Skip to main content
Log in

Information, classification and contestability: a cultural economics approach to Uber’s entry into the taxi industry

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Because of their novelty, the rise of large platform companies, such as Uber, pose a genuine challenge to our attempts to classify and understand economic activities. This article utilises a broad view of cultural economics and subjectivist economic analysis to provide some clarity. We see how economic analysis is capable of dealing with companies that provide information based services, and why such industries are increasingly common. Goods, product categories and consumption rituals are all considered as social constructs, and subject to cultural interpretation. The main implication of this approach is how the prevention of exclusion and the elimination of entry barriers are both related and relevant to the well-functioning of market orders.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

Data sharing is not applicable to this article as no new data were created or analyzed in this study.

Notes

  1. See “Rules for fools”, The Economist, 14 May 2011.

  2. In 2013 the price of a New York medallion reached $1,000,000 (see Flegenheimer, 2013) but as of May 2022 the average price was just under $140,000 (Daus, 2022).

  3. One could argue that there is a third type of cultural economics, which is the study of the culture of the discipline of economics. Canonical texts for this would include Leijonhufvud (1973) and Kitch (1983).

  4. Klamer (2016) provides a “value-based approach to cultural economics”, but in doing so demonstrates how stepping outside traditional economic subject matter remains speculative and hard to operationalise.

  5. For example, Douglas and Isherwood (1979) point out that there are economies of scale from household production, for example specialisation, the proficiency from repeated tasks, bulk ordering, lower financial costs, and the network effects that result from reciprocity; not to mention the external economies of scale that result from better transport links (e.g. p.117).

  6. I appreciate an anonymous reviewer for drawing this link.

  7. In other words, a main part of the value of a taxi journey derives from being transported from one location to another. The taxi itself, is just a physical desideratum of the service being provided. Uber’s business model, compared to a traditional taxi company, makes it even clearer that this service is intangible, but is not any less meaningful due to the fact that they are not directly providing consumers with the use of a vehicle. The ownership of the vehicle is of minor economic significance, because the vehicle itself is not what is generating utility.

  8. For Hayek (1945), prices are information. For Mary Douglas, goods are information.

  9. See Schumpeter (1934, 1942).

  10. An interesting application of this point is that for niche products the quality of a review matters greatly. But for mass market products the quantity (i.e. scope) of reviews (whether positive or negative) matters more. In some cases, the fact that a product has been widely reviewed (regardless of how critical) provides the validation that it is the type of product that the consumer is interested in. Also see Zuckerman and Kim (2003).

  11. Of course, this wasn’t the only convenience that Uber, and other ride sharing apps have provided. They also dispensed with the need to establish the price, make a payment, and work out an appropriate tip.

  12. See https://finance.yahoo.com/quote/UBER?p=UBER. Accessed October 11th 2021.

  13. For a full list see https://www.uber.com/global/en/cities/. Accessed October 11th 2021.

  14. This is in contrast to regulatory arbitrage which attempts to take advantage of discrepancies between existing laws, or lobbyists who attempt to protect the business plan from regulatory constraints. On the contrary, regulatory entrepreneurs “pursue lines of business knowing that changing the legal environment is crucially important for the business’s growth, or even it’s legality, and with the intention of effecting that change. Changing the law is not a side project, it is a material part of the business plan” (Pollman & Barry, 2017, p.393).

  15. Regulatory entrepreneurship does not imply that such activities are a core part of the stated business plan. Garud et al. (2022) find “no mention of regulations in Uber’s initial pitch deck” (p. 454).

  16. Indeed, Pollman and Barry (2017) contend that “the most successful regulatory entrepreneur’s chief source of political power is their army of activated users” (p. 448).

  17. This quote is from a 2014 Vanity Fair profile of Uber co-founder and then CEO, Travis Kalanick, by Kara Swisher. See Swisher, 2014.

  18. I appreciate the suggestion of an anonymous reviewer to draw this link.

  19. In 2015 Uber had a higher proportion of female drivers (14%) then traditional taxi companies (8%) (see Hall & Kruegar, 2018) and, according to Uber, the number of women who work for their ride-share or delivery platforms increased by 50% in the first half of 2021 (see Pandey, 2021).

  20. For evidence about Uber’s use of private investigators and treatment of journalists see Lacy (2014), Milligan (2014), and Smith (2014).

  21. Lyft are a similar ride sharing platform to Uber.

  22. This would include things like minimum wage legislation or overtime regulations.

  23. See Wright et al. (2019) for a discussion of an international framework that clarifies employee relations in the gig economy.

