Skip to main content
Log in

Analysts’ sale and distribution of non fundamental information

  • Published:
Review of Accounting Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine an analyst’s sale and distribution of information related to short-term price movements but unrelated to underlying firm value. By selling non fundamental information, the analyst increases competition on the signal, but prices become more sensitive to net order flow, creating an offsetting increase in the non fundamental signal’s value. More precise non fundamental information is more widely distributed. In the limit, a perfect non fundamental signal will be publicly disclosed for an arbitrarily small fee, and the analyst earns profits as if he possessed fundamental information. Consistent with empirical findings, analysts’ recommendations can be profitable, even when widely distributed or seemingly inconsistent with detailed forecasts. Analysis based on non fundamental information does not contribute to greater price efficiency but reduces liquidity costs. In a multi-period setting, traders with non fundamental information do not front-run, preferring to transact only in the period in which uninformed demand is executed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. http://www.schaeffersresearch.com/commentary/dailycontrarian.aspx.

  2. Bradshaw (2002) find that analysts’ opinions are not explained by per-period earnings forecasts despite the fact that earnings forecasts can predict one year ahead stock returns. Barniv et al. (2009) confirm these findings but finds a less intense negative relation between recommendations and returns following Regulation Fair Disclosure.

  3. Contrast this with the findings in Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2005), in which a distressed trader’s liquidity needs cannot be immediately satisfied, or those in Carlin et al. (2007), repeated play and a limited number of investors are required conditions for cooperation.

  4. Sabino (1993) and Fishman and Hagerty (1995) similarly discuss this benefit of fundamental information sales.

  5. For a summary, see Demski et al. (1999).

  6. Consistent with this, “The Strategic/Proprietary Trading desk leverages the Firm’s capital \(\ldots\). As a buy-side desk within a predominately sell-side Firm, this desk does not directly interact with Lehman Brothers clients. Instead, it relies on other sell-side firms in the market to provide incoming research (Lehman Brothers).”

  7. See, for example, Admati and Pfleiderer (1986, 1990), Brennan and Chordia (1990), and Biais and Germain (2002).

  8. Most large investment firms have proprietary desks that gather information but do not sell it directly. If risk sharing motives were significant at the firm or individual analyst level, we would expect direct sales of information by these buy-side analysts as well.

  9. The non fundamental signal is an abstract representation of the activities of financial analysts that lead to superior knowledge about market sentiment, including road shows, the analysis of various data feeds, relationships with institutional investors, orders over a squawk box, general market data, etc.

  10. While knowledge of non fundamental information is valuable in our market order model, it might not necessarily be so under other market structures.

  11. In our setting, observing c is equivalent to observing m, whereas Admati and Pfleiderer (1988) assume direct observability of the number of traders. In practice, the number of subscribers to a database (for example, I/B/E/S, FirstCall) may effectively function as a commitment to a fixed number of traders.

  12. Mikhail et al. (2004) show that analysts can produce profitable recommendations, but after accounting for transactions costs, returns are no longer reliably positive.

  13. Specifically, we solve for a single demand-based trader’s optimal response function given the expected demand posted by other demand-based traders and then apply the symmetry of types to get the Cournot solution. Because we assume the traders cannot resell their information, they are prevented from credibly acting more aggressively (that is, like a Stackelberg leader).

  14. Equivalently, the frontier can be interpreted as the maximum number of demand-based traders m willing to purchase information at every given price c.

  15. The proprietary trader can be one of the analyst’s clients as proprietary and demand-based trading are additively separable, with price sensitivity affected only by the number (not identity) of demand-based traders.

  16. Mathematically, the constant term disappears when differentiating non fundamental profits and setting equal to zero.

  17. By allowing the number of demand-based traders to be a continuous variable, we find that some degree of information sale is optimal, conceptually. If m is required to be an integer, there may be values of θ such that m = 1 is preferred to m = 2. Additionally, allowing the proprietary trader to acquire the analyst’s signal (that is, also become a demand based trader) does not alter the characterization of equilibrium prices or the results obtained.

  18. To the extent σ 2 u proxies for volume, our conclusions are consistent with Bhushan (1989) and O’Brien and Bhushan (1990), who document a positive relation between trading volume and analyst following.

  19. The insider trading case against Galleon is unrelated to these transactions.

  20. “Goldman’s Trading Tips Reward Its Biggest Clients”, August 24, 2009, The Wall Street Journal, p. A1.

  21. Efforts to promote transparency include the Securities Acts Amendments of 1975 and recent regulation against dark pools.

  22. The analyst’s information could be imperfect; the results are notationally more cumbersome but qualitatively similar.

  23. For all values of (positive) variance, the derivative of the analyst’s profits is strictly negative for all values of m > 1.5.

  24. We also consider the additional restriction where n = m, or the analyst can have a single set of clients to whom he sells both pieces of information. The information sharing result persists, but the optimal number is non-monotonic in θ. Proof available on request from authors.

  25. Fishman and Hagerty (1995) solve a model with duopolist information sellers of fundamental information only.

  26. An alternative way to think about the resource transfer from the analyst to the proprietary trader would be for the analyst to commit to sell to a smaller number of demand-based traders than is optimal in exchange for the information. Whether such commitments are feasible may be debatable, we however can imagine an unmodeled repeated relationship between the proprietary trader and analyst where a failure to stick to the agreed upon distribution would lead to no fundamental sales in all subsequent periods.

  27. In this section, we restrict the analyst from reselling fundamental information. However, the results are stronger when the analyst can resell and chooses the optimal demand-based and fundamental distribution \(\hat{m}\) and \(\hat{n}\) respectively. Proof available upon request from authors.

  28. Holding σ 2 u fixed, increases in the signal weight θ are the direct result of increases in precision (that is, decreases in \(\sigma_{\epsilon}^{2}\)).

  29. Notation is simplified by making the proprietary trader’s information perfect, but it is not necessary, and does not change the qualitative nature of the results.

  30. If there is no fundamental information in the first period, front-running is similarly unattractive. First round trading reduces the value of second period profits through an update on u 2 and with zero expected first period profits.

  31. If restricted to integer values, there will be no non fundamental sales whenever \(\theta<\hat{\theta}\approx0.478\), and thus price efficiency is constant for \(\theta\in(0,\hat{\theta})\).

References

  • Admati, A. R., & Pfleiderer, P. (1986). A monopolistic market for information. Journal of Economic Theory, 39(1), 400–438.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Admati, A. R., & Pfleiderer, P. (1988). Selling and trading on information in financial markets. American Economic Review, 78(2), 96–103.

    Google Scholar 

  • Admati, A. R., & Pfleiderer, P. (1990). Direct and indirect sale of information. Econometrica, 58(4), 901–928.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Back, K. (1992). Insider trading in continuous time. Review of Financial Studies, 5(3), 387–409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagnoli, M., Clement, M., Crawley, M., & Watts, S. (2009). The profitability of analysts stock recommendations: Is estimating intrinsic value all that matters? Working Paper, University of Texas at Austin, http://ssrn.com/abstract=143061.

