Skip to main content
Log in

Divisional performance measurement and transfer pricing for intangible assets

  • Published:
Review of Accounting Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the effectiveness of three transfer pricing methodologies for an intangible asset that is developed through bilateral, sequential investment. In general, a royalty-based transfer price that can be renegotiated provides better investment incentives than either a non-negotiable royalty-based transfer price or a purely negotiated transfer price, and in some cases induces first-best investment. This result contrasts with previous research that finds that the inability to limit renegotiation of initial contracts reduces investment efficiency. Further, I examine how tax transfer pricing rules inform optimal internal transfer prices when the firm decouples internal and external transfer prices.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A large body of literature examines the effects of tax transfer pricing rules on worldwide resource allocation and production decisions in a centralized firm. Halperin and Srinidhi (1987), Korn and Lengsfeld (2005), Harris and Sansing (1998), Smith (2002a), and Sansing (1999) are examples. Halperin and Srinidhi (1991) and Smith (2002b) extend this analysis to a decentralized firm in which divisional managers make production, but not investment decisions.

  2. See Williamson (1985) for more on the hold-up problem.

  3. Chung (1991), Aghion, Dewatripont, and Rey (1994), and others examine the roles of option contracts and bargaining to solve the hold-up problem with simultaneous investments.

  4. Hirshleifer (1956) shows that efficiency is achieved in this setting when markets are competitive if the transfer price is set at marginal cost. Baldenius and Reichelstein (2006), Vaysman (1998), and others have extended this work.

  5. See also Baldenius, Reichelstein, and Sahay (1999), Baldenius (2000), Sahay (2003) and Anctil and Dutta (1999), who explore the effectiveness of various transfer pricing methodologies in settings with specific investments and bilateral trade.

  6. See Smirnov and Wait (2004) for a discussion of achievable efficiency outcomes in simultaneous vs. sequential investment scenarios.

  7. Ernst and Young (2003) Global Transfer Pricing Survey.

  8. Survey results indicate that among a ‘best practices’ group of firms with over $2 billion in annual revenues, “77% use separate reporting systems to track internal pricing information” (Springsteel, 1999). See Durst (2002) for a more extensive discussion of the costs and benefits of decoupling.

  9. See Sahay (2003) and Baldenius et al. (2004), for example.

  10. See, for example, Wagenhofer (1994), Vaysman (1996, 1998), and Christensen and Demski (1998).

  11. Although transfers to other divisions or Division 1’s own use of the asset are not modeled, doing so would not change the basic results of the paper unless one division’s use of the asset created externalities for other divisions.

  12. Note that this characterization is consistent with a multi-period setting in which M(I 1,I 2) represents the present value of the future cash flows generated by the intangible asset.

  13. Although lump-sum payments are permissible in some countries as tax transfer prices for intangibles, U.S. tax law favors royalty agreements, and in many instances requires firms that use lump sums to adjust their payments ex-post if actual intangible-related revenues stray too far from projected revenues (Boos, 2003). Since these adjustments essentially turn the lump sum into a variable, profit-based transfer price, I only consider a royalty-based transfer price for tax purposes.

  14. This formulation is consistent with a royalty rate calculated as a percentage of net revenue, R(I 1,I 2,q), where \({M(I_1,I_2)}=R(I_1,I_2,q)-c\cdot q\) and the quantity of the final good, q, is chosen efficiently.

  15. This characterization is consistent with a transfer price derived using the Comparable Profit Method under U.S. tax law.

  16. When \(h> 0, \alpha^{\ast}=1-(1-\hat{\alpha})t-\frac{(1-t-\hat\alpha h)} {1+\rho^{({1}/{4})}\sqrt{(1-t-h)/(1-t)}}\) where \(\rho=\frac{w^{\prime\prime}(I_2)}{v^{\prime\prime}(I_1)}\). This expression takes on a simple form for some common functional forms. If v(I)=w(I)=log(I), for example, \(\alpha^{\ast}=\frac{1} {2}(1-t)+\hat\alpha t+\frac{1}{2}\hat\alpha h\).

  17. I performed a brief numerical analysis to assess the gains from decoupling for various values of \(\hat\alpha\) and h and for various functional forms for v(·) and w(·). In some cases, decoupling did not increase profits substantially unless \(\hat\alpha\) was significantly different from the optimal level. The value of decoupling generally increased with h.