  24. In employment law a “right to control” test establishes whether the hiring party can control the manner in which work is performed, an “economic realities” test establishes whether the worker is reliant on the hirer to earn their living, and an “entrepreneurial opportunity” test establishes whether the worker is able to earn extra money from taking risk and exercising their own entrepreneurial judgment. These are common ways to determine whether someone is a contractor (i.e. not controlled, not financially dependent on a single client, and able to exploit their own profit opportunities) rather than an employee (whose working practices are determined by management, are financially dependent, and earn more through longer hours rather than taking on extra risk).

  25. This isn’t to say that there may be other reasons why governments wish to regulate markets. Our assumption here is that their aim is improving choice and quality for the benefit of consumers. If the goal of public policy is to protect jobs, to preserve traditional ways of working, or to reward and enrich specific groups then enacting barriers to entry would be good.

References

  • Abbott, L., 1953, “Vertical Equilibrium under pure quality Competition” American Economic Review, 43(5):826–845

    Google Scholar 

  • Alba, J.W., and Hutchinson, J.W., 1987, “Dimensions of consumer expertise”, Journal of Consumer research, 13(4):411–454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anagnostopoulos, I., 2018. “Fintech and regtech: Impact on regulators and banks”. Journal of Economics and Business, 100, pp.7–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong, M. (2006). Competition in Two-Sided Markets. The RAND Journal of Economics, 37(3), 668–691. Routledge.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnott, R., 1995. “Time for revisionism on rent control?” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(1), pp.99–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron, D.P., 2018. Disruptive entrepreneurship and dual purpose strategies: The case of Uber. Strategy Science, 3(2), pp.439–462

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol and Bowen, 1966, Performing arts: The Economic Dilemma, New York: Twentieth Century Fund

    Google Scholar 

  • Beckert, J., and Musselin, C., 2013, Constructing Quality, Oxford University Press

  • Bellafante, G., 2015, “Uber Makes Its Pain New Yorkers’ Problem”, New York Times, July 24, https://www.nytimes.com/2015/07/26/nyregion/uber-makes-its-pain-new-yorkers-problem.html. Accessed October 31st 2022.

  • Bento, P., 2014, “Competition as a Discovery Procedure: Schumpeter meets Hayek in a Model of Innovation”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 6(3):124–152

    Google Scholar 

  • Beunza and Garud (2007) “Calculators, Lemmings or Frame-Makers? The intermediary role of Securities Analysts” The Sociological Review, 55(2_suppl), 13–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boulding, K.E., 1977, “Notes on goods, services, and cultural economics” Journal of Cultural Economics, 1(1):1–12

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brummer, C. and Yadav, Y., 2018. “Fintech and the innovation trilemma”. Geo. LJ, 107, p.235.

  • Camarero, C., Garrido, M. J., and Vicente, E., 2011, “How cultural organizations’ size and funding influence innovation and performance: The case of museums” Journal of Cultural Economics, 35(4):247–266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C., Babcock, L., Loewenstein, G., and Thaler, R., 1997, “Labor Supply of New York City Cabdrivers: One day at a time,“ Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, pp. 407–441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, H., 2018, “The rideshare guy 2018 reader survey. Technical Report” The rideshareguy.com (cited by Chen at al 2021)

  • Castaner, X., and Campos, L., 2002, “The determinants of artistic Innovation: Bringing in the role of Organizations”, Iournal of Cultural Economics, 26(1):29–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chapuis-Doppler and Delhomme (2020), “Regulating Composite Platform Economy Services: The State-of-play After Airbnb Ireland”, European Papers. https://www.europeanpapers.eu/en/europeanforum/regulating-composite-platform-economy-services-after-airbnb. Accessed February 16th 2023

  • Chen, M. K. and Sheldon, M., 2015, “Dynamic Pricing in a Labor Market: Surge Pricing and Flexible Work on the Uber Platform” Working Paper

  • Chen, M. K., Chevalier, J. A., Rossi, P. E., and Currier, L., 2021, “Suppliers and Demanders of Flexibility: The Demographics of Gig Work” Working Paper

  • Chen, M. K., Chevalier, J. A., Rossi, P. E., and Oehlsen, E., 2019, “The value of flexible work: Evidence from Uber Drivers” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 127, No. 6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook, C., Diamond, R., Hall, J., List, J., and Oyer, P., 2020, “The gender earnings gap in the gig economy: Evidence from over a million rideshare drivers”. Working Paper, Stanford University. https://web.stanford.edu/~diamondr/UberPayGap.pdf. Accessed October 31st 2022.

