1 Introduction

Rogers and Van Buskirk (2009) document a decline in voluntary disclosure following litigation and suggest that litigation causes managers to revise their beliefs about the costs and benefits of disclosure—seemingly adopting a belief that even disclosures made in good faith will get them into trouble. As Lowry (2009) observes, this finding should concern both shareholders and policymakers. If managers respond to litigation with reduced disclosure, the risk of future litigation stemming from a failure to preempt earnings disappointments may increase and, more generally, the firm’s information environment may suffer. Consistent with these concerns, Rogers and Van Buskirk (2009) conclude that their findings call into question litigation’s effectiveness as a governance mechanism and suggest that regulators or harmed shareholders may need to take action to motivate improved disclosure going forward.

In this paper, we consider unexplored dimensions of disclosure as well as alternative disclosure channels to provide additional evidence that speaks to litigation’s role in shaping managers’ disclosure strategies. Because large earnings disappointments trigger lawsuit filings,Footnote 1 we examine whether managers respond to litigation by adjusting their disclosure strategy in a manner that increases the likelihood of reporting earnings that beat prevailing earnings expectations. In so doing, we directly test whether managers’ disclosures become more asymmetrically conservative in response to litigation.

We first examine whether managers’ disclosure responses differ depending on the sign of the news disclosed—that is, the extent to which the disclosure raises versus lowers expectations of upcoming earnings realizations. We then explore whether managers adjust the information they disclose via their press releases and in their conference calls. In our final set of analyses, we test for broad post-lawsuit changes in firms’ overall information environments.

Litigation potentially influences managerial disclosures in opposing ways. If litigation reinforces the value of early warnings (as well as underscores the costs of ex post inaccurate positive guidance), then managers may respond by reducing their disclosure of good news forecasts but, at the same time, by increasing the frequency and timeliness of their cautionary forecasts. Consistent with this notion of asymmetric disclosure incentives, Skinner (1994) finds that managers generally warn of impending negative earnings news far more frequently than they provide positive forecasts. Subsequent work documents that this asymmetry in disclosure likelihood increases with ex ante litigation risk (Cao and Narayanamoorthy 2011; Houston et al. 2019).Footnote 2 Alternatively, litigation may cause managers to revise their beliefs about the value of any disclosure. Consistent with this view, Johnson et al. (2001) and Naughton et al. (2019) document reductions in the disclosure of both good and bad news in response to reductions in litigation risk.

The above studies focus on the link between ex ante litigation risk and disclosure. In contrast, examining ex post disclosure responses to actual litigation, Rogers and Van Buskirk (2009) conclude that the experience of litigation encourages managers to reduce their overall disclosure. Yet, earnings-related lawsuits allege that managers failed to warn in a timely manner. Thus litigation may motivate managers to increase the frequency and timeliness of their cautionary disclosure, notwithstanding their choice to reduce other guidance.

To investigate how managers’ disclosure strategy changes in response to litigation, we hand-collect a sample of 654 firms that faced earnings-disclosure-related lawsuits following the passage of Regulation Fair Disclosure (“Reg FD”) in 2000. Consistent with the results of Rogers and Van Buskirk (2009), we find that overall forecast quantity falls in the post-lawsuit period, relative to the pre-lawsuit period, for sued firms and as compared to the changes observed for a sample of propensity-matched peers. Yet, inconsistent with the notion that managers discount the value of all disclosure post litigation, we find that the sign and timing of the forecast matter: while managers reduce and delay their forecasts of positive (and confirming) earnings news following litigation, their bad news forecasts actually increase and become timelier.Footnote 3

We also investigate whether managers respond differently depending upon their experience during litigation. As Lowry (2009, p. 158) notes: “managers of sued firms are likely to directly observe the ways in which their prior disclosures are used (or at least attempted to be used) to prove wrongdoing.” As a result, managers of sued firms who guided in the past may become reticent to continue providing disclosures that are inherently predictive and therefore leave them vulnerable to investor-plaintiff “Monday-morning quarterbacking.”Footnote 4 At the same time, managers of sued firms who face allegations that they failed to warn at all may believe that the absence of guidance (i.e., their silence) got their firm into trouble, and they may begin viewing disclosure as a way to minimize expected legal costs. Nevertheless, the bulk of the costs imposed by lawsuit filings relate to legal, time, and reputational costs borne by lawsuit managers (Kim and Skinner 2012). Consequently, managers’ disclosure responses may also differ depending upon the extent to which the firm’s litigation matters prompt media scrutiny and the manager faces increased reputational costs.

Shifting our attention to managers’ experience during litigation, our evidence indicates that managers do not adopt the belief that a higher level of disclosure harmed their cases. We find that those managers who were guiders prior to the lawsuit (including those whose own prior warnings faced scrutiny for being insufficient during the litigation process) do not stop guiding; rather, they give cautionary guidance earlier and more frequently in the post-lawsuit period. Moreover, many managers who were nonguiders prior to facing legal scrutiny begin guiding following litigation, and, in fact, they are more likely to do so than their nonsued counterparts. Exploiting variation in media scrutiny, we find that our earlier findings indicating more frequent and timely warnings following litigation concentrate among those firms that experienced above-median changes in media coverage of their litigation matters. This evidence contradicts the notion that legal and media scrutiny during litigation prompts managers to begin viewing all disclosure—especially good faith, cautionary disclosures—as more costly.

The question remains, however, whether managers adjust the information they disclose via other channels. Expanding our measures of disclosure, we find no evidence of reduced overall disclosure. Instead, we find that firms’ press releases that discuss negative news increase in the post-lawsuit period, while their press releases discussing positive and neutral news remain unchanged. We also find that managers do not limit the information they provide via their conference calls. After a lawsuit, managers increase the length of their introductory remarks, while sustaining their prior level of responsiveness to analyst questions during their conference calls.