  18. See Williamson (1985), Aghion et al. (1994), Nöldeke and Schmidt (1995) and Edlin and Reichelstein (1996), for example.

  19. One exception is Edlin and Reichelstein (1995), who show that fully efficient outcomes in a bilateral investment setting with trade can only be achieved if renegotiation is allowed. In their setting, investment is efficient whether or not renegotiation occurs, but trade is generally only efficient with renegotiation.

  20. Edlin and Shannon (1998) show that for continuous, differentiable functions f(x) and g(x), if f′(x)>g′(x) for all x, the maximizer of f(·) is greater than the maximizer of g(·).

References

  • Aghion, P., Dewatripont, M., & Rey, P. (1994). Renegotiation design with unverifiable information. Econometrica, 62(2), 257–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anctil, R., & Dutta, S. (1999). Negotiated transfer pricing and divisional vs. firm-wide performance evaluation. The Accounting Review, 74(1), 87–104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldenius, T. (2000). Intrafirm trade, bargaining power and specific investments. Review of Accounting Studies, 5(1), 27–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldenius, T., Melumad, N., & Reichelstein, S. (2004). Integrating managerial and tax objectives in transfer pricing. The Accounting Review, 79(3), 591–615.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldenius, T., & Reichelstein, S. (2006). External and internal pricing in multidivisional firms. Journal of Accounting Research, forthcoming.

  • Baldenius, T., Reichelstein, S., & Sahay, S. (1999). Negotiated versus cost-based transfer pricing. Review of Accounting Studies, 4(2), 67–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boos, M. (2003). International transfer pricing: the valuation of intangible assets. Kluwer Law International.

  • Che, Y.-K., and Hausch, D. B. (1999). Cooperative investments and the value of contracting. The American Economic Review, 89(1), 125–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choe, C., & Hyde, C. (2005). Keeping two sets of books: The relationship between tax and incentive transfer prices. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 14(1), 165–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christensen, J., & Demski, J. S. (1998). Profit allocation under ancillary trade. Journal of Accounting Research, 36(1), 71–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christensen, P. O., Feltham, G. A., & Şabak, F. (2003). Dynamic incentives and responsibility accounting: A comment. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 35(3), 423–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chung, T.-Y. (1991). Incomplete contracts, specific investments, and risk sharing. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(5), 1031–1042.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durst, M. C. (2002). Management vs. tax accounting in intercompany transfer pricing. Tax Management Transfer Pricing Report, 10(21), 909–915.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutta, S., & Reichelstein, S. (2003). Leading indicator variables, performance measurement and long-term versus short-term contracts. Journal of Accounting Research, 41(5), 837–866.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edlin, A. S., & Hermalin, B. E. (2000). Contract renegotiation and options in agency problems. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 16(2), 395–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edlin, A. S., & Reichelstein, S. (1995). Specific investment under negotiated transfer pricing: An efficiency result. The Accounting Review, 70(2), 275–291.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edlin, A. S., & Reichelstein, S. (1996). Holdups, standard breach remedies, and optimal investment. The American Economic Review, 86(3), 478–501.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edlin, A. S., & Shannon, C. (1998). Strict single crossing and the strict spence-mirrlees condition: A comment on monotone comparative statistics. Econometrica, 66(6), 1417–1425.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ernst and Young. (2003). Transfer Pricing 2003 Global Survey. http://www.ey.com.

  • Grossman, S. J., & Hart, O. D. (1986). The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral integration. The Journal of Political Economy, 94(4), 691–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Halperin, R., & Srinidhi, B. (1987). The effects of the U.S. income tax regulations’ transfer pricing rules on allocative efficiency. The Accounting Review, 62(4), 686–706.