  • Cramer, J., & Krueger, A. B. (2016). Disruptive change in the Taxi Business: The case of Uber. The American Economic Review, 106(5), 177–182.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cunningham-Parmeter, K., 2016, “From Amazon to Uber: Defining employment in the Modern Economy”, 96 Boston University Law Review, 1673, 1680–91

    Google Scholar 

  • Dal Bó, E., 2006, “Regulatory capture: A review”. Oxford review of economic policy, 22(2), pp.203–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dalla Chiesa, C. and Dekker, E., 2021, “Communicating identity: How the symbolic meaning of goods creates different market types” Review of Social Economy.

  • DeBruyne, N.L., 2017. “Uber drivers: A disputed employment relationship in light of the sharing economy”. Chicago-Kent Law Review, 92, p.289.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dekker, E., 2020, “On emancipators, engineers, and students: The appropriate attitude of the economist”: Review of Austrian Economics, Vol. 33, pp. 55–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dekker, E., 2022, “How cognitive institutions and interpretative rationality enable markets with infinite Variety” in Martin, A.G., and D’Amico, D.J., (Eds.) Contemporary Methods and Austrian Economics, Emerald

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Dekker, E., and Kuchař, P., 2016, “Exemplary goods: The product as economic variable” Schmollers Jahrbuch, Vol. 136, No. 3, pp. 237–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dekker, E., and Kuchař, P., 2021, Governing markets as Knowledge Commons, Cambridge University Press

  • Dempsey, P. S., 1996, “Taxi industry regulation, deregulation and reregulation: The paradox of market failure” University of Denver College of Law, Transportation Law Journal, Vol. 24, Issue 1, pp. 73–120

    Google Scholar 

  • Daus, M., 2022, “In Depth with Daus: Rising Medallions Could Be Good News for All NYC Transportation”, Chauffeur driven.com, August 10th 2022. https://www.chauffeurdriven.com/news-features/in-this-issue/3408-in-depth-with-daus-rising-medallions-could-be-good-news-for-all-nyc-transportation.html. Accessed February 15th 2023.

  • Douglas M., and Isherwood, B., 1979 [1996] The World of Goods, Routledge

  • Ducci, F., & Tremblay-Huet, S. (2018). Competition Law and Policy Issues in the sharing economy. In D. McKee, F. Makela, & T. Scassa (Eds.), Law and the “Sharing Economy”: Regulating Online Market Platforms (pp. 295–318). University of Ottawa Press.

  • Flegenheimer, M., 2013, “$1 Million Medallions Stifling the Dreams of Cabdrivers,” New York Times

  • Frechette, G. R., Lizzeri, A., and Salz. T., 2016, “Frictions in a Competitive, Regulated Market: Evidence from Taxis.“ Working paper, Dept. Econ., New York Univ.

  • Galbraith, J.W., and Hodgson, D.J., 2015, “Innovation, experience and artists’ age-valuation profiles: Evidence from eighteenth-century rococo and neoclassical painters” Journal of Cultural Economics, 39(3):259–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garud, R., Kumaraswamy, A., Roberts, A., Xu, L., 2022, “Liminal movement by digital platform-based sharing economy ventures: The case of Uber Technologies” Strategic Management Journal, Volume 43, Issue 3, pp. 447–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerwe, O., and Silva, R., 2020, “Clarifying the sharing economy: Conceptualization, typology, antecedents, and effects” Academy of Management Annals, 5(1): 317–371

    Google Scholar 

  • Giraudo, M., 2021, “On legal bubbles: Some thoughts on legal shockwaves at the core of the digital economy” Journal of Institutional Economics, Vol. 18, Issue 4., pp. 1–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, J., and Krueger, A., 2018, “An analysis of the Labor Market for Uber’s driver-partners in the United States” ILR Review, 71(3):705–732

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harasztosi, P. and Lindner, A., 2019. Who pays for the minimum wage?. American Economic Review, 109(8), pp.2693–2727.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, S., and Krueger, A., 2015 “A proposal for modernizing labour laws for twenty-first century work: The ‘Independent worker’” Brookings Policy Brief, https://www.brookings.edu/research/a-proposal-for-modernizing-labor-laws-for-21st-century-work-the-independent-worker/. Accessed October 31st 2022.