  • Barber, B., Lehavy, R., McNichols, M. S., & Trueman, B. (2001). Can investors profit from the prophets? Security analyst recommendations and stock returns. Journal of Finance, 56(2), 1083–1124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barniv, R., Hope, O.-K., Myring, M., & Thomas, W. (2009). Do analysts practice what they preach and should investors listen? effects of recent regulations. Accounting Review, 84(4), 1015–1039.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhushan, R. (1989). Firm characteristics and analyst following. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 11(2-3), 255–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Biais, B., & Germain, L. (2002). Incentive-compatible contracts for the sale of information. Review of Financial Studies, 15(4), 987–1003.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Block, S. (1999). A study of financial analysts: practice and theory. Financial Analysts Journal, 55(4), 86–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradshaw, M. T. (2002). The use of target prices to justify sell-side analysts’ stock recommendations. Accounting Horizons, 16(1), 27–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradshaw, M. T. (2004). How do analysts use their earnings forecasts in generating stock recommendations? Accounting Review, 79(1), 25–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, M. J., & Chordia, T. (1990). Brokerage commission schedules. Journal of Finance, 48(4), 1379–1403.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier, M. K., & Pedersen, L. H. (2005). Predatory trading. Journal of Finance, 60(4), 1825–1863.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlin, B., Lobo, M., & Viswanathan, S. (2007). Episodic liquidity crises: Cooperative and predatory trading. Journal of Finance, 62(5), 2235–2274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Craig, S. (2009). Goldman’s trading tips reward its biggest clients. Wall Street Journal, A1. http://online.wsj.com/article/SB125107135585052521.html.

  • Demski, J., Lewis, T., Yao, D., & Yildirim, H. (1999). Practices for managing information flows within organizations. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 15(1), 107–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishman, M. J., & Hagerty, K. (1995). The incentive to sell financial market information. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 4(2), 95–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishman, M. J., & Longstaff, F. A. (1992). Dual trading in futures markets. Journal of Finance, 47(2), 643–671.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garcia, D., & Sangiorgi, F. (2009). Information sales and strategic trading. Working Paper, University of North Carolina, http://www.unc.edu/garciadi/paper19v05.pd.

  • Irvine, P., Lipson, M., & Puckett, A. (2007). Tipping. Review of Financial Studies, 20(3), 741–768.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kyle, A. (1985). Continuous auctions and insider trading. Econometrica, 53(6), 1315–1335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lang, M., & Lundholm, R. (1996). Corporate disclosure policy and analyst behavior. Accounting Review, 71(4), 467–492.

    Google Scholar 

  • Madhavan, A., Porter, D., & Weaver, D. (2005). Should securities markets be transparent? Journal of Financial Markets, 8(3), 265–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madrigal, V. (1996). Non-fundamental speculation. Journal of Finance, 51(2), 553–578.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mikhail, M. B., Walther, B. R., & Willis, R. H. (2004). Do security analysts exhibit persistent differences in stock picking ability? Journal of Financial Economics, 74(1), 67–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien, P. C., & Bhushan, R. (1990). Analyst following and institutional ownership. Journal of Accounting Research, 28(Supplement), 55–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rochet, J.-C., & Villa, J.-L. (1994). Insider trading without normality. Review of Economic Studies, 61(1), 131–152.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Röell, A. (1990). Dual-capacity trading and the quality of the market. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 1(2), 105–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sabino, J. (1993). Incentives to sell information. Working Paper, University of Pennsylvania.

  • Sender, H. (2009). Galleon paid banks millions for ‘edge’. Financial Times, October 28, http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/9b7b329e-c400-11de-8de6-00144feab49a.html#axzz1DyuMfBn.

  • Bernhardt, D., & Taub, B. (2008). Front-running dynamics. Journal of Economic Theory, 138(1), 288–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu, F. (1999). What is the value of knowing uninformed trades? Economics Letters, 64(1), 87–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We appreciate the comments of Stan Baiman, Anne Beyer, Khrystina Bochkay, Mark Bradshaw, Gus DeFranco, Diego Garcia, Ilan Guttman, Jack Hughes, Paul Irvine, Stephannie Larocque, Roby Lehavy, Beatrice Michaeli, Christine Parlour, and seminar participants at Carnegie Mellon University, Dartmouth College, The University of Chicago, The University of Georgia, Rutgers University, and The University of Wisconsin.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Carolyn B. Levine.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Lemma 1

Suppose for constants β m , γ m and λ m XZ, and P are given by

$$ X_{m}=\beta_{m} s \,\,\,Z_{m}=\gamma_{m} \tau \,\,\, P_{m} =\lambda_{m} y. $$

Given the linear rules, the proprietary trader and a (representative) demand-based trader’s profits can be written as

$$ \begin{aligned} E\{(v-P_{m})x_{m}|s,m, x_{m}\} &= E(x_{m} (v-\lambda_{m}(x_{m}+m\gamma_{m} \tau +u))|s,m,x_{m})\\ &= x_{m}(\Uppsi s-\lambda_{m}x_{m})\\ E\{(v -P_{m})z_{m}|\tau,m, z_{m}\} &= E(z_{m}(v-\lambda_{m}(\beta_{m} s + z_{m} + (m-1)\bar{\gamma}_{m}\tau+u))|\tau,m,z_{m})\\ &= -z_{m}\lambda_{m}(z_{m}+(m-1)\bar{\gamma}_{m}\tau+\theta \tau), \end{aligned} $$

where \(\bar{\gamma}\) is the expected trading strategy of each of the other m − 1 demand-based traders. Taking first order conditions and replacing \(\bar{\gamma}\) with γ (since all demand-based traders are identical) gives

$$\beta_{m}=\frac{\Uppsi}{2\lambda_{m}} \,\,\, \hbox{and}\,\,\,\gamma_{m}=-\frac{\theta}{m+1}. $$
(7)

The market efficiency condition P m  = λ m y = E{v|y} implies

$$ \lambda_{m} =\frac{\beta_{m} \Upsigma}{\beta_{m}^2 \Upsigma/\Uppsi+\sigma_u^2\left(\frac{m^2 \gamma_{m} ^2}{\theta }+2 m \gamma_{m}+1\right)}. $$
(8)

Solving (7) and (8) subject to the second order condition λ m  > 0 gives the equilibrium. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 1

  1. (i)

    The expected profit of an individual demand-based trader in a market with a total of m demand-based traders, \(\Uppi^{D}_{i,m}\) is

    $$\Uppi^{D}_{i,m}=\frac{\gamma_{m} \left(-\gamma_{m} \lambda-\left(\frac{(m-1) \gamma_{m} }{\theta }+1\right) \theta \lambda\right) \sigma_{u}^2}{\theta}. $$
    (9)

    Replacing the expression of γ m and simplifying yields

    $$\Uppi^{D}_{i,m}=\frac{\theta \lambda \sigma_{u}^2}{(m+1)^2}, $$
    (10)

    making a demand-based trader indifferent between buying and not buying information at

    $$ c=\frac{\theta \lambda\sigma_{u}^2}{(m+1)^2}. $$
    (11)

    Replacing λ with λ m , we get

    $$ c_{m}=\frac{\theta}{2(m+1)} \left(\frac{\Upsigma \Uppsi \sigma_u^2}{m (m+2) (1-\theta)+1}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}. $$
    (12)

