results for SLB transactions: the estimated coefficient on the interaction term, RE_V alue x SLB, is positive but not statistically significant. We note that firms tend to “monetize” the increase in value of their real estate with SLB transactions, which means these transactions can result from past increases in real estate values. The estimated coefficient on SLB is positive (0.028) and significant at 5% level, which means that CEO compensation increases by $149,744, when evaluated at the mean, following an SLB transaction, regardless of real estate luck in the most recent period. Since we run all regressions with industry-year fixed effects, we filter out the common yearly industry component of these action variables, which means that our results only capture responses to real estate value changes that are not common to the whole industry.Footnote 21

As mentioned before, standard errors are calculated using two-way cluster at MSA and year. Conley et al. (2018) specifically raise the issue regarding a small number of clusters in Balakrishnan et al. (2014), who have a similar setting to ours. In our case, approximately 90% of our observations correspond to firms that have between 10 and 24 years of data, which mitigates this concern. Nevertheless, in Appendix D, we restrict our sample to firms that have more than 10 years of data and show consistent results.

The results of this section further support the notion that CEOs are rewarded for their responses to real estate luck, across different measures of action: RE_Sales, the catchall variable ROA, and LT_Debt_Issues transactions.

4.4 Cash and equity pay

In Table 4, we repeat our analysis differentiating between cash and equity compensation. We expect most of pay for luck to occur through equity compensation, as the stock price of the company, assuming some degree of market efficiency, should reflect the market value of the real estate assets of the firm. We measure equity grants using the fair value at grant date, which can occur at different times throughout the fiscal year for different firms. The equity grants thus relate mechanically to stock returns and thus can incorporate higher RE_V alue. On the other hand, we do not expect CEOs to be rewarded for luck using cash compensation, as that would be harder to justify to shareholders.

Table 4 Pay for action - components of pay

Columns 1-7 show the regression results for cash compensation. We do not find evidence of pay for luck through cash compensation, as the coefficient on RE_V alue is negative and insignificant across the different specifications. But we do find that CEOs are rewarded in cash compensation for taking actions using three of our action measures: sales of real estate RE_Sales, SLB s, and through the catchall measure, ROA.

Columns 8-14 show regressions using equity compensation. As expected, we find evidence of pay for luck through equity compensation, despite accounting for responses to luck in the regressions. We also find that equity pay is positively associated with the action variable LT_Debt_Issues, which is consistent with debt issues being in general positively perceived by investors.

Overall, the results presented in this section suggest that CEOs get rewarded using equity, not cash, for real estate luck. In contrast, when we test pay for action, we find that cash compensation is associated with most responses to luck, whereas equity compensation is not, suggesting that compensation responses to changes in real estate prices happens mostly through cash bonuses.Footnote 22 Since the evidence using total compensation suggests that CEO’s are rewarded for SLB transactions, regardless of luck, we exclude this variable from the rest of the analysis.

4.5 Is pay for luck optimal?

It only makes sense for the board to incentivize the CEO to respond to luck if such responses are optimal for shareholders. Even though it is arguably difficult to evaluate and directly test whether these actions are optimal, since we cannot observe a counterfactual, we can evaluate whether, on average, responses to real estate luck add value to shareholders. To do this, in this section, we explore cross-sectional variation in the level of financial constraints and corporate governance. In Appendix E, we run an event study on SLB transactions. We find that these transactions in general generate significant cumulative abnormal returns (CAR) between 1.3% and 1.4%.

4.5.1 Pay for responses to luck and financing constraints

In this section, we study heterogeneous effects of responses to changes in real estate prices for firms with different levels of financial constraints. We focus our analysis on the action variable LT_Debt_Issues, which is arguably an optimal response to increases in real estate values when firms are financially constrained. In addition, issuing debt does not have a direct impact on a firm’s operations. In contrast, a firm’s decision to relocate its headquarters (captured by the action variables RE_Sales and ROA) results from strategic considerations, such as labor market conditions, corporate taxes, the proximity to business services (e.g., airport), or a merger. For this reason, we focus this analysis on the action variable LT_Debt_Issues.