Our final set of tests broadens the scope of analysis to consider changes in the overall information environment of the firm. Conditional upon the decision to provide a forecast, we find no evidence that managers’ willingness or ability to provide an accurate forecast changes in the post-lawsuit period. We also detect no changes in liquidity. Combined, this evidence quiets concerns that managers respond in a way that harms overall transparency (Lowry 2009). Further, we find that positive earnings surprises and the likelihood of beating consensus forecasts both increase in the post-lawsuit period. This suggests that the increased frequency and timeliness of cautionary forecasts along with accompanying disclosure in both press releases and conference calls may help walk down expectations. More generally, it contradicts the notion that firms adopt disclosure policies that leave the firm more vulnerable to litigation.

Collectively, our evidence suggests that following litigation managers continue to view disclosure as a way to shape their firms’ information environments and reduce expected legal costs. Accordingly, our paper contributes to the rich literature that examines the relation between disclosure and litigation. Cao and Narayanamoorthy (2011), Houston et al. (2019), and Naughton et al. (2019) find that managers respond to increases (decreases) in expected litigation risk with increases (decreases) in disclosure, while Field et al. (2005) and Billings and Cedergren (2015) find that increased disclosure links to a reduced risk of actual litigation. Combined, this evidence supports the classic legal liability hypothesis of Skinner (1994): managers seek to and do use disclosure to lower the firms’ litigation costs. Yet other evidence suggests that managers respond to actual litigation by adopting the belief that disclosures — even those made in good faith — may court trouble (Rogers and Van Buskirk 2009). As Lowry (2009) notes, survey and empirical evidence indicates that managers view good and bad news disclosures differently, particularly in the context of managing litigation risk (Graham et al. 2005; Skinner 1994), and thus the evidence of Rogers and Van Buskirk (2009) raises questions when compared to the literature. By directly considering the sign of the news when testing for changes in disclosure, our evidence reconciles these conflicting findings.

In so doing, our evidence supports an important alternative viewpoint of how firms respond to litigation as well as the effectiveness of litigation as a disciplining mechanism. Rogers and Van Buskirk (2009) conclude that regulatory and contractual intervention is needed, because managers do not respond with more frequent and timely bad news disclosures.Footnote 5 Expanding analyses to consider unexplored dimensions of disclosure, our paper concludes just the opposite. Most notably, our evidence suggests that managers adopt a more conservative disclosure strategy by increasing their efforts to walk down prevailing expectations to preempt negative surprises while maintaining disclosure via other channels. This paints a different picture of managers’ responses to litigation and accordingly contradicts the notion that regulators and shareholders should be troubled and take action.

Our paper also has implications for academic research. A well-cited review of the disclosure literature notes that existing evidence suggests that litigation decreases managers’ incentives to disclose (Beyer et al. 2010). Consistent with this view, many theoretical and empirical papers assume a reduced level of disclosure following actual litigation to inform their predictions (e.g., Files et al. 2009; Brochet et al. 2011; Laux and Stocken 2012). Yet recent work by Marinovic and Varas (2016) theorizes that litigation concerns crowd out positive disclosures while increasing the frequency of negative disclosures. Nonetheless, the empirical evidence remains mixed.Footnote 6 Because our findings provide a more refined view of how disclosure changes in response to actual litigation, our paper helps inform a growing stream of theoretical and empirical research in making predictions about how disclosure behavior varies with litigation risk in the broader population of firms. Further, researchers often focus on documenting changes in the frequency, likelihood, and precision of disclosure. Consistent with the work of Heflin et al. (2012), Heflin et al. (2016), our findings call attention to the importance of considering the sign of disclosure when examining changes in disclosure behavior, particularly in contexts where managers may face asymmetric disclosure incentives.

2 Data and descriptive statistics

2.1 Litigation sample

The classic litigation risk hypothesis advanced by Skinner (1994) focuses on managers’ incentives to preempt negative earnings surprises. Accordingly, we assemble a sample of firms that faced litigation from 2001 through 2015.Footnote 7 As shown in Panel A of Table 1, we begin by obtaining a list of 3,151 lawsuits from the litigation database maintained by Stanford Law School’s Securities Class Action Clearinghouse (“SCAC”) (http://securities.stanford.edu). The SCAC covers all securities class action lawsuits filed in Federal Court. Because our predictions relate to disclosure in the context of earnings news, we narrow this list to earnings-disclosure-related lawsuits brought under Rule 10b-5 of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934. A typical 10b-5 lawsuit alleges that the company made false or misleading statements and/or failed to disclose material adverse information in a timely manner to the market, resulting in a period when the firm’s stock price was artificially inflated. The class of investors (known as the “plaintiff class”) who purchased the company’s stock during this time (known as the “class period”) claims damages that result from managers’ inadequate disclosure. The revelation of negative earnings news (along with a drop in the firm’s stock price) typically triggers the filing of the lawsuit.

Table 1 Lawsuit Data

Because Skinner’s (1994) theory does not suggest that managers seek to use disclosure in advance of fraud or financial misreporting revelations to limit legal liability, we review each complaint to identify cases where managers are alleged to have failed to disclose earnings news in a timely manner.Footnote 8 To confirm the nature of each claim, we read the first identified complaint for the lawsuit. Consistent with work examining disclosure-related litigation, we then remove 2,219 lawsuits that do not relate to firms’ earnings disclosures.Footnote 9 We also remove 278 lawsuits for which sufficient data is not available to conduct our multivariate tests. As shown in Panel A of Table 1, this process identifies 630 unique firms that faced 654 lawsuits based on the firms’ earnings disclosures during our sample period. Figure 1 shows how the sample distribution varies across time. The number of earnings-disclosure-related lawsuits peaked around 2003 and 2004, with 71 and 64 lawsuits, respectively, after the dot-com bubble burst.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Lawsuits by Year

Reading the lawsuit complaints along with other public documents (e.g., subsequent legal filings, SEC filings, press releases, and media coverage) allows us to identify lawsuit durations, outcomes, allegations, and prior disclosure behavior. Although we find that slightly over half of all lawsuits are dismissed (344 ÷ 654 = 53%), Panel B of Table 1 indicates that resolution does not happen quickly in most cases. The average dismissed lawsuit takes almost two years to resolve. For nondismissed lawsuits, the average time to resolution approaches nearly four years. Further, consistent with Kim and Skinner (2012), we find that the vast majority of settlements are not large: the median settlement amount for the 301 settled lawsuits in our sample is $9.5 million. As Kim and Skinner (2012) note, the main penalties borne by lawsuit managers relate to legal, reputational, and time costs.