    The analyst’s profits are equal to \(\Uppi^{A}=m c_{m}\). The analyst chooses the optimal number of demand-based traders to maximize profits. Taking the FOC of \(\Uppi^{A}\) in m:

    $$ \theta \sqrt{\Upsigma\Uppsi \sigma_{u}^{2}} \left(\frac{\left(m \left(1-m-m^2\right)(1-\theta )+1\right) }{2 (m+1)^2 (m (m+2) (1-\theta)+1)^{3/2}}\right)=0. $$
    (13)

    Therefore m* and c* are implicitly defined by the following equations

    $$ 0 = m^{*}\left(1-m^{*}-m^{*2}\right) (1-\theta )+1 $$
    (14)
    $$ c^{*} = \frac{\theta}{2(m^{*}+1)^2} \left(\frac{\Upsigma \Uppsi\sigma_u^2}{r_{m^{*}}}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}. $$
    (15)
  2. (ii)

    Write (14) as \(\,\Upgamma(\theta,m^{*})=0\,\) where

    $$ \Upgamma(\theta, m)=m\left(1-m-m^{2}\right) (1-\theta )+1. $$
    (16)

    \(\forall \, m \geq 0,\Upgamma(\theta,m)\) is a third degree polynomial, increasing in \(m\in[0,1/3]\), taking values in [1, 1 + (5/27) (1 − θ)] and decreasing in \(m\in(1/3,+\infty)\), taking values in \((-\infty,1+(5/27)(1-\theta)]\). Therefore, there exists a unique real solution to \(\Upgamma(\theta,m^{*})=0\), which can be written as \(m^{*}= \Updelta(\theta)\). Using the implicit function theorem,

    $$ \begin{aligned}\Updelta'(\theta) &=-\frac{\partial\Upgamma}{\partial\theta}(\theta,m)/\frac{\partial\Upgamma}{\partial{m}}(\theta, m)\\ &= \frac{m\left(1-m-m^2\right)}{\left(1-2m-3 m^2\right) (1-\theta)}.\end{aligned} $$
    (17)

    By (14), \(\left(1-m-m^2\right)<0\) and \(\left(1-2m-3m^2\right)<0\). Thus \(\Updelta'(\theta) >0\), and m* is increasing in θ. As \(\theta\rightarrow0,\,m^{*}\rightarrow{\left(1-m-m^2\right)}/{\left(1-2m-3m^2\right)}\) and therefore \(m^{*} > 1 \,\forall\,\theta \in (0,1)\).

Taking the second order condition, solving (14) for θ, and substituting gives

$$ -\frac{\sqrt{\Upsigma\Uppsi \sigma_{u}^{2}}(1-m^{*})(1-3m^{*})}{2 m^{*2} (1+m^{*})^{2} \sqrt{-(1-m^{*}-m^{*2})}} \leq 0 $$

for all m* ≥ 1. Since m* is unique, greater than 1, and the second order condition (SOC) is negative at m*, m* is a global maximum. \(\square\)

Proof of Corollary 1

  1. (i)

    \(\lim_{\theta\rightarrow 1}\Uppi^{A}=\frac{m}{2(m+1)}\left(\Upsigma \Uppsi\sigma_{u}^{2}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}\) which is increasing in m and thus maximized at \(m^*\rightarrow \infty\). As m* is increasing in θ, m* is increasing in \(1/\sigma^2_{\epsilon}\) and σ 2 u .

  2. (ii)

    \(\Uppsi\) is increasing in 1/σ2. Proprietary trading profits are

    $$ \Uppi^{P*}=\sqrt{\Upsigma\Uppsi \sigma_{u}^{2}} \left(\frac{ \sqrt{(1+m^{*} (m^{*}+2)(1-\theta)) }}{2 (m^{*}+1)}\right), $$
    (18)

    and the analyst’s profits, at m* are

    $$ \Uppi^{A*}=\sqrt{\Upsigma \Uppsi \sigma^2_u }\left(\frac{m^{*} \theta }{2(m^{*}+1)\sqrt{1+ m^{*} (m^{*}+2) (1-\theta))}}\right). $$
    (19)

    Since m* is independent of \(\Uppsi\) and \(\Upsigma\), it follows immediately that \(\Uppi^{P*}\) and \(\Uppi^{A*}\) are increasing in \(\Upsigma\) and 1/σ2.

  3. (iii)

    Differentiating (18) with respect to θ gives

    $$ -\sqrt{\Upsigma \Uppsi\sigma_{u}^{2}}\left(\frac{ 2 \theta \Updelta^{'}(\theta )+m^{*}(m^{*}+1) (m^{*}+2)}{4 (m^{*}+1)^2 \sqrt{1+m^{*}(m^{*}+2)(1-\theta)}}\right)\leq 0, $$
    (20)

    and since \(\Updelta^{'}(\theta )>0\), and thus \(\Uppi^{P*}\) is decreasing in \(1/\sigma^{2}_{\epsilon}\).

    First, replace \(\theta =(\sigma^{2}_{u}/(\sigma_{u}^{2}+\sigma^{2}_{\epsilon}))\) and differentiate (18) with respect to σ 2 u . Then, replace m*'(θ) with \(\Updelta'(\sigma_{u}^{2}/(\sigma_{u}^{2}+\sigma^{2}_{\epsilon}))\), and \(\sigma^{2}_{u}=(m^*-1)(1+m^*)^2\sigma^2_{\epsilon}\) (14) to yield

    $$ \frac{m^{*}\left(m^{*2}+m^*-2\right)+2}{4 (m^*+1) (3 m^*-1)\left(m^{*2}+m^*-1\right)^{3/2} \sqrt{(m^*-1)\sigma^2_\epsilon}}\geq0 $$
    (21)

    and thus \(\Uppi^{P*}\) is increasing in \(\sigma^{2}_{u}\).

    Differentiating (19) with respect to θ, substituting for \(\Updelta^{'}(\theta)\) and θ yields

    $$ \sqrt{ \Upsigma \Uppsi\sigma^{2}_{u}}\left(\frac{m^{*2}\sqrt{-\left(1-m^*-m^{*2}\right)}}{4(1+m^*)}\right)\geq0. $$
    (22)

    Thus \(\Uppi^{A*}\) is increasing in non fundamental precision, \(1/\sigma^{2}_{\epsilon}\).

    First, replace \(\theta =(\sigma^{2}_{u}/(\sigma_{u}^{2}+\sigma^{2}_{\epsilon}))\) and differentiate (19) with respect to σ 2 u . Then, replace m*'(θ) with \(\Updelta'(\sigma_{u}^{2}/(\sigma_{u}^{2}+\sigma^{2}_{\epsilon}))\) and \(\sigma^{2}_{u}=(m^*-1)(1+m^*)^2\sigma^2_{\epsilon}\), which yields for m ≥ 1

    $$ \sqrt{\frac{\Upsigma\Uppsi}{\sigma^2_\epsilon} }\left(\frac{m (m+2) \sqrt{\left(m^3-2m+1\right)}}{4 (m+1) \left(m^2+m-1\right)^2}\right)\geq 0. $$

    Thus \(\Uppi^{A*}\) is increasing in \(\sigma^{2}_{u}\).