Table 5 shows the results for firms with different levels of financial constraints. Following the literature (Almeida et al. 2011; Campello and Hackbarth, 2012; Hadlock & Pierce, 2010), we use the firms’ previous year’s dividend payout and the Whited and Wu (2006) index (W-W), as proxies for the level of financial constraints. In the spirit of Almeida et al. (2011), for each year in our sample, we classify firms as financially constrained (unconstrained) if their dividend payout is below (above) the median within the year. We also employ the Whited-Wu index: each firm with Whited-Wu index value above (below) the median within the year is assumed to be constrained (unconstrained). We find that evidence of pay for responses to luck in the form of LT_Debt_Issues is more pronounced for financially constrained firms, irrespective of the measure of financing constraints used. The coefficient on RE_V alue x LT_Debt_Issues ranges from 0.037 and 0.039, at 5% significance level. On the other hand, for the financially unconstrained firms, we find that the pay for responses to luck coefficient is insignificant when using both measures. These results are consistent with responses to luck being more valuable for financially constrained firms, whose managers use increases in the value of real estate assets to relax these constraints.

Table 5 Pay for action - financial constraints

4.5.2 Pay for responses to luck and corporate governance

In this section, we explore cross-sectional variation in the level of corporate governance. Following the literature (Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2001; Dittmar & Mahrt-Smith, 2007), we use the following measures to draw inferences about corporate governance strength: the Herfindahl index (HHI) of industry concentration and the presence of institutional blockholders. In our first test, we analyze the role played by the product market competition of the firm’s industry: we construct the HHI index for each firm in our sample following Giroud and Mueller (2011). We expect to see stronger responses to luck in industries with low industry concentration. In less concentrated industries, managers have greater competitive pressure to maximize firm value or, in other words, less slack to behave sub-optimally. Therefore we should expect them to more actively respond to real estate luck. In our second test, in the spirit of Core et al. (1999), we use outside blockholder ownership, defined as the ownership by external blockholders with at least 5% of the outstanding shares, as a further measure of firm governance. Holderness (2003), among others, argue that blockholders have incentives to improve corporate management, and their presence indicates sound corporate governance. While we recognize that other aspects of corporate governance may influence our setting, we focus on these measures because they are well founded in the literature and offer clear predictions for what constitutes good governance.

Table 6 shows the results of pay for responses to luck in subsamples of strongly and weakly governed companies. We proceed by splitting our sample into high and low HHI firms (Panel A), based on the annual median value of HHI. The estimated coefficients on pay for responses to luck are positive and mostly significant in the subsample with low industry concentration (low HHI) across different measures of action (as captured by ROA, and RE_Sales). On the other hand, for more concentrated industries (as proxied by high HHI), the results are insignificant. In Panel B, we split the sample into high and low block ownership firms, if their aggregate block ownership is above (below) the median block ownership in each year. We find that the firms with high blockholder ownership compensate executives for responses to luck, as captured by RE_Sales transactions, whereas those with low blockholder ownership do not.

Table 6 Pay for action - corporate governance

Overall, the results presented in Table 6 suggest that better governed firms seem to be more likely to reward their CEOs for responding to (real estate) luck, which is consistent with the evidence of Bertrand and Mullainathan (2001). Taken together, the results presented in this section suggest that responses to luck are perceived as valuable from a shareholder’s point of view.

5 Robustness tests and discussion

5.1 Alternative measures of R E_V a l u e

We re-estimate our baseline results using an alternative definition of a firm’s real estate holdings, which accounts for accumulated depreciation of real estate. We follow Balakrishnan et al. (2014) and Chaney et al. (2012) and start with the sample of US-based Compustat firms in 1993 with nonmissing total assets. The year of 1993 was the last one in which the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) required that firms report the accumulated depreciation of buildings; this is also the year in which the CEO compensation information became available in Execucomp for a larger number of firms. We define real estate assets as buildings, land and improvement, and construction in progress (Compustat variables FATB, FATC, and FATP). In essence, this is the property and plant subset of property, plant, and equipment. To compute the market value of a firm’s real estate (buildings, land and improvement, and construction in progress), we measure the ratio of the accumulated depreciation of buildings (in 1993) to the historic cost of buildings, which gives us the relative proportion of the original value of a building that has been depreciated. Based on a depreciable life of 40 years (Chaney et al. 2012), we compute the average age of buildings for each firm. We infer the market value of a firm’s real estate assets for each year (RE_V alue_CST) in the sample period (1993 to 2016) by inflating their historical cost with MSA-level residential real estate inflation after 1975 and CPI inflation before 1975.Footnote 23 Using this approach gives us a smaller sample, resulting in a dataset of around 5,000 observations (when we combine the firms active in 1993 with the Execucomp data), relative to our main approach described in Table 2.