Shareholders can and do use managers’ guidance behavior (both the presence of positive news forecasts and the lack of cautionary warnings) as evidence of wrongdoing (Sale 2002; Johnson et al. 2007). Consistent with this notion, as shown in Panel C, we find that 483 (74%) of the firms in our sample have a history of guidance (GUIDER) in the eight quarters prior to the lawsuit filing. With regard to plaintiff allegations, 280 (43%) lawsuits include allegations that managers failed to provide a cautionary warning. The other 374 lawsuits are those in which managers did provide a cautionary warning but still faced subsequent litigation, with plaintiffs alleging that those warnings were insufficient. These univariates indicate that warning of impending negative earnings news does not prevent a lawsuit filing, as plaintiffs often argue that managers’ warnings were too little or too late to be sufficient.

2.2 Data

After identifying and hand-collecting the litigation sample, we augment this dataset with financial statement data from Compustat, guidance and analyst forecast data from First Call and I/B/E/S, security price data from CRSP, and insider transaction data from Thomson Reuters. We begin this process by obtaining the report date of quarterly earnings announcements (RDQ) for all lawsuit firms in Compustat for the eight quarters before and after the date of the lawsuit filing. To these firm-quarter observations, we add earnings guidance data from First Call’s Company Issued Guidelines files and the earnings guidance data now offered by I/B/E/S.Footnote 10

We code variables that capture the frequency and timeliness of managers’ guidance. First, we count the total number of pieces of guidance that the firm provided during that fiscal quarter (GUIDANCE_COUNT_ALL), with zero signifying quarters in which managers did not provide any guidance. We code positive and negative guidance (POSITIVE_GUIDANCE_COUNT and NEGATIVE_GUIDANCE_COUNT) using analysts’ prevailing estimates (following I/B/E/S); firm-quarters without positive or negative guidance are coded as zero.Footnote 11 Using this approach, a revenue forecast and an earnings forecast provided on the same date are treated as separate pieces of guidance. Second, we count the number of unique days on which the firm provided guidance during that fiscal quarter (GUIDANCE_COUNT_DAYS). Using this second approach, concurrently provided forecasts are treated as a single guidance event. Finally, averaging over all guidance given during the quarter, we compute the mean number of days between the date of guidance and the end of the fiscal quarter (GUIDANCE_HORIZON).

We gather additional disclosure data from RavenPack and the Thomson One StreetEvents database. In particular, we use RavenPack to identify the total number of firm-generated press releases in the quarter (PR_COUNT) but limit analysis to news items with a relevance score of 100 (i.e., where the entity was prominent in the news story). We classify the content of the press release as positive, negative, or neutral (POSITIVE_PR_COUNT, NEGATIVE_PR_COUNT, and NEUTRAL_PR_COUNT) based on the event sentiment score (ESS) in RavenPack, which is a granular score between 0 and 100 that represents the news sentiment for a given entity by measuring various proxies sampled from the news. An event with ESS greater than 50 represents a positive article, whereas one with ESS of less than 50 represents a negative article. Events with an ESS equal to 50 are considered neutral.

We use conference call transcripts obtained from Thomson One StreetEvents to develop our measures of conference call disclosure (CC_DISCLOSURE). We examine the content of conference calls (rather than the incidence of a call), because the vast majority of firms hold earnings conference calls after the passage of Reg FD. Although managers have some discretion over the tone they convey in an earnings call, the tone is largely dictated by the firm’s quarterly earnings performance and the content of the questions asked by analysts. Thus, in contrast to earnings forecasts, which managers can choose to provide, depending upon the information contained therein, managers cannot avoid hosting a call depending on the nature of the news to be discussed. As such, our tests focus on the level of disclosure and responsiveness of managers to analyst questions during the conference call. For each sued firm, we obtain transcripts from events occurring during the eight-quarter pre- and post-lawsuit periods used in our main firm-quarter sample tests. We limit our earnings conference call collection to firms whose lawsuit occurred in 2003 or later, which allows the pre-sued period to occur in the post-Reg-FD timeframe. We then match the date of each recorded transcript to the earnings release date in Compustat to identify quarterly earnings calls. Using a Python script, we then capture and parse the text of each call transcript to identify key variables related to the call, including the words and proportion of the call in the opening (scripted) monologue of the call presented by management (Mono words, Mono %), the number of questions asked by analysts during the Q&A session (#Qs), and the mean word length of management responses to such questions (Response per Q).

Next, we collect analyst forecast data from I/B/E/S, using the unadjusted, detail file three days prior to each earnings announcement. From this file, we derive the number of analyst forecasts (NUMEST), conditional on the forecast being no more than 90 days old (i.e., nonstale); the median nonstale analyst forecast; and the standard deviation of nonstale analyst forecasts (DISPERSION). We measure each quarter’s earnings surprise (SURPRISE) as the reported actual earnings minus the most recent median analyst estimates, deflated by stock price three trading days prior to the earnings release date. That is, we examine the typical standardized unexpected earnings surprise. Following Rogers and Van Buskirk (2013), we create indicator variables for positive earnings surprises (P_SURPRISE equals one if SURPRISE > +0.0001) and for negative earnings surprises (N_SURPRISE equals one if SURPRISE < −0.0001). In addition, we code an indicator variable for firm quarters where the firm reports negative earnings (LOSS). To capture the recent history of earnings surprises, we compute the proportion of the four prior quarters that SURPRISE was nonnegative, that is, the proportion of quarters the firm met or beat the median analyst forecast (PROPMB).