\(\square\)

Proof of Corollary 2

Price efficiency is computed as:

$$V(v|P_{m})=V(v)-cov(v,P_{m})^{2}/V(P_{m})=\Upsigma -\frac{\beta_{m}^2 \Upsigma ^2}{m^2 \gamma_{m} ^2 \sigma_u^2/\theta +2 m \gamma_{m}\sigma_u^2+\beta_{m} ^2 \Upsigma/\Uppsi +\sigma_u^2}. $$

Using the coefficients given in Lemma 1, we obtain

$$ V(v|P^{*})=\Upsigma-\Upsigma \Uppsi/2. $$

\(\square\)

Proof of Corollary 3

Uninformed traders’ losses are the sum of the profits of the proprietary trader and the analyst, or

$$L(\theta)=\Uppi^{A*}(\theta)+\Uppi^{P*}(\theta). $$

Losses are minimized by setting the first order condition to zero, or

$$ 0=\frac{\sqrt{\Upsigma\Uppsi \sigma_u^2 }}{4}\left(m^{*}\left(m^{*} (2 \theta-1-(1-\theta)m^{*}) -2(1-\theta) \theta m^{*'}(\theta)\right)\left((1+(1-\theta)m^{*}(m^{*}+2)\right)^{\frac{3}{2}}\right). $$

Replacing m*' with (17) and simplifying,

$$\theta^*=\frac{(m^*+1)^2(3m^{*}-1)}{(3 m^{*} (m^{*}+2)+1)m^{*}}.$$

Using (14) and \(\theta=\sigma_u^2/(\sigma^2_{u}+\sigma^2_{\epsilon})\), we have \(\sigma_u^{2*}=9\sigma^2_{\epsilon}\) or θ* = 9/10 and m* = 2. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 2

Let \(K=\left(\frac{\sigma_u^2}{(1+ m)^2 \Upsigma + \sigma^2(1+ m (3 + m))}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}\). Solving for FME following Lemma 1 gives

$$ \beta_\eta = (1+m) K,\,\, \gamma_\eta = -K, \,\, \hbox{and}\,\,\lambda_\eta=\frac{\Upsigma}{(2 (1 + m) \Upsigma + (2 + m)\sigma^2)}\frac{1}{K}. $$

The difference between expressions (3) and (4) yields

$$ \left(\Upsigma\sigma_u^2\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}\left(\frac{1}{2}-\frac{\Upsigma^\frac{1}{2}((m+1)^2 \Upsigma +(m (m+3)+1) \sigma^2)^{\frac{1}{2}}}{2 (m+1)\Upsigma +(m+2) \sigma^2}\right). $$
(23)

Differentiating with respect to m, gives

$$-\frac{\Upsigma^\frac{1}{2} \sigma^2 \left((m+4) \sigma^2+4 \Upsigma\right)\left(\Upsigma \sigma_u^2\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}}{2 \left(2(m+1) \Upsigma +(m+2) \sigma^2\right)^2 ((m+1)^2 \Upsigma+(m(m+3)+1) \sigma^2)^\frac{1}{2}}\leq0. $$

Further,

  • at m = 0, (23) is equal to \(\frac{1}{2}\left(\Upsigma\sigma_u^2\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}\left(1-\left(\frac{\Upsigma}{\Upsigma+\sigma^2}\right)^\frac{1}{2}\right)>0\),

  • as m ⇒ +∞, (23) converges to \(\left(\Upsigma\sigma_u^2\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}\left(\frac{1}{2}-\frac{(\Upsigma(\Upsigma+\sigma^2))^\frac{1}{2}}{2 \Upsigma +\sigma^2}\right)>0\).

Thus ∀ m ≥ 0, (23) is positive. \(\square\)

Lemma 2

Let r m  = (m(m + 2)(1 − θ) + 1)/(m + 1)2 and define constants β m,n , γ m,n and λ m,n by \(\beta_{m,n} =( \Uppsi r_{m}\sigma_{u}^2/ (n \Upsigma) )^{1/2}, \gamma_{m,n} =-\theta/(m+1),\) and \(\lambda_{m,n} =(n\Upsigma\Uppsi/((n+1)^2 r_{m}\sigma_{u}^2))^{1/2}.\) Equilibrium demand and price schedules are

$$ X^{*}_{m,n} = \beta_{m,n}s \,\,\,\,\,\, Z^{*}_{m,n} = \gamma_{m,n} \tau \,\,\,\,\,\,P^*_{m,n} = \lambda_{m,n} (x+mz+u). $$

Proof of Lemma 2

Given the linear rules, the proprietary trader (or equivalently a representative proprietary trader) and a (representative) demand-based trader choose X m,n and Z m,n to maximize profits, that can be written as

$$ \begin{aligned} E\{(v-P_{m})x_{m}|s,m, x_{m}\} &= x_{m,n} (\Uppsi s-\lambda_{m,n} (x_{m,n}+(n-1)\bar{\beta}_{m,n}s )))\\ E\{(v -P_{m})x_{m}|\tau,m,z_{m}\} &= -z_{m,n} \lambda_{m,n} ( z_{m,n}+ (m-1)\bar{\gamma}_{m,n} \tau + \theta \tau) \end{aligned} $$

where \(\bar{\beta}_{m,n}\) and \(\bar{\gamma}_{m,n}\) are the expected trading strategies of the other n − 1 proprietary traders, and m − 1 demand-based traders, respectively. Taking first order conditions and substituting \(\bar{\gamma}_{m,n}\) with γ m,n and \(\bar{\beta}_{m,n}\) with β m,n gives

$$\beta_{m,n}=\frac{\Uppsi}{(n+1)\lambda_{m,n}} \,\,\,\hbox{and}\,\,\, \gamma_{m,n}=-\frac{\theta}{m+1}. $$
(24)

The market clearing condition, P = λ m,n y = E{v|y} implies

$$ \lambda_{m,n} = \frac{ n\beta_{m,n} \Upsigma }{(n^2\beta_{m,n}^2 \Upsigma)/\Uppsi+\sigma_u^2\left(\frac{m^2 \gamma_{m,n} ^2}{\theta}+ 2 m\gamma_{m,n} +1\right)}. $$
(25)

Solving (24) and (25) subject to the second order condition λ m,n  > 0 gives the equilibrium. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 3

  1. (i)

    From Lemma 2, the expected profit of an individual demand-based trader in a market with a total of m demand-based traders and n proprietary traders, \(\Uppi^{D}_{i,m,n}\) is

    $$\Uppi^{D}_{i,m,n}=\frac{\theta \lambda_{m,n} \sigma_{u}^2}{(m+1)^2},$$
    (26)

    leaving a demand-based trader indifferent between buying and not buying information at \(c=\frac{\theta\lambda_{m,n} \sigma_{u}^2}{(m+1)^2}\). Using Lemma 2, substitute for λ m,n , yielding

    $$c_{m,n}=\frac{\theta}{(m+1)(n+1)} \left(\frac{n \Upsigma \Uppsi\sigma_u^2}{m (m+2) (1-\theta )+1}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}. $$
    (27)