Panel A in Table 7 presents the results of re-estimating the baseline regressions, using the RE_V alue_CST measure of a firm’s real estate holdings. Results of estimating pay for luck using Eq. 1, shown in Column 1, confirm our finding that there is a positive association between CEO pay and the value of a firm’s real estate holdings, further suggesting the presence of pay for (real estate) luck. The estimated coefficient of 0.012 is positive and significant at 10% level. Columns 2 to 4 show results of estimating Eq. 3 for different proxies for CEO actions. The estimated coefficients of β2, on the interaction of CEO action proxies and RE_V alue_CST are positive and significant at common significance levels in most specifications, with the exception of LT_Debt_Issues. In sum, the results in this section suggest that CEOs are rewarded for (real estate) luck and for responses to luck, irrespective of the computation of the value of the firm’s real estate holdings.

Table 7 Robustness tests

5.2 Location of firms’ real estate holdings and time-varying real estate exposure

In the main analysis, we assume that the majority of a firm’s real estate holdings are located in the same MSA as its headquarters, and we measure exposure to real estate markets using real estate holdings of the firm in 1992, which is prior to our estimation period. To address a potential concern that a firm’s geographic footprint extends beyond the location of its headquarters and that exposure to real estate markets can be time-varying, we re-estimate our main results using a more granular measure of a firm’s real estate holdings, which accounts for the location of firm’s real estate assets across all states.

We run our baseline specification using a state-weighted HPI for each firm based on its real estate holdings across the United States. Since Compustat does not contain data on the location of each piece of a firm’s real estate holdings, we test the validity of previous results by using state-level data on firms’ operations obtained from García and Norli (2012), who extract state name counts from annual reports filed with the SEC on Form 10-K. The authors parse all 10-Ks filed with the SEC from 1994 through 2008, which gives them information on firm real estate holdings, such as factories, warehouses, and sales offices. This procedure yields a count of the number of times each 10-K mentions a U.S. state name. Based on the state name counts, we construct a relative exposure of each firm to the state-level real estate market, as captured by state-level house price indices HPI.

In this test, we follow the empirical strategy of Cuñat et al. (2018), whereby HPI is not measured at the MSA level, where the company’s headquarters is located, but is now calculated as a weighted average of the state-level HPIs in which the firm operates. The relative weights are based on the time-varying firm exposure to that state’s real estate market obtained using García and Norli (2012) data. In this procedure, we construct measures of time-varying firm-level real estate values that account for the different weights that each location represents in the firm’s overall business and construct firm-specific real estate price indices that aggregate prices across all the locations where a firm operates. Although this test helps address the measurement issues mentioned above, it introduces the concern that time-varying real estate exposure measures can be confounded with CEO’s actions.

Results from replicating the tests of Tables 2 and 3 with this revised measure of real estate market values are shown in Panel B of Table 7. The results are consistent in significance and almost two times larger in the case of RE_Sales and LT_Debt_Issues than in our baseline analysis. We find evidence of pay for luck as well as evidence of pay for responses to luck.

5.3 Measuring responses to luck

Our identification strategy relies on the fact that, under US GAAP, a firm’s accounting performance is unrelated to real estate market dynamics, unless the CEO responds to those dynamics in some way. The interaction term using one of our action variables, ROA, captures the sensitivity of CEO compensation to accounting performance that relates to changes in real estate values. This identification can be compromised by measurement error concerns, which we discuss in this section.

The first is the idea that the manager’s optimal response to a real estate price change can be no action at all. For instance, the optimal response to an increase in prices might not be to sell and realize the capital gain but instead to hold onto the property, if prices are expected to increase even more in the future. In such cases, this “no action” response is captured by market performance but not by accounting performance. Thus the observed sensitivity of compensation to responses to luck is underestimated.

Although unlikely, there may also be instances where accounting performance is linked to real estate prices, irrespective of responses. This is the case when real estate property is accounted for as investment property or as an asset available for sale. In these cases, real estate assets can be marked-to-market. We address this concern in two ways. First, in all our tests, we focus only on real estate property used in the firm’s operations and accounted for in property, plant, and equipment to estimate the sensitivity of compensation to responses to luck. These assets are not marked-to-market, and therefore the interaction term of ROA with RE_V alue will be nonzero only if a manager responds to real estate prices.

By excluding investment property, again we are providing a lower bound for the coefficient of responses to luck. Note that CEOs can also respond to real estate prices by buying or selling property that is not for the use of the company but for investment purposes. However, it is also not clear whether investing in real estate assets for investment purposes is an optimal action, given that this does not belong to the business operations of a nonreal-estate company (non-REIT). These cases are extremely rare: only four firm-year observations in our entire sample have such investment assets on their balance sheets.

Note as well that the pay for action that is measured is limited to firms that retain assets over the sample period. Since the real estate exposure measure is captured in 1992, if a CEO reacts to an increase in real estate by conducting for instance an SLB transaction, the manager is less able to react to a second increase in real estate prices.Footnote 24

Overall, our estimated coefficients represent a lower bound for the true sensitivity of compensation to responses to luck. Both issues discussed above suggest that our coefficient is underestimated due to “no actions” not being captured and actions over investment property also being ignored.