In addition to actual and forecasted earnings information, we collect share price, return, number of shares outstanding, and volume data from CRSP. We use these data to compute the market value of a firm’s equity each quarter (MVE), the 90-day return ending three days prior to the earnings release date (PRIOR_RET), and the standard deviation of daily returns over that 90-day period (VOLATILITY).

We also gather insider trading data from the Thomson Reuters Stock Transactions file. In constructing our trading measures, we concentrate on the behavior of directors and officers, consistent with prior work (e.g., Johnson et al. 2007; Li et al. 2016). This focuses our attention on the trading decisions of those insiders who are most likely to be aware of impending earnings news and most likely to be in a position to influence the firm’s disclosures. To further concentrate on the trading of individuals most central to disclosure choices, we restrict our measure of insider trading to actions of just the CEO and CFO.Footnote 12

We fully define all the variables used in our analyses in the appendix. Table 2 displays descriptive statistics for the quarter immediately prior to the lawsuit filing for each of the 654 lawsuit firms. As shown, the median lawsuit firm has a market capitalization (MVE) of $970 million, is followed by six analysts (NUMEST), has met or beat analysts’ estimates in three of the prior four quarters, and reported a 0.33% return-on-assets (ROA) while earning a − 8.3% return in the quarter leading up to the lawsuit filing.Footnote 13

Table 2 Descriptive Statistics

2.3 Univariate analyses

Because our predictions focus on changes in managers’ disclosure behavior in response to litigation, we begin by comparing measures of guidance activity in the eight quarters before (i.e., POST-SUIT = 0) to the eight quarters after (i.e., POST-SUIT = 1) the lawsuit filing. Within these measures, we separate the forecasts based on the sign of the forecast news (negative, neutral, and positive). As shown in Table 3, the evidence supports the notion that the sign of disclosure matters: positive (negative) guidance occurs less (more) frequently in the post-sued period, measured in both GUIDANCE_COUNT_ALL and GUIDANCE_COUNT_DAYS. Further, the GUIDANCE_HORIZON for negative (positive) guidance increases (decreases) in the post-sued period. At the same time, press release activity (of any sentiment) generally increases in the post-sued period. Conference call metrics also change after a lawsuit: the opening monologue segment (both in absolute numbers and as a percentage of the total words in the call) increases. The number of questions fielded decreases; however, the number of words used in response to each question does not decrease, suggesting that overall responsiveness does not change.Footnote 14 Turning our attention to indirect measures of information flow pre- and post-lawsuit, we find that signed forecast and analyst error do not significantly change, while the likelihood of a significant beat (which we define as a signed analyst surprise > +0.01) increases.

Table 3 Univariate Changes in Disclosure Behavior

Collectively, these univariate findings contradict the notion that litigation causes managers to revise their beliefs about the costs and benefits of their current level of disclosure, regardless of the sign of the news. Instead, they provide initial support for the notion that managers respond to litigation by reducing the frequency and timeliness of their positive and neutral news forecasts while increasing the frequency and timeliness of their negative news forecasts. In our upcoming multivariate tests, we examine changes in managers’ disclosure behavior surrounding lawsuit filings (1) after controlling for various determinants of managers’ disclosure decisions documented by prior work and (2) as compared to corresponding changes in disclosure for a group of propensity-matched control firms that were not sued.

2.4 Propensity-matched control sample

We propensity-match our lawsuit firms to suitable control firms in the year prior to the lawsuit filing based on the litigation risk model as detailed by Kim and Skinner (2012, Eq. 3), which takes into account industry membership (HIGHLIT_FPS), firm size (ASSETS), performance (RETURN and SALES_GROWTH), skewness of returns (SKEWNESS), return volatility (VOLATILITY), and share turnover (TURNOVER). We augment this litigation risk model to include insider sales (CEOCFO_SALES_ALL) to assemble a propensity-matched sample of control firms that faced similar litigation risk (Billings and Cedergren 2015). Specifically, we estimate our augmented Kim and Skinner (2012) logistic regression model over a population of 159,399 firm-quarters during our sample period, and each sued firm’s lawsuit quarter is then matched without replacement to a nonsued firm-quarter using nearest neighbor matching of the lawsuit fitted probability. The matched firm-quarter serves as the pseudo-lawsuit quarter for the matched control firm, with the eight quarters before and after the pseudo-lawsuit quarter serving as the matched control firm’s pre-sued and post-sued periods, respectively.

Table 4 provides descriptive statistics for the 654 lawsuit firms (SUED = 1) and 654 control firms (SUED = 0). Our propensity-matching approach leads us to identify a suitable group of similarly situated control firms in terms of litigation risk, with all but one of the covariates (VOLATILITY) showing no significant differences between the sued and nonsued group. (We further control for volatility in all our regression specifications.) Further, we detect no differences in overall guidance activity in the two years leading up to the lawsuit filing. In our upcoming multivariate tests, we address any potential lingering disparities with the inclusion of additional control variables, including measures of prior disclosure behavior.

Table 4 Propensity-Matched Control Sample

We also tabulate the trend in measures of firm performance in the seventeen quarters centered on the lawsuit filing. As shown in Table 4, we do not detect significant differences in ROA or stock performance during the eight quarters prior to the lawsuit filing. Thus our matching procedure appears to have selected similarly situated control firms in terms of performance prior to the filing of the lawsuit. In terms of post-lawsuit performance, not surprisingly, we do detect differences in the quarters immediately following the lawsuit filing. Yet no significant differences remain beginning four quarters after the lawsuit filing.