    The expected profit of an individual proprietary trader in a market with a total of m demand-based traders and n proprietary traders, \(\Uppi^{P}_{i,m,n}\) is

    $$\Uppi^{P}_{i,m,n}=\frac{\Upsigma \Uppsi }{(n+1)^2 \lambda_{m,n} },$$
    (28)

    making a trader indifferent between buying and not buying fundamental information at \(\xi=\frac{\Upsigma\Uppsi}{(n+1)^2 \lambda_{m,n} }\). Substituting for λ m,n , we get

    $$\xi_{m,n}=\left(\frac{\Upsigma \Uppsi\sigma_u^2}{n}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}\frac{((1+m (m+2)(1-\theta))^\frac{1}{2}}{(n+1) (m+1)}. $$
    (29)

    The analyst’s profits are equal to the sum of the proprietary and demand based sales, or \(\Uppi^{A}_{m,n}=(n-1)\xi_{m,n}+mc_{m,n}\). The analyst maximizes profits by choosing m and n optimally. Taking the first order condition of \(\Uppi^{A}_{m,n}\) in m and n and simplifying yields the implicit expressions for the optimal number of proprietary and demand-based traders (\(\hat{n}\) and \(\hat{m}\), respectively)

    $$ \hat{m} \theta (-\hat{n}(\hat{m} (\hat{n}-4)+\hat{n}-7)+\hat{m}+2) +(\hat{m}+1)^2((\hat{n}-4) \hat{n}-1)= 0 $$
    (30)
    $$ \hat{m} (1-\theta)\left(2+\hat{m}-(\hat{m}+1)^2 \hat{n}\right)+1=0. $$
    (31)

    Solving (31) for \(\hat{n}\) gives

    $$ \hat{n}=\frac{\hat{m}(\hat{m}+2) (1-\theta )+1}{\hat{m} (\hat{m}+1)^2 (1-\theta )}.$$
    (32)

    Applying (32) into (30) and simplifying gives

    $$ \frac{(\hat{m}(\hat{m}+2) (1-\theta)+1)^2 (1-\hat{m} (\hat{m} (\hat{m}+5)+3)(1-\theta))}{\hat{m}^2 (\hat{m}+1)^3 (1-\theta)^2}=0. $$
    (33)

    Denote \(\tilde{\Upgamma}(\theta,\hat{m})=0\) where

    $$\tilde{\Upgamma}(\theta,m)=(m (m+2) (1-\theta)+1)^2 (1-m (m (m+5)+3)(1-\theta )). $$
    (34)

    Differentiating \(\tilde{\Upgamma}(\theta,m)\) in m gives

    $$ (1-\theta ) (m (m+2)(1-\theta )+1) \times (m (m (55 \theta-m (7m+40) (1-\theta ) -58)-6(4-3 \theta))+1). $$
    (35)

    Solving \(\tilde{\Upgamma}(\theta,\hat{m})=0\) for θ gives the two (unique) roots below, with only (36) feasible.

    $$ \begin{aligned} \theta&= \frac{(\hat{m}+1)^2}{\hat{m} (\hat{m}+2)}>1\,\, \hbox{and} \\ \theta&= \frac{(\hat{m}+1) (\hat{m} (\hat{m}+4)-1)}{\hat{m} (\hat{m}(\hat{m}+5)+3)}. \end{aligned} $$
    (36)

    Substituting (36) into (35) yields

    $$ -\frac{(\hat{m}+1)^2(\hat{m}+3) (\hat{m}+5)^2 (3 \hat{m}+1)}{\hat{m} (\hat{m}(\hat{m}+5)+3)^3}<0. $$
    (37)

    Thus \(\hat{m}\) and \(\hat{n}\) are unique.

  2. (ii)

    Rewriting (30) and (31) in matrix form:

    $$ \phi = \left[{\begin{array}{cc} \phi_{1}(m,n,\theta) &\phi_{2}(m,n,\theta) \\\end{array} } \right]=\left[ {\begin{array}{cc} 0 & 0 \\\end{array} } \right] $$

    The Jacobian matrix of ϕ in m and n is

    $$ J_{\phi}(m,n) = \left[{\begin{array}{cc} \frac{\partial\phi_{1}}{\partial m}(m,n,\theta)& \frac{\partial\phi_{1}}{\partial n}(m, n,\theta) \\\frac{\partial\phi_{2}}{\partial m}(m, n,\theta) &\frac{\partial\phi_{2}}{\partial n}( m, n,\theta) \\ \end{array} }\right] $$

    where

    $$ \begin{aligned}\frac{\partial\phi_{1}}{\partial m}( m, n,\theta) &= 2 (m ((n - 4) n- 1) - 1) (1 - \theta) + n (7 \theta-8 + n (2 - \theta))\\\frac{\partial\phi_{1}}{\partial n}( m, n,\theta) &= 2 (n-2)(m+1)^2+m \theta (4 m-2n (m+1) +7) \\\frac{\partial\phi_{2}}{\partial m}( m, n,\theta) &= (m+1) (2-3 mn-n) (1-\theta) \\ \frac{\partial\phi_{2}}{\partial n}( m,n,\theta) &= -m (m+1)^2 (1-\theta). \end{aligned} $$

    The Jacobian matrix of ϕ in θ is

    $$ J_{\phi}(\theta) = \left[\begin{array}{c} \frac{\partial\phi_{1}}{\partial\theta}(m,n,\theta) \\ \frac{\partial\phi_{2}}{\partial\theta}(m, n,\theta)\end{array} \right] = \left[ \begin{array}{c} m (m-n (m(n-4)+n-7)+2) \\ m \left(n (m+1)^2-m-2\right) (2 \theta -1)+1\end{array} \right]. $$

    The determinant of \(J_{\phi}(\hat{m},\hat{n})\), is

    $$\frac{\partial\phi_{1}}{\partial m}( m, n,\theta)\times\frac{\partial\phi_{2}}{\partial n}( m,n,\theta)-\frac{\partial\phi_{1}}{\partial n}( m, n,\theta)\times\frac{\partial\phi_{2}}{\partial m}( m, n,\theta). $$
    (38)

    Substituting (32) and (36) into (38) and simplifying yields

    $$ \frac{(m+1) (m+3) (m+5)^2(3 m+1)}{m (m (m+5)+3)^2}. $$
    (39)

    Expression (36) positive (θ > 0) implies \(m>\sqrt{5}-2\), and the determinant is always different from zero. Applying the implicit function theorem,

    $$ \eta(\theta) = \left[{\begin{array}{c} \frac{\partial\hat{m}}{\partial\theta}(\theta) \\\frac{\partial\hat{n}}{\partial\theta}(\theta) \\ \end{array} }\right]=-[J_{\phi}(m,n)]^{-1} [J_{\phi}(\theta)]. $$

    Using the expressions for \(\hat{n}\) and θ ((32) and (36), respectively) and simplifying in the expressions of \(\frac{\partial\hat{m}}{\partial\theta}(\theta)\) and \(\frac{\partial\hat{n}}{\partial\theta}(\theta)\) gives

    $$ \begin{aligned}\frac{\partial\hat{m}}{\partial\theta}(\theta) &= \frac{m^2 (m(m+5)+3)^2}{(m+3) (3 m+1)}> 0 \\\frac{\partial\hat{n}}{\partial\theta}(\theta) &= -\frac{4 m^2 (m(m+5)+3)^2}{(m+1)^2 (m+3) (3 m+1)}< 0. \end{aligned} $$

    Thus \(\hat{m}\) is increasing in θ and \(\hat{n}\) is decreasing in θ.