    Google Scholar 

  • Halperin, R., & Srinidhi, B. (1996). U.S. income tax transfer pricing rules for intangibles as approximations of arm’s length pricing. The Accounting Review, 71(1), 61–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Halperin, R. M., & Srinidhi, B. (1991). U.S. income tax transfer-pricing rules and resource allocation: The case of decentralized multinational firms. The Accounting Review, 66(1), 141–157.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, D. G., & Sansing, R. C. (1998). Distortions caused by the use of arm’s-length transfer prices. The Journal of the American Taxation Association, 20(Supplement), 40–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1956). On the economics of transfer pricing. Journal of Business, 29(3), 172–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Indjejikian, R., & Nanda, D. (1999). Dynamic incentives and responsibility accounting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 27(2), 177–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korn, E., & Lengsfeld, S. (2005). Duopolistic competition, taxes, and the arm’s-length principle. Working Paper

  • Lulfesmann, C. (2001). Team production, sequential investments and stochastic payoffs. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 157(3), 430–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nöldeke, G., & Schmidt, K. M. (1995). Option contracts and renegotiation: A solution to the hold-up problem. The RAND Journal of Economics, 26(2), 163–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nöldeke, G., & Schmidt, K. M. (1998). Sequential investments and options to own. The RAND Journal of Economics, 29(4), 633–653.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sahay, S. (2003). Transfer pricing based on actual cost. Journal of Management Accounting Research, 15, 177–192.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sansing, R. (1999). Relationship-specific investments and the transfer pricing paradox. Review of Accounting Studies, 4(2), 119–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smirnov, V., & Wait, A. (2004). Hold-up and sequential specific investments. The RAND Journal of Economics, 35(2), 386–400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, M. (2002a). Ex ante and ex post discretion over arm’s length transfer prices. The Accounting Review, 77(1), 161–184.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, M. (2002b). Tax and incentive trade-offs in multinational transfer pricing. Journal of Accounting, Auditing and Finance, 17(3), 209–236.

    Google Scholar 

  • Springsteel, I. (1999). Separate but unequal. CFO Magazine.

  • Vaysman, I. (1996). A model of cost-based transfer pricing. Review of Accounting Studies, 1, 73–108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vaysman, I. (1998). A model of negotiated transfer pricing. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 25(3), 349–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagenhofer, A. (1994). Transfer pricing under asymmetric information: An evaluation of alternative methods. European Accounting Review, 1, 71–104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper is a chapter from my dissertation at Stanford University. I thank my advisor, Stefan Reichelstein, for his encouragement and assistance on this project, as well as seminar participants at Stanford University, University of Texas, Austin, UCLA, University of Minnesota, London Business School, Columbia, Duke, University of Washington, University of Utah, Harvard, U.C. Berkeley, Yale, and Northwestern. I also appreciate helpful comments and suggestions from two anonymous reviewers and the paper’s RAST Conference discussant, Tim Baldenius.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Nicole Bastian Johnson.

Appendix A

Appendix A

Proof of Lemma 1

The firm’s central office chooses first-best levels of investment to maximize firm profit:

$$ (I_1^{\ast},I_2^{\ast})\in\mathop{\hbox{argmax}}\limits_{I_1,I_2}\; \{(1-t)[v(I_1)+w(I_2)-I_1-I_2]- h[{\hat \alpha}(v(I_1)+w(I_2))-I_1]\}. $$

Then I *1 , I *2 solve the following first order conditions:

$$ v^{\prime}(I_1)=\frac{1-t-h}{1-t-h{\hat \alpha}},$$
(21a)
$$ w^{\prime}(I_2)=\frac{1-t}{1-t-h{\hat \alpha}}. $$
(21b)

(A2) and the strict concavity of v(·) and w(·) guarantee an interior solution. The RHS of (21a) is decreasing in h and the RHS of (21b) is increasing in h. Then by decreasing marginal returns, I *1 is increasing in h and I *2 is decreasing in h.

Proof of Proposition 1

Assume that the investments are quasi-independent. Then first-best investments, I *1 , I *2 , satisfy

$$ v^{\prime}(I_1^{\ast})=\frac{1-t-h}{1-t-{\hat \alpha}h},\quad w^{\prime}(I_2^{\ast})=\frac{1-t}{1-t-{\hat \alpha}h}. $$

Under a uniform royalty-based transfer pricing scheme, divisional managers choose I u1 and I u2 to solve

$$ v^{\prime}(I_1^u)=\frac{1}{\hat \alpha},\quad w^{\prime}(I_2^u)=\frac{1}{1-{\hat \alpha}}. $$

(A3) and the strict concavity of v(·) and w(·) guarantee an interior solution. Since

$$ \frac{1}{\hat \alpha}> \frac{1-t-h}{1-t-{\hat \alpha}h}\quad \hbox {and}\quad \frac{1}{1-{\hat \alpha}}> \frac{1-t}{1-t-{\hat \alpha}h} $$

decreasing marginal returns imply that I *1 >I u1 and I *2 >I u2 .