5.4 Endogeneity concerns

There are two potential sources of endogeneity in our analysis. The first is that real estate prices might not be exogenous to the performance of firms and hence CEO compensation. That is, there might be an unobservable variable (e.g., an increase in demand or an influx of new firms to the region) that drives both location-specific real estate prices and CEO compensation, which would in turn affect our results. The second concern relates to the real estate ownership decision: firms more likely to own their real estate may also be more likely to compensate their CEOs for responses to luck.

To address the first concern, the omitted variable bias, we follow the instrumental variable approach of Cvijanović (2014) and Chaney et al. (2012). To capture the variation in the market value of a firm’s real estate assets RE_V aluei,t, we inflate the market value of its real estate holdings in 1992 with a growth in MSA-level residential (land) price index from 1992 to year t, HPIm,t, as instrumented by interacting local land supply elasticity with aggregate real estate prices. The instrument in the first-stage regression is land supply inelasticity interacted with the growth in aggregate U.S. real estate prices from 1992 to year t, as measured by the S&P/Case-Shiller U.S. National Home Price Index, and RE_V aluei,1992, a measure of the market value of a firm’s real estate assets in 1992, as shown in the following first-stage specification.

$$ HPI_{m,t} = \beta_{1} {P}_{t}^{\text{US}} {e}_{0}^{m} + \beta_{2} {P}_{t}^{\text{US}} {e}_{0}^{m} RE\_Value_{i,1992}^{m} + \sum\limits_{x}\beta_{X} X_{i,t} + \gamma_{i,c} + \delta_{j,t} + \varepsilon_{c,i,t} $$
$$ RE\_Value_{i,t}^{m} = \beta_{1} {P}_{t}^{\text{US}} {e}_{0}^{m} + \beta_{2} {P}_{t}^{\text{US}} {e}_{0}^{m}RE\_Value_{i,1992}^{m} + \sum\limits_{x}\beta_{X} X_{i,t} + \gamma_{i,c} + \delta_{j,t} + \varepsilon_{c,i,t} $$

where \({P}_{t}^{\text {US}}\) denotes the growth in S&P/Case-Shiller U.S. House Price index from 1992 to year t, \({e}_{0}^{m}\) denotes land supply elasticity in MSA m, and HPIt,m denotes the growth in the house price index in MSA m from 1992 to year t. As in Eq. 1, Xi,t are firm and CEO-specific controls as defined in Section 3, and we include firm-CEO fixed effects, γi,c and industry-year fixed effects, δj,t.

We then use the predicted RE_V aluei,t and MSA real estate prices HPIm,t from the first stage in our tests with compensation as the dependent variable, as specified in Eqs. 1 and 3, with the same fixed effects structure and control variables as used in Table 3.

The results of the first-stage regression are shown in Table 13 of Appendix F. As expected, the interaction of housing supply elasticity and the Case-Schiller index has a positive and statistically significant coefficient at the 1% confidence level (0.007) when used to instrument for HPIm,t. Importantly, its interaction with RE_V aluei,1992 has a positive and statistically significant coefficient at the 1% confidence level (0.008) when used to instrument for RE_V aluei,t. A high value of the associated F-statistic (36.69) suggests that the chosen IV does not suffer from the weak instrument problem.

Our identification assumes that the elasticity of the land supply affects CEO compensation of real-estate owning firms only through its effect on real estate values. The exclusion restriction will be violated if land supply elasticity (interacted with a measure of demand for real estate, as captured by national real estate prices, and with a measure of firm-level real estate holdings) is correlated with CEO compensation for reasons other than real estate price growth. While we cannot test the exclusion restriction explicitly, the robustness of our findings to a comprehensive series of rigorous control variables and rich fixed effects structure partially mitigates this concern. Similar approaches have also been used extensively in the literature (Chaney et al. 2012; Cvijanović, 2014; Mian and Sufi, 2011; Adelino et al. 2015).Footnote 25

The second potential source of endogeneity is that firms that are more likely to own real estate are also more sensitive to local demand shocks. Thus finding that CEOs are compensated for real estate changes could reflect the board’s attempt to compensate the CEO for responses to demand shocks. To address this concern, we follow the standard procedure (Chaney et al. 2012) and further include interactions between firms’ initial characteristics and the HPI: in particular, we include five quintiles of firm age, firm size, and ROA as well as two-digit SIC-industry and MSA dummies. The results of these second-stage regressions are shown in Panel C in Table 7. Overall, we find significant evidence of pay for luck and significant pay for responses to luck. The estimates found using this setting resemble those in Table 3.