    Further:

    • at θ = 0, from (36) and (30), \(\hat{m}=\sqrt{5}-2\approx0.236\), and \(\hat{n}=2+\sqrt{5}\approx4.236\)

    • \(\lim_{\theta\rightarrow 1}\pi^{A}_{m,n}=\frac{m \sigma_u \sqrt{n \Upsigma \Uppsi }}{mn+m+n+1}+\frac{(n-1)\sigma_u \sqrt{\Upsigma\Uppsi}}{(m+1) (n+1)\sqrt{n}}\), which is increasing in m.

    Thus profits are maximized at \(\hat{m} \rightarrow\infty\) and \(\hat{n}=1\).

  3. (iii)

    Substituting m = 1 into (31) and using (30), we solve for θ and find \(\bar{\theta}=8/9\).

    To prove \(\hat{m}\) and \(\hat{n}\) characterize a global maximum, define the Hessian matrix

    $$ H(m,n) = \left[{\begin{array}{cc} \frac{\partial^2\Uppi^{A}}{\partial m^2}\left(m,n,\theta\right)& \frac{\partial^2\Uppi^{A}}{\partial m\partial n}(m, n,\theta) \\ \frac{\partial^2{\Uppi^{A}}}{\partial n\partial m}(m, n,\theta) & \frac{\partial^{2}\Uppi^{A}}{\partial n^2}( m,n,\theta) \\ \end{array} } \right]. $$

    Substituting for \(\hat{n}\) and θ and simplifying yields

    $$ H(\hat m)=\left(\frac{\Upsigma \sigma^2_u\Uppsi}{\hat{m}(\hat{m}+5)+3}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}\frac{(\hat {m}+1)}{(\hat {m}+3) (\hat {m}+5)^2} \left[ \begin{array}{cc}-\frac{(\hat m (\hat m+4)-1) (\hat m (3 \hat m+14)+3) }{2 \hat m^2(\hat m+1)^2} &-\frac{(\hat m (\hat m+4)-1) }{2 \hat m} \\-\frac{(\hat m (\hat m+4)-1) }{2 \hat m} &-\frac{(\hat m+1)^2(\hat m+7) }{8} \end{array} \right]. $$

    Define

    $$G(\hat m)=\left[\begin{array}{cc}-\frac{(\hat m (\hat m+4)-1) (\hat m (3 \hat m+14)+3) }{2 \hat m^2(\hat m+1)^2} & -\frac{(\hat m(\hat m+4)-1) }{2 \hat m} \\-\frac{(\hat m (\hat m+4)-1) }{2 \hat m} & -\frac{(\hat {m}+1)^2 (\hat {m}+7) }{8}\end{array}\right].$$

    \(\hat{m}> \sqrt{5}-2\Rightarrow -\frac{(\hat m (\hat m+4)-1) (\hat m (3 \hat m+14)+3)}{2 \hat m^2 (\hat m+1)^2}<0\) and the determinant of \(G(\hat m)\) is \(\frac{(m+5)^2 (3 m+1) (m(m+4)-1)}{16 m^2}>0\). Thus the Hessian is negative definite. Given \(\hat{m}\) and \(\hat{n}\) are unique, \(\Uppi^{A}\) attains a global maximum at \(\hat{m}\) and \(\hat{n}\). \(\square\)

Proof of Corollary 4

  1. (i)

    Replacing \(\hat{n}\) using (32) and θ using (36) into the expression of the uninformed traders’ losses, \(L_{\hat{m},\hat{n}}(\theta)\) (that is, total profits of demand-based and the proprietary traders) yields

    $$ \sqrt{\Upsigma \Uppsi\sigma_u^2}\left(\frac{(\hat{m}(\theta)+1) (\hat{m}(\theta)+4)}{2(\hat{m}(\theta)+3) \sqrt{\hat{m}(\theta)(\hat{m}(\theta)+5)+3}}\right). $$
    (40)

    Differentiating the above expression in θ yields

    $$ \frac{(\hat{m} (\hat{m}(\hat{m}+10)+27)+6) \hat{m}'(\theta )}{4 (\hat{m}+3)^2 (\hat{m}(\hat{m}+5)+3)^{3/2}}>0. $$
    (41)

    Thus uninformed traders’ losses are minimized at θ = 0.

  2. (ii)

    Price efficiency, the inverse of \(Var(v|P_{m,n} )=\Upsigma-\frac{n \Upsigma \Uppsi }{n+1}\), is increasing in nn is decreasing in θ, and thus price efficiency is maximized at θ = 0.Footnote 31 From expression (41) the uninformed traders’ losses are increasing in θ, when there are \(\hat{n}\) fundamental traders and \(\hat{m}\) demand-based traders. From Corollary 3, the uninformed traders’ losses are minimized at θ = 9/10 when the analyst does not have fundamental information.

    From (30) and (36),

    • At \(\theta=0,\hat{m}=\sqrt{5}-2\approx 0.236\), and \(\hat{n}=2+\sqrt{5}\approx4.236\). The uninformed traders’ losses are \(L_{\hat{m},\hat{n}}(\theta)=\frac{\left(\sqrt{5}-1\right)\sqrt{2+\sqrt{5}}}{3+\sqrt{5}\sqrt{1+\sqrt{5}\left(\sqrt{5}-2\right)}}\approx 0.393\).

    • At \(\theta=9/10, \hat{n}\approx2.941\) and \(\hat{m}\approx 1.061\). The uninformed traders’ losses are \(L_{\hat{m},\hat{n}}(\theta)\approx0.418\)

    • At \(\theta\rightarrow 1,\hat{m} \rightarrow \infty\) and \(\hat{n}=1\). The uninformed traders’ losses are \(L_{\hat{m},\hat{n}}(\theta)=1/2\).

    When the analyst has only non fundamental information, the uninformed traders’ losses are

    • L(θ) = 1/2 at \(\theta \in \{0,1\}\) and

    • \(L(\theta)=1/\sqrt{5}\approx 0.447\) at θ = 9/10, the level at which losses are minimized.