Proof of Corollary to Proposition 1

Lemma 1 shows that with quasi-independent assets, I *1 is increasing in h and I *2 (I 1) is decreasing in h. Under a uniform royalty based transfer pricing system, both divisions underinvest, as shown in Proposition 1. Further, both divisions’ investments are independent of h, as can be seen from their first order conditions:

$$ v^{\prime}(I_1)=\frac{1}{\hat \alpha}, \quad w^{\prime}(I_2)=\frac{1} {1-{\hat \alpha}}.$$

The result immediately follows.

Proof of Proposition 2

When v(I)≡ w(I) and h=0, the firm’s objective is

$$ \mathop{\hbox{max}}\limits_{I_1,I_2} \{[v(I_1)+v(I_2)-I_1-I_2](1-t)\}. $$

Since the problem is symmetric and marginal returns are decreasing, firm-wide profit is optimized when I 1=I 2. The divisions will choose I 1 and I 2 to solve

$$ v^{\prime}(I_1)=\frac{1-t}{\alpha-{\hat \alpha}t},\quad w^{\prime}(I_2)=\frac{1-t}{1-\alpha-({1-\hat \alpha})t}. $$

Since v(I)=w(I), the two divisions will choose the same level of investment when they face the same marginal cost, i.e.

$$ \frac{1-t}{\alpha-{\hat \alpha}t}=\frac{1-t} {1-\alpha-({1-\hat \alpha})t}. $$
(22)

(22) implies that the optimal decoupled royalty rate, α*, is

$$ \alpha^{\ast}=\frac{1-t}{2}+{\hat \alpha}t. $$

Then when \({\hat \alpha}=\frac{1}{2},\alpha^{\ast}=\frac{1}{2}\) and there is no gain from decoupling.

Proof of Proposition 3

The available negotiation surplus will be maximized if I 2(I 1) is chosen such that

$$ I_2^{\ast}(I_1)\in\mathop{\hbox{argmax}}\limits_{I_2}\{M(I_1, I_2)(1-t-{\hat \alpha}h)-I_1(1-t-h)-I_2(1-t)\}. $$

Division 2 will choose I 2(I 1) so that

$$ \hat{I}_2(I_1)\in\mathop{\hbox{argmax}}\limits_{I_2}\{M(I_1, I_2)[(1-\beta)-(1-{\hat \alpha})t)]-I_2(1-t)\}. $$

Then Division 2 will invest efficiently if the post-negotiation royalty rate, β, solves

$$ 1-t-{\hat \alpha}h=1-\beta-(1-{\hat \alpha})t, $$

which implies \(\beta={\hat \alpha}(t+h)\).

Given that Division 2 will invest efficiently ex-post, Division 1 chooses I 1 such that

$$ \hat{I_1}\in\mathop{\hbox{argmax}}\limits_{I_1}\{\gamma [M(I_1,I_2^{\ast}(I_1)) (1-t-{\hat \alpha}h)-I_2^{\ast}(I_1)(1-t)]-I_1(1-t-h)\}, $$

whereas firm-wide profit is maximized when I 1 is chosen such that

$$ I_1^{\ast}\in\mathop{\hbox{argmax}}\limits_{I_1}\{M(I_1,I_2^{\ast}(I_1))(1-t-{\hat \alpha}h)-I_1(1-t-h)-I_2^{\ast}(I_1)(1-t)\}.$$

Then since \(\gamma< 1, \hat{I_1}< I_1^{\ast}\) under negotiated transfer pricing. Footnote 20

Proof of Proposition 4

Investments are quasi-independent

If the royalty scheme is carried out, Division 2’s payoff from investing I 02 is

$$ [v(I_1)+w(I_2^0)](1-\alpha-{(1-\hat \alpha)}t)-I_2^0(1-t). $$
(23)