  • Harris, S. D., & Krueger, A. B. (2016). Is Your Uber Driver an Employee or an Independent Contractor? Perspectives on Work, 20, 30–80. 30).

  • Hayek, F.A., 1945, “The Use of Knowledge in Society”, American Economic Review, 35(4):519–530

    Google Scholar 

  • Heikkila, M, 2020, “EU court ruling delivers win for Uber, ride-hailing apps” Politico, December 3rd. https://www.politico.eu/article/uber-europe-court-ruling-delivers-win-ride-hailing-apps/. Accessed October 11th 2021

  • Heilbrun, J., 1993, “Innovation in art, innovation in technology, and the future of the high arts” Journal of Cultural Economics, 17(1):89–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Howcroft, D., and Bergvall-Kareborn, B., 2019, “A typology of Crowdwork Platforms” Work, Employment and Society, Vol. 33, No. 1, pp. 21–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kitch, Edmund W., ed., 1983, “The Fire of Truth: A Remembrance of Law and Economics at Chicago, 1932–1970.” Journal of Law and Economics 26(1):163–234

  • Klamer, A., (Ed.) 1996, The value of culture: On the Relationship between Economics and the Arts, Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Klamer, A., 2016, “The value-based approach to cultural economics”, Journal of Cultural Economics, 40:365–373

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleiner, M.M., 2000, “Occupational licensing”. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(4), pp.189–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleiner, M.M. and Krueger, A.B., 2013, “Analyzing the extent and influence of occupational licensing on the labor market”. Journal of Labor Economics, 31(S1), pp. S173-S202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kretschmer, T., Leiponen, A., Schilling, M. and Vasudeva, G., 2022. Platform ecosystems as meta-organizations: Implications for platform strategies. Strategic Management Journal, 43(3), pp.405–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuchař, P., 2016, “Entrepreneurship and institutional change” Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 26:349–379

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lacy, S., 2014, “The Moment I Learned Just How Far Uber Will Go to Silence Journalists and Attack Women”, Pando, Nov. 17. https://pandodaily.com/2014/11/17/the-moment-i-learned-just-how-far-uber-will-go-to-silence-journalists-and-attack-women/. Accessed October 31st 2022

  • Leijonhufvud, A., 1973, “Life among the Econ” Economic Inquiry, 11(3):327–337

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lemley, Mark A., and A. Douglas Melamed. “Missing the forest for the trolls.” Columbia Law Review 113, no. 8 (2013): 2117–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maffie, M.D., 2020. Are we ‘sharing’or ‘gig-ing’? A classification system for online platforms. Industrial Relations Journal, 51(6), pp.536–555

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mair, J., and Reischauer, G., 2017 “Capturing the dynamics of the sharing economy: Institutional research on the plural forms and practices of sharing economy organizations” Technical Forecasting and Social Change, 125, 11–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martini, J.D., 2017. “International Regulatory Entrepreneurship: Uber’s battle with regulators in France”. San Diego International Law Journal, 19, p.127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milligan, S., 2014, “A Ride Scare Tactic?”, U.S. News, Nov. 19, http://www.usnews.com/opinion/blogs/susan-milligan/2014/11/19/an-uber-executive-suggests-the-company-target-its-media-critics. Accessed October 31st 2022

  • Mims, C., 2015, “How Everyone Gets the ‘Sharing’ Economy Wrong, Wall Street Journal, May 24, http://www.wsj.com/articles/how-everyone-gets-the-sharing-economy-wrong-1432495921. Accessed October 31st 2022

  • Moazami, Y., 2017. “UBER in the US and Canada: Is the gig-economy exploiting or exploring labor and employment laws by going beyond the Dichotomous Workers’ Classification”. U. Miami Int’l & Comp. L. Rev., 24, Issue 2, p.609–659

    Google Scholar 

  • Moon, Y., 2017, “Uber: Changing the way the World Moves”, Harvard Business School Case No. 316 – 101

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Driscoll, G. P. and Rizzo, M. J.,1985, The Economics of Time and Ignorance

  • Øverby, Harald, and Jan A. Audestad. 2021. “Multisided Platforms: Classification and Analysis” Systems 9, no. 4: 85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palagashvili, L., 2017, “Disrupting the Employee and Contractor Laws”, University of Chicago Legal Forum, Article 15.

  • Pandey, E., 2021, “The rise of women in the gig economy”, Axios Blog, August 26th. https://www.axios.com/2021/08/26/women-gig-economy-doordash-uber-delivery-driver Accessed October 31st 2022.