To further examine comparative trends in performance, we plot the quarterly measures of ROA for both the lawsuit and control firms in Fig. 2. This figure highlights that both the lawsuit and control firms experience a deteriorating trend in ROA in the quarters leading up to the (pseudo-) lawsuit date (i.e., quarter 0). This negative trend, however, reverses by quarter +1, when ROA trends upward in the post-lawsuit period both for the lawsuit and control firms.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Trend Analysis Quarters [−8, +8] Relative to Lawsuit. This figure presents a trend analysis of ROA in the 17-quarter period centered on the quarter in which the firm was sued (or the pseudo-lawsuit quarter for control firms)

Collectively, this evidence helps quiet concerns that the changes in disclosure that we document stem from differentially worse financial situations between the lawsuit and control firms ex ante. Nonetheless, while the evidence in Table 4 and Fig. 2 suggests that the lawsuit and control firms are well-matched before the lawsuit filing, differences in firm performance do emerge in the year immediately following the lawsuit. This highlights the need for strong controls for differences in financial condition in our analyses. Consequently, we include measures of firm performance (returns, ROA, and sales growth) as controls in our upcoming multivariate tests.

In addition, we perform a battery of untabulated robustness tests to address the concern that differential ex post performance explains the changes in disclosure we observe. First, we re-estimate the main analyses including controls for differential performance in the forecast-quarter. To do so, we consider a number of variations: (1) we control for differential ROA, calculated as the ROA of the sued (nonsued) firm minus the ROA of the nonsued (sued) firm in the corresponding quarter, relative to the lawsuit quarter, and differential return performance (calculated in an analogous fashion as differential ROA performance); (2) we control for differential year-over-year quarterly change in ROA (again calculated in an analogous fashion); (3) we control for the absolute value of the differential ROA and the differential return performance in the forecast quarter; (4) we include an indicator variable to control for instances where the differential ROA or differential return performance exceeded 5% in the forecast quarter. Second, we re-estimate the main analyses (as well as all of the robustness tests described above) using alternative control samples matched based on ex post performance alone. Finally, we also re-estimate the main analyses using a propensity-matched sample that considers ex post performance along with our original roster of matching criteria. Our main results remain robust across all of these additional specifications, and, in fact, the coefficient estimates and t-statistics for our variables of interest remain virtually unchanged.

3 Results

3.1 Research design

Using the propensity-matched nonsued firms as a benchmark, we begin by examining whether firms reduce their overall level of disclosure after lawsuit filings. To do so, we estimate the following regression model that builds on the model of Rogers and Van Buskirk (2013) and augmented by Billings et al. (2015), as follows.

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}\mathrm{DISCLOSURE}={\beta}_0+{\beta}_1\left(\mathrm{SUED}\times \mathrm{POST}-\mathrm{SUIT}\right)+{\beta}_2\left(\mathrm{P}\mathrm{OST}-\mathrm{SUIT}\right)\kern6.5em \\ {}+{\beta}_3\left(\mathrm{SUED}\right)+{\beta}_4\left(\mathrm{GUIDE}\_\mathrm{CQTR}\right)+{\beta}_5\left(\mathrm{GUIDE}\_\mathrm{PRIOR}\right)+{\beta}_6\left(\mathrm{P}\_\mathrm{SURPRISE}\right)\ \\ {}+{\beta}_7\left(\mathrm{N}\_\mathrm{SURPRISE}\right)+{\beta}_8\left(\left|\mathrm{SURPRISE}\right|\right)+{\beta}_9\left(\mathrm{LOSS}\right)+{\beta}_{10}\left(\mathrm{DISPERSION}\right)\kern1.75em \\ {}+{\beta}_{11}\left(\mathrm{P}\mathrm{RIOR}\_\mathrm{RET}\right)+{\beta}_{12}\left(\mathrm{Log}\_\mathrm{MVE}\right)+{\beta}_{13}\left(\mathrm{Log}\_\mathrm{NUMEST}\right)+{\beta}_{14}\left(\mathrm{P}\mathrm{ROPMB}\right)\\ {}+{\beta}_{15}\left(\mathrm{VOLATILITY}\right)+{\beta}_{16}\left(\mathrm{ROA}\right)+{\beta}_{17}\left(\mathrm{CEOCFO}\_\mathrm{SALES}\_\mathrm{ALL}\right)+\varepsilon .\kern3.75em \end{array}} $$
(1)

DISCLOSURE takes on the different disclosure variables as delineated in Section 2 when discussing the univariate results of Table 3.

Consistent with Rogers and Van Buskirk (2013), we expect that current-quarter guidance increases with past guidance. Accordingly, the inclusion of both GUIDE_CQTR and GUIDE_PRIOR allows us to focus on the factors associated with the decision to guide in the current quarter—as opposed to examining the factors that determine firms’ decisions to commit to an overall practice of issuing guidance.Footnote 15

Following Rogers and Van Buskirk (2013), we control for the current quarter’s earnings news (P_SURPRISE, N_SURPRISE, |SURPRISE|, and LOSS), the information environment of the firm (DISPERSION, Log_MVE, and Log_NUMEST), and recent performance (PRIOR_RET and PROPMB). Consistent with Billings and Cedergren (2015), Billings et al. (2015), and Li et al. (2016), we also include controls for forecast difficulty (VOLATILITY) and the presence of “disclose-or-abstain” insider trading incentives (CEOCFO_SALES_ALL).

3.2 Do managers reduce overall guidance in response to litigation?

Our first multivariate test examines changes in guidance behavior surrounding litigation. To do so, we estimate Eq. (1) where GUIDANCE_COUNT_ALL serves as the dependent variable. If lawsuit managers respond to litigation with reduced disclosure, as compared to the propensity-matched control firms, we expect to observe a negative coefficient for the interaction SUED×POST-SUIT. We report results of this regression in Table 5.

Table 5 Do Managers Adopt a More Conservative Disclosure Strategy in Response to Litigation?

In column [1], we examine GUIDANCE_COUNT_ALL for the full lawsuit sample of sued and matched firms. Consistent with Rogers and Van Buskirk (2009), our evidence indicates that lawsuit managers reduce the overall level of guidance in response to a shareholder lawsuit, as compared to similarly situated matched firms.Footnote 16 With respect to control variables, our conclusions are generally consistent with expectations. Most notably, prior guidance activity (GUIDE_CQTR and GUIDE_PRIOR) predicts current-quarter guidance frequency, while the guidance frequency falls with forecast difficulty (DISPERSION).