Let \({\tilde{\alpha}}(I_1)\) be the value of α, conditional on I 1, that makes (23) equal to zero. Then

$$ {\tilde{\alpha}}(I_1)=1-(1-{\hat \alpha})t-\frac{I_2^0(1-t)} {v(I_1)+w(I_2^0)}. $$
(24)

Then for a given level of I 1, any \(\alpha> {\tilde{\alpha}}(I_1)\) will give Division 2 a negative payoff if he invests I 02 . Further, if \(\alpha>{\tilde{\alpha}}(I_1)\), Division 2 cannot improve his payoff by investing I 2>I 02 . To see why, note that Division 2’s first order condition is

$$ w^{\prime}(I_2)(1-\alpha-({1-\hat \alpha})t)-(1-t)=0. $$
(25)

Then because of the strict concavity of w(·), his marginal return from investing more than I 02 is only positive if

$$ w^{\prime}(I_2^0)(1-\alpha-({1-\hat \alpha})t)-(1-t)> 0. $$
(26)

Replacing α in (26) with \({\tilde{\alpha}}(I_1)\) from (24), we get

$$ w^{\prime}(I_2^0)\left[\frac{I_2(1-t)} {v(I_1)+w(I_2^0)}\right]-(1-t)> 0. $$
(27)

But (27) implies

$$ I_2^0\cdot w^{\prime}(I_2^0)> v(I_1)+w(I_2^0), $$
(28)

which is never true because w(·) is strictly concave and strictly increasing, which implies that I 2· w′(I 2)<w(I 2) for all I 2. Then at \(\alpha={\tilde{\alpha}}(I_1)\), Division 2 will never invest more than I 02 and will only invest I 02 if (23) is non-negative.

Now, suppose that α is set equal to \({\tilde{\alpha}}(I_1^{\ast})\) but I 1<I *1 . Plugging \({\tilde{\alpha}}(I_1^{\ast})\) from (24) into (23) gives us Division 2’s payoff from investing I 02 :

$$ \frac{I_2(1-t)[v(I_1)+w(I_2^0)]} {v(I_1^{\ast})+w(I_2^0)}-I_2^0(1-t). $$
(29)

This expression will always be negative if I 1<I *1 since v(I 1) is increasing in I 1. Then if \(\alpha={\tilde{\alpha}}(I_1^{\ast})\), (23) will always be negative (and Division 2 will not invest) unless Division 1 invests at least I *1 .

Division 1 will not invest more than I *1 since under the royalty scheme, he maximizes his payoff by choosing \(\hat{I}_1< I_1^{\ast}\) and by decreasing marginal returns, his payoff is decreasing in I 1 for \(I_1>\hat{I}_1\). He will be willing to invest exactly I *1 as long as his payoff from doing so is positive. At \(\alpha={\tilde{\alpha}}(I_1^{\ast})\), Division 1’s status quo payoff if he invests I *1 is

$$ [v(I_1^{\ast})+w(I_2^0)]({\tilde{\alpha}}(I_1^{\ast})-{\hat \alpha}(t+h))-(1-t-h)I_1^{\ast}= $$
(30a)
$$ v(I_1^{\ast})(1-t-\hat\alpha h)-I_1^{\ast}(1-t-h) + w(I_{2}^{o})(1-t-\hat\alpha h)-I_{2}^{o}(1-t)> 0. $$
(30b)

Since (30b) corresponds to the firm’s objective function and is always positive for I 1I *1 , I 2I *2 (I 1) (because of (A2)), Division 1 will invest I *1 when \(\alpha=\tilde{\alpha}(I_1^{\ast})\). In equilibrium, the internal royalty rate will be renegotiated to \(\alpha=\hat{\alpha}(t+h)\), as shown in the proof to Proposition 3, so that Division 2 will invest I *2 (I *1 ) and first best will be achieved.

Investments are substitutes: (M12<0)

For this case, I will show that I 1 = 0 at \(\alpha=\hat{\alpha}(t+h)\) and that I 1>I *1 at \(\alpha=1-(1-\hat{\alpha})t\) and then infer the result by the intermediate value theorem.

First consider the case of \(\alpha=\hat{\alpha}(t+h)\). Division 1’s payoff under the royalty agreement will be zero and Division 2 will be unwilling to renegotiate after Division 1 invests because I 2 will be efficient, leaving no gain from bargaining. Therefore Division 1 will choose I 1 = 0.