    Therefore the uninformed traders’ losses are always lower when the analyst also has fundamental information. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 4

From Lemma 2, the price sensitivity with two proprietary traders and m demand-based traders is equal to

$$\lambda_{m}=\frac{\sqrt{2}}{3}\left(\frac{\Upsigma\Uppsi}{\sigma_u^2}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}} \left(\frac{(m+1)^2}{(m(m+2) (1-\theta )+1)}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}. $$
(42)

Using (11), and replacing λ with (42)

$$ c_m =\frac{\sqrt{2}\theta}{3 (m+1)}\left(\frac{\Upsigma \Uppsi\sigma_u^2}{m (m+2) (1-\theta )+1}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}. $$

Taking the FOC of the analyst’s (proprietary and demand-based) profits with respect to m

$$ \frac{\sqrt{\Upsigma\sigma^2_u \Uppsi }}{3 \sqrt{2}}\left(\frac{\theta \sqrt{1+m (m+2)(1-\theta )} \left(1-m^2 (2 m+3) (1-\theta )\right) }{\left((m+1)^3-m (m+1) (m+2) \theta \right)^2}\right)=0. $$
(43)

Therefore the optimal number of demand-based traders and fees, when there are two proprietary traders are implicitly defined by the following equations

$$ 0 = 1-(m^{**})^2 (2m^{**}+3) (1-\theta )\\ $$
(44)
$$ c^{**} =\frac{\sqrt{2}\theta}{3 (m^{**}+1)} \left(\frac{\Upsigma \Uppsi\sigma_u^2}{m^{**} (m^{**}+2) (1-\theta )+1}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}.$$
(45)

Taking n as exogenous, we differentiate the uninformed traders’ losses in θ. It yields after simplifying:

$$ \frac{m^2\left(-\frac{n}{m (m+2) (\theta -1)-1}\right)^{3/2} \left(-\frac{2\theta \left((m+1)^2 n-m-2\right)}{(m+1) (3 m n+n-2)}+m (\theta-1)+2 \theta -1\right)}{2 n (n+1)}=0. $$
(46)

Solving (31) and (46), we obtain:

$$ \begin{aligned} \theta&= \frac{4 n^2+4 n+1}{(n+1) (4 n+1)}\\ m &= \frac{n+1}{n}.\end{aligned} $$
  • When n = 1, θ* = 9/10 and m* = 2. Uninformed traders’ losses are equal to \(1/\sqrt{5}\approx0.447\). For θ = 0 and θ = 1, L(θ) = 1/2.

  • When n = 2, θ** = 25/27≈ 0.926 and m** = 3/2. Uninformed traders’ losses are equal to 4/9 ≈0.444. For θ = 9/10, uninformed traders’ losses are approximately equal to 0.445 and for θ = 0 and θ = 1, uninformed traders’ losses are \(\sqrt2/3\approx 0.471\).

Thus \(\Uppi^{D}(m^{*})+\Uppi^P(m^{*})\geq \Uppi^{D}(m^{**})+2\Uppi^{P}(m^{**})\). Given that the maximum fee the proprietary trader can extract from the analyst is

$$ \bar{f}=\Uppi^{D}(m^{**})+\Uppi^{P}(m^{**})-\Uppi^{D}(m^{*}) $$

it follows that \(\Uppi^{P}(m^{*})\geq \Uppi^P(m^{**})+\bar{f}\), and thus the proprietary trader does not sell fundamental information. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 5

Since \(\Uppi^{D}(m^{*})+\Uppi^P(m^{*})\geq\Uppi^{D}(m^{**})+2\Uppi^{P}(m^{**})\), interdivisional sharing cannot increase overall profits. \(\square\)

Proof of Proposition 6

Let the linear demand functions of the proprietary trader and demand-based traders be denoted x 2 = β2 v + b 2 p 1 and z 2 = γ2 τ2 + g 2 p 1 with conditional expectations

$$ \begin{array}{lll}E^P(\tau|v,y_1) =\kappa v + \omega p_1; & E^P(u_2|v,y_1) = k v + wp_1= \theta \kappa v + \theta \omega p_1\\ E^D(v|\tau,y_1) = \phi\tau+ \zeta p_1; & E^M(v|y_1,y_2) = p_2 = d_2 p_1 + \lambda_2 y_2.\end{array} $$
(47)

Then, writing the proprietary trader’s objective function, replacing for the expressions of p 2y 2u 2 and taking expectations, we have

$$ \begin{aligned}E((v-p_2)x_2|v,p_1) &= E(v-\lambda_2 y_2 - d_2 p_1) x_2\\ &=(v-\lambda_2(x_2 + m(\gamma_2 (\kappa v + \omega p_1 )+ g_2 p_1) +k v + w p_1)-d_2 p_1)x_2. \end{aligned} $$

Differentiating, setting equal to zero, and solving for β2 and b 2 gives

$$ \begin{aligned} \beta_2&= \frac{1 - \lambda_2 \kappa (\theta + \gamma_2 m)}{2 \lambda_2}\\b_2 &= -\frac{d_2 + \lambda_2(\theta\omega + m (g_2+ \gamma_2\omega))}{2 \lambda_2}. \end{aligned} $$

The SOC confirms λ2 > 0.

Doing the same for an individual demand-based trader, we have

$$ \begin{aligned} E((v-p_2) z_2| \tau, p_1) =& (v- (\lambda_2(x_2+z_2' (m-1)+z_2+u_2)+d_2 p_1) )z_2\\ =& \left(\zeta p_1 + \phi \tau - (\lambda_2(\beta_2 (\zeta p_1 + \phi \tau) + b_2 p_1 +\right.\\&\left.(\gamma_{2i} \tau + g_{2i} p_1) (m - 1) + z_2 + \theta \tau)+ d_2 p_1)\right) z_2. \end{aligned} $$

Differentiating, substituting symmetric demand functions for all demand-based traders, setting equal to zero, and solving for γ2 and g 2 gives

$$ \begin{aligned} \gamma_2&= { \frac{2 \theta \lambda_2 - \phi (1 +\theta\kappa\lambda_2)}{\lambda_2 (m \kappa \phi - 2 (1 + m))}}\\g_2 &= \frac{-d_2+\zeta + \lambda_2(\theta\omega + \gamma_2 m \omega+ \zeta \kappa(\theta + \gamma_2 m ))}{(2+m)\lambda_2}\end{aligned} $$

The SOC confirms λ2 > 0.

Turning to the first period problem, the proprietary trader maximizes total expected profits, or E{(v − p 1)x 1 + (v − p 2)x 2}. Using the expressions above and appropriate substitutions leads to the following optimization program

$$ \begin{aligned}&(v-\lambda_1 x_1)x_1 + (v-(\lambda_2(\beta_2 v + b_2 \lambda_1x_1)+ m(\gamma_2(\kappa v+\omega\lambda_1 x_1)+\\ & \quad g_2\lambda_1 x_1)+ (\theta\kappa v + \theta\omega\lambda_1 x_1))+d_2\lambda_1 x_1)(\beta_2 v + b_2\lambda_1 x_1). \end{aligned}$$

the FOC to zero yields

$$ \beta_1 = -{ \frac{(-1+b_2 \lambda_1 (-1 + \lambda_2 (2 \beta_2 + \kappa (\theta+\gamma_2 m)) + \beta_2 \lambda_1 (d_2 + \lambda_2 (\omega(\theta +\gamma_2 m)+ g_2 m )))}{2\lambda_1 (1 + b_2 \lambda_1 (d_2 +\lambda_2 (b_2 + \theta\omega + m(g_2 + \gamma_2 \omega))))}}.$$

The SOC confirms 2 λ1 (− b 2 λ12 (b 2 + γ2 m ω + g 2 m + θ ω) + d 2) − 1) < 0.