To provide additional evidence related to the second concern, that firms that own their real estate may also be more likely to compensate their CEOs for responses to luck, we run a propensity-score-matching test, where we match firms into treatment and control groups by their real estate holdings in 1992, their industry, and location. The first-stage regression is a probit regression where the independent variable corresponds to the treatment variable (action) and the independent variables correspond to the real estate exposure (RE_V alue), industry indicators, and MSA indicators. The treatment is defined using each of the action variables as previously defined: ROA, RE_Sales and LT_Debt_Issues interacted with RE_V alue. The treatment indicator equals one when the value of the action variable is above the sample median and zero otherwise. Controls are matched with replacement, and we use the single nearest-neighbor matching algorithm. Results are shown in Table 8. We find a positive treatment effect on CEO compensation across the different action variables. The average treatment effect on the treated ranges from 0.027 to 0.064 and is always statistically significant at 1%. Because our dependent variable is the logarithm of pay, these estimates represent percentage differences between treatment and control groups. For instance, for firms in the treatment group defined with ROA (firms for which ROA interacted with RE_V alue is above median), there is a 6.4 percentage point compensation premium when compared to firms in the control group. This result is consistent with CEOs being rewarded for responses to luck.

Table 8 Propensity-score-matching analysis

5.5 Types of news

In this subsection, we explore how our results vary with the types of real estate luck. In the spirit of Balakrishnan et al. (2014), we split our sample into firm-years in which the yearly change in real estate prices was above (below) the median change in our sample, which serves as a proxy for good (bad) real estate luck. We then re-estimate our regressions separately for years with above (below) the median change in the MSA price index. Further, we analyze the effect of large changes in real estate values, by re-estimating our regressions using only firm-year observations for which the yearly changes in MSA real estate prices (HPI) are in the top quartile of our sample. The results of these tests are presented in Table 9. Overall and when considering ROA and LT_Debt_Issues, our results are driven by positive real estate luck (changes in HPI above the median), and they also seem to be driven by large changes in real estate prices (changes in HPI in the top quartile).Footnote 26 Interestingly, managers are also compensated for responding to below median changes in HPI when it comes to RE_Sales but not when responding to above median changes. As selling real estate assets, including headquarters, is a strategic decision for firms, we conjecture that real estate prices are not the only factor to be considered. As an example, Ljungqvist and Smolyansky (2018) suggest that state corporate income taxes can also affect decisions to relocate headquarters.

Table 9 Types of news

6 Conclusion

We use variation in real estate values as a measure of luck to test whether CEOs are paid for factors outside their control (luck) and for responding to luck (action). To identify CEO actions, we propose a novel empirical strategy that relies on the different exposure of firms to changes in real estate values and on the fact that market and accounting performance do not reflect changes in the value of real estate in the same way. While stock market returns should promptly reflect any changes in the value of real estate assets of the firm, accounting returns should not, unless the manager takes some action. When we explore this difference, we find that CEOs are rewarded for their responses to luck, such as their sales of real estate or issuance of debt to exploit increased collateral value. We find that firms that are more financially constrained are the ones that reward CEOs for action, suggesting that the CEO’s response to the luck is more valuable for these firms. While evidence of pay for luck only occurs through equity pay, CEOs seem to be compensated for action mostly using cash and in well governed firms.

Our results provide consistent evidence of pay for action or response to luck. Nonetheless, they are subject to the common caveats in the literature that studies real estate value dynamics. First, our sample is subject to a survivorship bias, since we measure exposure to real estate changes at the beginning of the sample period, to alleviate concerns that exposure is endogenous. Second, although a firm’s headquarters is typically one of its largest real estate holdings, it is likely not its only holding. To the extent that firms have significant amounts of real estate property in states other than of their headquarters state, the change in the value of those real estate assets can be an omitted variable introducing noise in our results. We perform a robustness test using a smaller sample size for which we can identify the location of each of the firm’s real estate assets and obtain similar results. This test also allows us to construct a time-varying measure of a firm’s real estate exposure. Third, following Chaney et al. (2012), we rely on the residential price index to proxy for changes in commercial real estate property values, as that information is not readily available. Both are highly correlated. We also show that the results are robust to doing a propensity-score match and to exploring whether pay for action occurs when there is good real estate luck (i.e., yearly changes in MSA real estate prices in the top quartile or above the median value of our sample).

This paper brings a new perspective on the debate over pay for luck. Using our setting, we can identify responses to luck and show that CEOs are rewarded for these responses, which are arguably optimal from the point of view of the shareholders.