The result strengthens when we focus on nondismissed (i.e., settled) lawsuits. Comparing the dismissed lawsuit sample (column 3) to the nondismissed lawsuit subsample (column 2), the statistical significance and the magnitude of the coefficient increases considerably (from −0.046 to −0.079). While the litigation outcome is not known to the firm at the time of the lawsuit filing, managers are likely to have an estimate as to the strength of the case against them early on and form a belief about the likelihood of dismissal. As such, the partition between dismissed versus nondismissed likely identifies variation in the severity (treatment effect) of litigation. That is, the dismissed cases represent the less costly lawsuits that resolve more quickly. Thus, consistent with this notion and with Rogers and Van Buskirk (2009), we observe the effect of litigation on overall disclosure is stronger within the nondismissed, more costly lawsuits.Footnote 17

Relatedly, Cutler et al. (2019) demonstrate a link between increased disclosure during the class period and the likelihood of nondismissal (i.e., settlement). In relation to our findings, one potential interpretation of this negative relation between disclosure during the class period and severity of the lawsuit is that litigation may cause managers to view disclosure as costly. Yet it is important to note that Cutler et al. use the dismissed versus nondismissed (settled) indicator as an outcome variable, suggesting that settlement is a costly outcome. In contrast, Rogers and Van Buskirk (2009) use the dismissed versus nondismissed indicator to identify variation in the treatment effect of litigation, suggesting that lawsuits that survive dismissal (i.e., those that are settled) are the more severe lawsuits that take longer to resolve, because of the strength of the case. Thus increased disclosure may not cause the worse outcome; rather, it may merely pick up cases where the incentives to disclose were higher because of the severity of the negative news and, consequently, the case was stronger.Footnote 18 Nonetheless, consistent with Rogers and Van Buskirk (2009), the evidence of Cutler et al. (2019) suggests that litigation may cause managers to view disclosure as costly. In our upcoming tests, we examine whether litigation revises managers’ beliefs about the costs of disclosure and whether this varies based on the sign, timing, and venue of disclosure as well as managers’ experience during litigation.

3.3 Do managers adopt a more conservative disclosure strategy in response to litigation?

The evidence in Panel A of Table 5 indicates that managers reduce their overall level of disclosure following lawsuit filings. Panel B of Table 5 examines the sign of disclosure. Columns [1] and [2] focus on the frequency of positive and negative guidance (POSITIVE_GUIDANCE_COUNT and NEGATIVE_GUIDANCE_COUNT), respectively. If litigation causes managers to revise their beliefs about the costs and benefits of their current level of disclosure (regardless of the sign of the news), we expect to observe a negative coefficient on SUED × POST-SUIT in both columns [1] and [2]. If, however, litigation reinforces the value of cautionary warnings (along with the costs of ex post inaccurate positive guidance), then we expect to observe a negative coefficient on the interaction of SUED × POST-SUIT in column [1] and a positive coefficient on SUED × POST-SUIT in column [2]. That is, if litigation causes managers to reassess the costs and benefits associated with the particular sign of their disclosures (and not just overall quantity), we expect managers to reduce the number of good news forecasts while increasing the incidence of bad news forecasts.

We find evidence consistent with the latter explanation. Specifically, in columns [1] and [2] we observe a negative and positive coefficient on SUED × POST-SUIT for positive and negative guidance, respectively. Thus, consistent with Skinner (1994), the lawsuit filing appears to have reinforced the contrasting costs and benefits of positive versus negative forecasts. The asymmetric response also aligns with evidence of Nelson and Pritchard (2007), who find that managers increase their use of cautionary language in response to increases in litigation risk but do not remove cautionary language when litigation risk declines.

The evidence in columns [1] and [2] confirms that managers view the costs and benefits of positive versus negative guidance differently when deciding whether to continue to provide guidance after the lawsuit. Because most lawsuits allege that managers’ warnings were insufficient during the class period (Table 1, Panel C), this leads one to question whether managers also adjust the timing of their forecasts. Thus, in columns [3] and [4], we examine the timeliness of the forecasts (GUIDANCE_HORIZON). If litigation reinforces the value of early, cautionary warnings (as well as underscores the costs of ex post inaccurate positive guidance), we expect to observe a negative coefficient on the interaction of SUED × POST-SUIT when examining the timeliness of positive forecasts (column [3]) and a positive coefficient on SUED × POST-SUIT when examining the timeliness of negative forecasts (column [4]). As evidenced by the contrasting coefficients on the interaction term, we find that good news arrives later while bad news arrives earlier in the quarter for lawsuit firms in the post-lawsuit period (as compared to the changes in forecast horizon observed for the nonlawsuit firms).Footnote 19

Because the tabulated regressions in Panel B of Table 5 count only positive or negative guidance activity in the dependent variable, we also consider the extent to which this is effectively also cutting on the main dependent variable in Panel A (i.e., the level of guidance in general). In untabulated analyses, we have explored various regression specifications, and all results remain robust. In particular, the results presented in Panel B of Table 5 are robust to measuring our dependent variable as the proportion of the total guidance given during the quarter that was negative (e.g., GUIDANCE_COUNT_ALL using negative guidance scaled by the sum of positive and negative GUIDANCE_COUNT_ALL). In measuring the proportion of negative guidance, we use a number of different approaches that either include or exclude firm-quarters with no guidance as well as whether the denominator in the proportion includes confirming (i.e., neither positive nor negative) guidance. In addition, the results are also robust to estimating our main regression specifications using a negative binomial distribution.

In summary, the evidence in Table 5 corroborates the main finding of Rogers and Van Buskirk (2009): the total quantity of guidance falls following litigation. Yet it suggests a different conclusion in terms of whether litigation causes managers to doubt the value of all disclosures—especially cautionary guidance. Rogers and Van Buskirk (2009) infer from the absence of significant increases in signed management forecast error, earnings surprise, or earnings announcement abnormal returns that managers do not change the sign of their forecasts to adopt a more conservative disclosure strategy. In contrast, our tests that directly consider the sign of the forecast indicate that litigation does, in fact, intensify managers’ efforts to avoid negative earnings surprises: while managers reduce and delay their forecasts of positive (and confirming) earnings news (which drives the reduction in overall disclosure level), bad news warnings actually increase and become timelier.Footnote 20 Nonetheless, the effect of litigation on managers’ disclosure strategies may also depend upon managers’ disclosure history and their experience in litigation.

3.4 Does the response differ depending on the experience during litigation?

Next, we conduct cross-sectional tests to strengthen our attribution of litigation as a disciplining mechanism. Rogers and Van Buskirk (2009) conclude that scrutiny causes lawsuit managers to reduce disclosure, because they emerge from litigation with the belief that even their good faith disclosures will get them into trouble. To focus on a subset of managers for which this premise should be especially pronounced, we partition the sample based on the firms’ guidance history. Specifically, we code an indicator variable (GUIDER = 1) for firms that provided guidance in the two years prior to the lawsuit filing. For this subsample of guiders (N = 483), we expect managers to be especially susceptible to the notion that litigation caused them to believe that their disclosures weren’t helpful and, in fact, got them into trouble.

In contrast, for the remaining 171 nonguiding firms, it is more difficult to make a clear prediction. These nonguiders did not directly observe their own disclosures being used against them during litigation, which suggests that they may be less likely to believe that disclosure will get them into trouble. Instead, litigation may cause these managers to begin viewing guidance as valuable and necessary. Yet, because these firms had no history of guidance prior to the lawsuit, this means that litigation would need to push these firms to take on a new commitment to providing guidance—not just an adjustment within their existing policy. Research suggests that the marginal cost of initiating a commitment to guidance may exceed the anticipated benefit (Balakrishnan et al. 2014; Clinch and Verrecchia 2015). Thus this shifts the focus from the intensive margin (i.e., guidance frequency) to the extensive margin (i.e., likelihood of becoming a guider) for this nonguiding subsample.

To explore these cross-sectional differences, Panel A of Table 6 repeats our main tests after sorting the sample firms into these two groups. As shown in the first three columns, our findings suggest that GUIDERS do not adopt the belief that a higher level of disclosure harmed their cases or that even their good faith disclosures will be used against them. Rather, we find that those managers whose own guidance faced scrutiny for being insufficient continue to view disclosure as a valuable tool to bridge expectations gaps: managers who gave “insufficient” prior warnings give cautionary guidance earlier and more frequently in the post-lawsuit period.

Table 6 Does the Response Differ Depending on Managers’ Experience During the Litigation Process?

Shifting focus to the nonguiders, we do not detect significant changes in their guidance frequency (see specifications [4] through [6]). Nonetheless, we do find that these firms are more likely to begin guiding in response to litigation. In particular, as shown in specifications [7] and [8]), when comparing the lawsuit firms without a history of guidance to the nonsued (control) firms that also were nonguiders in the pre-period, we find that the lawsuit firms are more likely to begin providing guidance in the quarter and year following the lawsuit filing.

As an alternative approach to examining variation in managers’ experience during the litigation process, we identify those managers whose lawsuits exposed them to heightened media scrutiny. In particular, in Panel B of Table 6, we partition the lawsuit sample based on at-or-above-median changes in the level of media coverage surrounding their litigation matters (VISIBILITY = 1). We use the Key Developments database from Capital IQ to identify material news events pertaining to litigation occurring in the days surrounding the lawsuit filing (i.e., LIT_NEWS_ITEMS). We count the number of litigation-related news items (i.e., Capital IQ Key Development Item #25) during days [−10, +180], relative to the lawsuit filing date. To calculate an abnormal measure of litigation-related press coverage (∆LIT_NEWS_ITEMS), we difference this number from the number of litigation-related news items that occurred in the same period in the prior year. We then partition the sample based on the median ∆LIT_NEWS_ITEMS of three for the full sample and re-estimate our main regressions from Table 5.

We expect these high visibility managers to be especially susceptible to the notion that litigation caused them to believe that their disclosures aren’t helpful and, in fact, may get them into trouble. Comparing the first two columns to the last two columns in Panel B of Table 6, we observe that our earlier findings of more frequent and timely warnings following litigation concentrate among those lawsuit firms that experienced above-median changes in the level of media coverage surrounding their litigation matters.

Partitioning the sample based on litigation-related press coverage might also partition the sample based upon the severity of the litigation. To investigate this possibility, we examine the extent to which firm and lawsuit characteristics differ across this partition. When examining median differences, we do not detect significant differences in any of the following firm or lawsuit characteristics: size of the firm (in terms of MVE or ASSETS), length of the litigation class period, return performance during the litigation class period, days until lawsuit resolution, incidence of settlement, or settlement amount. Consequently, it does not appear that partitioning the sample based on increased incidence of litigation-related media coverage also partitions the sample based on the severity of the lawsuit.

In summary, narrowing in on lawsuit managers who experienced increased legal and media scrutiny during litigation, our evidence suggests that such scrutiny underscored the value of timely cautionary disclosure to these managers. At the same time, we find no evidence to suggest that any subsample of managers responded to litigation by reducing their cautionary guidance. Combined, this evidence contradicts the conclusion that scrutiny during litigation prompts managers to begin viewing all disclosure—especially good faith, cautionary disclosures—as more costly.

3.5 Do managers adjust the content of their disclosures in other venues following litigation?

Next, we broaden our analysis to other disclosure venues. The univariate statistics presented in Table 3 indicate that lawsuit managers do not reduce disclosures they make via press releases. Instead, they increase them. In Table 7, we test this hypothesis by re-estimating Eq. (1) using the count of firm-initiated press releases issued during the quarter as the dependent variable. Given the change in focus to press releases from guidance, we control for the prior level of firm-initiated press releases with the inclusion of lagged PR_COUNT in these regressions.Footnote 21 Panel A of Table 7 depicts the distribution of press release categories in our sample. Note that 26% of press releases relate to earnings-related disclosures, 19.2% to product and services, and 10.9% to marketing.