Similarly an individual demand based trader optimizes total expected profits, which can be written as

$$ \begin{aligned}&-\lambda_1 ((m - 1) z_1^{\prime} + z_1) z_1 +((\zeta (\lambda_1 ((m - 1)z_1^{\prime} + z_1)) + \phi \tau) - (\lambda_2 ((\beta_2 (\zeta (\lambda_1((m -1) z_1^{\prime} \\ & \quad + z_1)) + \phi \tau) + b_2 (\lambda_1 ((m -1) z_1^{\prime} + z_1)) ) + (\gamma_2 \tau + g_2 (\lambda_1 ((m - 1) z_1^{\prime} +z_1))) m + \theta \tau) \\ & \quad +d_2 (\lambda_1 ((m - 1) z_1^{\prime} +z_1)))) (\gamma_2 \tau + g_2 (\lambda_1 ((m - 1) z_1^{\prime} + z_1))).\end{aligned} $$

Differentiating, substituting, setting equal to zero, and recognizing the symmetry in demand-based strategies, yields

$$ \gamma_1 = {\frac{-\gamma_2 (d_2 - \zeta + \lambda_2 (b_2 + 2 g_2 m + \beta_2\zeta)) + g_2 (\phi - \lambda_2 (\theta + \beta_2 \phi))}{1 + m (1+ 2 g_2 \lambda_1 (d_2 - \zeta + \lambda_2 (b_2 + g_2 m +\beta_2\zeta)))}}. $$
(48)

The SOC confirms \(2 \lambda_1 (-C_2 \lambda_1(\lambda_2 (\beta_2 \zeta+b_2+g_2 m)+d_2-\zeta)-1)<0\).

Using the projection theorem to calculate the conditional expectations in (47) yields

$$ \begin{aligned} \phi =& -\frac{\gamma_1 m}{\lambda_1(\beta_1^2 \Upsigma + \sigma_u^2)} \, \zeta = \frac{\beta_1 \Upsigma}{\lambda_1(\beta_1^2 \Upsigma + \sigma_u^2)} \quad\quad \kappa =-\frac{ \beta_1\gamma_1 m }{\gamma^2_1 m^2 + \theta} \\ \omega =& \frac{\gamma_1 m}{\lambda_1(\gamma^2_1 m^2 + \theta)} \, \lambda_1= \frac{\theta \beta_1 \Upsigma}{\theta(\beta_1^2 \Upsigma + \sigma_u^2)+ \gamma_1^2 m^2 \sigma_u^2}. \\ \lambda_2 =& \frac{(\gamma_1 m^2(-\beta_2 \gamma_1 + \beta_1 \gamma_2) - \theta(\beta_2 - \beta_1 \gamma_1 m) )\Upsigma} {2\beta_1\beta_2 \gamma_1 m (\gamma_2 m + \theta)\Upsigma - \gamma_2 m(\gamma_2 m + 2 \theta) (\beta^2_1 \Upsigma + \sigma_u^2)- \gamma_1^2 m^2 (\sigma_u^2(1-\theta)+\beta_2^2 \Upsigma) - \theta(\beta_1^2+\beta_2^2)\Upsigma+\sigma_u^2)} \\ d_2 =& \Upsigma (-\beta_1 \gamma_2 m (\gamma_1 m \lambda_1 (b_2+g_2 m)+2 \theta )-\beta_1 \theta (\gamma_1 m \lambda_1 (b2+g_2 m)+1)\\ &-\beta_1 \gamma_2^2 m^2+\beta_2 \gamma_1^2 b_2 m^2 \lambda_1+\beta_2 \gamma_1^2 g_2 m^3 \lambda_1+\beta_2 \gamma_1 m (\gamma_2 m+\theta )+\beta_2 b_2 \theta \lambda_1+\beta_2 g_2 m \theta \lambda_1)/ \\ & (\lambda_1 \left(-\theta \left(\left(\beta_1^2+\beta_2^2\right)\Upsigma +\sigma_u^2\right)-\gamma_2^2 m^2 \left(\beta_1^2 \Upsigma +\sigma_u^2\right)-2 \gamma_2 m \theta \left(\beta_1^2 \Upsigma +\sigma_u^2\right)\right.\\ &+2 \beta_1 \beta_2 \gamma_1 m \Upsigma (\gamma_2 m+\theta )-\gamma_1^2 m^2 \left(\sigma_u^2 (1-\theta)+\beta_2^2 \Upsigma \right)). \end{aligned} $$

Using conjectures of γ1 = 0 and d 2 = 1, substitute, simplify, and solve for equilibrium. Without first period trading by the demand-based traders, the proprietary trader does not update his priors on u 2, and demand-based traders do not update beyond p 1, and

$$ \begin{array}{ll} E^P(\tau|v,y_1)=E(\tau)=0 \rightarrow \kappa=0; \omega=0; k=0; w=0\\ E^D(v|\tau,y_1)=E(v|y_1)=p_1 \quad \rightarrow \phi=0; \zeta=1.\\ \end{array} $$

Substituting, solve for the remaining parameters.

$$ \begin{array}{llllll} \beta_1 &= \frac{\lambda_1-2\lambda_2}{\lambda_1^2 - 4 \lambda_1\lambda_2}\,\,\,\,\,\,\,& \lambda_1 & = \frac{\beta_1 \Upsigma}{\beta_1^2 \Upsigma + \sigma_u^2}\,\,\,\,\,\, & \gamma_2 &= -\frac{\theta}{(1+m)}\\ g_2 &= 0 & \beta_2 &= \frac{1}{2\lambda_2} & b_2 &= -\frac{1}{2\lambda_2}\\ \end{array} $$
(49)
$$ \lambda_2 = \frac{(1+m)}{2}\left(\frac{\Upsigma}{(1+m(2+m)(1-\theta))(\beta_1^2 \Upsigma +\sigma_u^2)}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}. $$

The inequalities to verify are

$$ \begin{aligned} \frac{\lambda_1 (\lambda_1-4 \lambda_2)}{2 \lambda_2}<&0 \\ \lambda_1>&0 \\ \lambda_2>&0. \end{aligned} $$

Replacing the above parameters in expressions (49) and (48) yields d 2 = 1 and γ1 = 0. Conjecture \(\beta_1=q (\sigma_{u}^2/\Upsigma)^{1/2}\), where q ≥ 0 (as β1 > 0 given λ1 > 0). Substituting all the above parameters from (49) in the expression of β1 and simplifying yields:

$$ q=-\frac{\left(q^2+1\right) \left(q \sqrt{\left(q^2+1\right) (m (m+2) (1-\theta )+1)}-(m+1) \left(q^2+1\right)\right)}{q \left(2 (m+1) \left(q^2+1\right)-q \sqrt{\left(q^2+1\right) (m (m+2) (1-\theta )+1)}\right)}. $$

Rearranging the terms implies

$$ (m+1) q^4+q \sqrt{\left(-q^2-1\right) (m (m+2) (\theta -1)-1)}-m-1=0. $$
(50)

Differentiating the left hand side (LHS) yields

$$ 4 (m+1) q^3+\frac{\left(2 q^2+1\right)\sqrt{\left(q^2+1\right)(m(m+2) (1-\theta ))}}{q^2+1}. $$
(51)

The derivative (51) is positive for q ≥ 0. For q = 0, the LHS of (50) is equal to −(1 + m) and for \(q\rightarrow +\infty\), the LHS of (50) goes to m + 1. Thus there exists a unique q satisfying (50). \(\square\)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Cheynel, E., Levine, C.B. Analysts’ sale and distribution of non fundamental information. Rev Account Stud 17, 352–388 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-012-9183-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-012-9183-x

Keywords

Navigation