  • Parker, G. G., Van Alstyne, M. W., and Choudary, S. P., 2016, Platform revolution: How networks markets are transforming the economy and how to make them work for you, New York, NY: WW Norton & Company

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollman, E., and Barry, J. M., 2017, “Regulatory entrepreneurship”, Southern California Law Review, Vol. 90, No. 383

    Google Scholar 

  • Prassl, J., and Risak, M., 2016, “Uber, TaskRabbit, & Co: Platforms as employers? Rethinking the legal analysis of Crowdwork, Comparative Labor Law & Policy Journal, Forthcoming

    Google Scholar 

  • Redfearn, R. L. (2016). Sharing Economy Misclassification: Employees and independent contractors in Transportation Network Companies. Berkeley Technology Law Journal, 31(2), 1023–1056.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rochet, J.-C., & Tirole, J. (2003). Platform competition in two-sided markets. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(4), 990–1029.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanders, D.E., and Pattison, P., 2016 “Worker characterisation in a gig economy viewed through an Uber centric lens” Southern Law Journal, Vol 26, p. 297–320

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A., 1934, The theory of Economic Development. Transaction. (First published in 1911 as Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung.)

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. 1942 [1950], Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. Harper and Brothers.

  • Sen, A., Clemente, A. and Jonker, L., 2011, “Retail gasoline price ceilings and regulatory capture: Evidence from Canada”. American law and economics review, 13(2), pp.532–564.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, B., 2014, “Uber Executive Suggests Digging Up Dirt on Journalists” Buzzfeed, Nov. 17, http://www.buzzfeed.com/bensmith/uber-executive-suggests-digging-up-dirt-on-journalists. Accessed October 31st 2022.

  • Stigler, G., 1971. “The theory of Economic Regulation” The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science. 2(1): 3–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J., and Becker, G.S., 1977, “De gustibus non est disputandum” American Economic Review, 67, 76–90

    Google Scholar 

  • Sundararajan, A., 2016, The sharing economy: The end of employment and the rise of crowd-based capitalism, Cambridge MA: MIT Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Swisher, K., 2014, “Man and Uber Man”, Vanity Fair [https://www.vanityfair.com/news/2014/12/uber-travis-kalanick-controversy accessed December 7th 2020]

  • Throsby, D., 1994, “The production and consumption of the Arts: A view of Cultural Economics”, Journal of Economic Literature, 32(1):1–29

    Google Scholar 

  • Throsby, D., 1995, “Economics and sustainability”, Journal of Cultural Economics, 19(3):199–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Todolí-Signes, A., 2017. The ‘gig economy’: Employee, self-employed or the need for a special employment regulation?. Transfer: European Review of Labour and Research, 23(2), pp.193–205

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wijnberg, N.M., 2011, “Classification systems and the selection systems: The risks of radical innovation and category spanning” Scandinavian Journal of Management, 27:297–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wohlsen, M., 2014, “Uber’s brilliant strategy to make itself too big to Ban, Wired, July 8, http://www.wired.com/2014/07/ubers-brilliant-strategy-to-make-itself-too-big-to-ban. Accessed October 31st 2022.

  • Wright, C.F., Bamber, G.J., Wailes, N. and Lansbury, R.D., 2019. “An internationally comparative framework for analysing employment relations and the gig economy. Perspectives on Neoliberalism, Labour and Globalization” in India: Essays In Honour of Lalit K. Deshpande, pp.207–224.

  • Yussopov, V., Soldani, J., Breitenbucher, U., Brogi, A., and Leymann, F., (2021), “FaaSten your decisions: A classification framework and technology review of function-as-a-Service platforms” Journal of Systems and Software, Vol 175

  • Zukerman, E.W., 1999, “The categorical imperative: Securities analysts and the Illegitimacy Discount” American Journal of Sociology, 104(5):1398–1438

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zuckerman, E.W., and Kim, T-Y., 2003, “The critical trade-off: Identity assignment and box‐office success in the feature film industry” Industrial and Corporate Change, 12(1):27–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anthony J. Evans.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

I appreciate helpful comments and constructive feedback from Erwin Dekker, Liya Palagashvili, Nikolai Wenzel and two anonymous reviewers from this journal. Remaining limitations are my own responsibility.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Evans, A.J. Information, classification and contestability: a cultural economics approach to Uber’s entry into the taxi industry. Rev Austrian Econ (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-023-00624-0

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-023-00624-0

Keywords

Navigation