Table 7 Do Managers Adjust the Content of Their Disclosures in Other Venues Following Litigation?

Panel B of Table 7 shows multivariate results when using press releases as the dependent variable. In contrast to the overall reduction in guidance documented in Table 5, column [1] of Panel B suggests that the overall number of firm-initiated press releases actually increases in the post-period for the lawsuit firms, as compared to the matched firms. Yet, consistent with our earlier guidance findings in Table 5, the remaining columns suggest this increase is driven by an increase in those firm-initiated press releases that discuss negative news, as evidenced by the large and significant coefficient for SUED × POST-SUIT in column [3].

Shifting attention to firms’ quarterly earnings conference calls, Panel C examines changes in conference call dynamics surrounding the lawsuit filing.Footnote 22 In particular, in Panel C of Table 7, we examine changes in disclosure in the opening script as well as changes in the extent to which managers field questions. As shown in columns [2] and [3], our results suggest that managers lengthen their introductory remarks (both in proportion to the total words spoken and in the absolute number of words) in the post-lawsuit period. At the same time, the evidence presented in column [1] suggests that the overall length of the earnings call (measured as the number of words spoken by all parties on the call) does not significantly change. Thus the relative proportion of the call devoted to the Q&A portion seems to decrease. Despite this, however, we find no evidence that managers decrease their responsiveness to questions after being sued. Although the number of questions fielded by management does fall after the call (column [4]), so does the number of analysts participating (column [5]), so that the number of questions per call scaled by analysts participating does not significantly change (column [6]). Moreover, the average length of each response per analyst question does not change (column [7]). Similarly, in untabulated analyses, we detect no change in “non-answer” rates, as measured following Gow et al. (2019).Footnote 23

In summary, expanding our analyses to consider additional channels of disclosure beyond those explored by Rogers and Van Buskirk (2009), we find no evidence of reduced overall disclosure. Instead, we find that firms’ press releases that discuss negative news increase in the post-lawsuit period, while their press releases discussing positive and neutral news remain unchanged. We also find that managers do not limit the information they provide via their conference calls. After a lawsuit, managers increase the length of their introductory remarks while sustaining their prior level of responsiveness to analyst questions. Overall, this evidence suggests that many managers respond to litigation by not only emphasizing early, cautionary warnings but also maintaining (or even increasing) disclosure in other venues. Building upon this evidence, our next analysis examines more general changes in firms’ information environment surrounding litigation.

3.6 Does the overall information environment of the firm change following litigation?

Our findings thus far indicate that guiding firms increase the frequency and timeliness of their bad news guidance while maintaining or increasing disclosure via alternative channels. In Table 8, we investigate changes in indirect measures of information flow following litigation. In the first two specifications, we examine changes in the accuracy of managers’ forecasts; in the next four columns, we focus on analysts’ forecasts; in the final specification, we examine liquidity.

Table 8 Information Environment

As shown in columns [1] and [2], consistent with Rogers and Van Buskirk (2009), we detect no changes in unsigned or signed management forecast error. That is, conditional upon the decision to issue a forecast, we find no evidence to suggest that managers’ willingness or ability to provide an accurate forecast changes in the post-lawsuit period.Footnote 24 Looking at analyst forecast error, however, we do detect certain changes in earnings surprises. Specifically, as shown in column [3], we find that absolute earnings surprises increase. Additionally, while signed earnings surprises do not significantly increase (column [4]), the likelihood of positive earnings surprise (i.e., our P_SURPRISE and BEAT variables on columns [5] and [6] logistic regressions) increases. This suggests that the increased frequency of negative news forecasts (and accompanying increases in disclosure via press releases and conference calls) may help walk down expectations in the post-lawsuit period. Additionally, we find no evidence that stock liquidity (as measured using the Amihud stock illiquidity measure) changes.Footnote 25 Thus, lawsuit managers—including those managers who did not take advantage of warning in the past—appear to respond to litigation with a renewed emphasis on cautionary guidance, and, in so doing, they decrease the likelihood that the firm reports another potentially lawsuit-triggering negative earnings surprise.

4 Conclusion

Research calls into question litigation’s effectiveness as a corporate governance mechanism—finding that litigation causes managers to reduce disclosure, perhaps stemming from a belief that even their good faith disclosures will be used against them. From shareholders’ perspective, this finding is concerning, given the documented litigation and other information environment benefits associated with disclosure (Field et al. 2005; Anantharaman and Zhang 2011; Billings and Cedergren 2015). This finding is also concerning from the standpoint of regulators, as it calls into question the extent to which litigation disciplines managers. Further, proponents of litigation reform are often concerned that abusive litigation constrains managers’ willingness to openly communicate forward-looking information to the marketplace (Johnson et al. 2000; Johnson et al. 2001; Johnson et al. 2007).

We consider unexplored dimensions of disclosure and alternative channels of disclosure to provide additional evidence that speaks to the role that litigation plays in shaping managers’ disclosure strategies. Consistent with Skinner (1994)‘s classic legal liability hypothesis, we find that, while managers reduce and delay forecasts of positive earnings news following litigation, they increase the frequency and timeliness of their bad news forecasts. We also find that managers maintain (if not increase) the information they provide via press releases and during conference calls following litigation. Supporting the notion that managers use disclosure to walk down expectations, additional analyses document an increase in the likelihood that lawsuit firms report earnings that beat consensus forecasts in the post-lawsuit period.

Collectively, our evidence suggests that following litigation managers continue to view disclosure as a valuable tool that shapes their firms’ information environments and reduces expected legal costs. Thus our evidence reconciles the finding that managers respond to litigation by reducing disclosure with the growing body of literature that finds that managers seek to and do use disclosure to lower their firms’ litigation risk. At the same time, our evidence supports an important alternative viewpoint of how firms respond to litigation as well as the effectiveness of litigation as a disciplining mechanism.