Now consider the case of \(\alpha=1-(1-\hat{\alpha})t\). In this case, Division 2’s payoff from investment is zero under the royalty agreement, so he will choose I 2 = 0 unless the agreement is renegotiated. Then Division 1’s marginal payoff is

$$ (1-\gamma)\frac{\partial}{\partial I_1}M(I_1,0)+\gamma \frac{\partial}{\partial I_1}M(I_1,I_2^{\ast}(I_1))=\frac{1-t-h}{ 1-t-\hat{\alpha}h}. $$
(31)

When γ=1, Division 1 will choose I 1=I *1 . When γ=0, Division 1’s marginal payoff is

$$ \frac{\partial}{\partial I_1}M(I_1,0)=\frac{1-t-h}{1-t-\hat{\alpha}}=\frac{\partial}{\partial I_1}M(I_1^{\ast},I_2^{\ast}(I_1^{\ast})).$$
(32)

Suppose I 1<I *1 and (32) holds. Then it follows that \(\frac{\partial}{\partial I_1}M(I_1,0)>\frac{\partial}{\partial I_1}M(I_1^{\ast},0)>\frac{\partial}{\partial I_1}M(I_1^{\ast},I_2^{\ast}(I_1^{\ast}))\), a contradiction. The first inequality holds because of decreasing marginal returns and the second because the investments are substitutes. Therefore I 1>I *1 if the investments are substitutes at γ = 0. Note that by the implicit function theorem,

$$ \hbox{sgn}(I_1^{\prime}(\gamma))=\hbox{sgn}\left(-\frac{\partial}{\partial I_1}M(I_1,0)+\frac{\partial}{\partial I_1}M(I_1,I_2^{\ast}(I_1))\right). $$
(33)

The RHS (33) is negative when the investments are substitutes, so I 1 (γ)<0.

Then when \(\alpha=1-(1-\hat{\alpha})t\), we have I 1=I *1 at γ = 1, I 1>I *1 at γ = 0 and I 1 (γ)<0, indicating that I 1>I *1 . Recall that I 1 = 0 at \(\alpha=\hat\alpha(t+h)\). Then by the intermediate value theorem, and given Assumption 1, there exists a value of α that implements first best, i.e. I 1=I *1 , when the investments are substitutes.

Proof of Proposition 5

When the investments are strict complements, Division 1’s first order condition under renegotiable royalty-based transfer pricing is

$$\begin{aligned} &\left\{\frac{\partial}{\partial I_1}M(I_1,I_2(I_1|\alpha)) +\frac{\partial}{\partial I_2} M(1_1,I_2(I_1|\alpha)I_2^{\prime}(I_1)\right\}[\alpha-\hat{\alpha}(t+h)- \gamma(1-t-\hat{\alpha}h)] \\ &\quad+\gamma\left[\frac{\partial}{\partial I_1}M(I_1,I_2^{\ast}(I_1))(1-t-\hat{\alpha}h)+I_2^{\prime}(I_1)(1-t)\right]=(1-t-h) \end{aligned} $$
(34)

and under negotiation, it is

$$ \gamma\frac{\partial}{\partial I_1}M(I_1,I_2^{\ast}(I_1))(1-t-\hat{\alpha}h)=(1-t-h).$$
(35)

When

$$ \alpha>\hat{\alpha}(t+h)+\gamma(1-t-\hat{\alpha}h),$$
(36)

the RHS of (34) is greater than the RHS of (35) for a given I, implying that when (36) holds, I 1 is higher under renegotiable royalty-based transfer pricing than under negotiation. We know from Proposition 3 that Division 1 always underinvests under negotiated transfer pricing. This result, combined with Assumption 1, implies that it is always possible to choose a value of α such that (36) holds and Division 1 invests more efficiently under the renegotiated royalty-based system than under negotiation.

(Note that the RHS of (36) is always less than 1. To see why, notice that the RHS of (36) is increasing in γ and \(\hat{\alpha}\), and that at \(\gamma=\hat{\alpha}=1\), it is equal to one. Then since γ<1 by assumption, the RHS of (36) is less than one.)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Johnson, N.B. Divisional performance measurement and transfer pricing for intangible assets. Rev Acc Stud 11, 339–365 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-006-9006-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-006-9006-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation