Skip to main content
Log in

Breaking out of the Kirznerian box: A reply to Sautet

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

What is now called the judgment-based approach to entrepreneurship (JBA) has a rich pedigree in Austrian economics and continues to grow rapidly in that tradition as well as in various research fields in business and management. The JBA has also attracted some criticisms. Frédéric Sautet’s recent review essay is an example. Sautet’s main concern is that the JBA rejects Israel Kirzner’s alertness/discovery approach which, in Sautet’s view, provides a more compelling basis for theorizing. Unfortunately, we do not find Sautet’s criticisms of the JBA convincing. They frequently ignore our arguments about entrepreneurial judgment and its manifestation in the business firm, fail to address our criticisms of the alertness/discovery approach, and are rooted in a flawed understanding of the history of economic thought.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We pass over sections of Sautet’s essay such as “Firms and Capital Goods” that are not critical of us.

  2. If true, this would undermine Kirzner’s claim to originality, a claim Sautet urgently wishes to defend.

  3. Schumpeter also had no theory of economic calculation and explicitly rejected the idea that entrepreneurs deal with uncertainty, both crucial aspects of Mises’s theory (McCaffrey, 2009). Schumpeter also does not use the stationary state as a foil for explaining entrepreneurship, as Sautet claims (Sautet, 2018, p. 126): it was a necessary starting point for his theory, which was based on a version of Walrasian general equilibrium, another concept Mises unqualifiedly rejected. Schumpeter’s entrepreneur attempts to escape this equilibrium, which for him can only be done through credit creation (McCaffrey, 2013; Rothbard, 1987).

  4. Furthermore, the later editions of Theory of Economic Development still strongly emphasize entrepreneurs’ need for bank credit, which is surely not universally available.

  5. See Schumpeter (2003, p. 417) for a clarification about the empirical progress of this transition.

  6. See respectively, Martin, 1979; Möller and McCaffrey, 2021; McCaffrey and Salerno, 2014; McCaffrey, 2016; Foss and Klein, 2012; Salerno, 2008; Klein and Foss, 2010, and the wealth of textual evidence cited in these sources.

  7. In attributing this construct to the work of Lionel Robbins, Kirzner has not appreciated Robbins’ views, which are more nuanced and less mechanical than Kirzner implies (Salerno, 2009).

  8. Boettke (2005) similarly describes the Kirznerian system as an add-on to neoclassical microeconomics: “as Franklin Fischer pointed out in his very important book The Disequilibrium Foundations of Equilibrium Economics (1983) that unless we have good reasons to believe in the systemic tendency toward equilibrium we have no justification at all in upholding the welfare properties of equilibrium economics. In other words, without the sort of explanation that Kirzner provides the entire enterprise of neoclassical equilibrium is little more than a leap of faith.” But why must we accept the enterprise of neoclassical equilibrium economics?

  9. Cf. Kirzner (1963, 1963) and Becker (1963).

  10. The fact that Kirzner does not appear even in the footnotes to mainstream price theory is as good an indication as any that his contribution has not been recognized. Klein and Bylund (2014) show that Kirzner’s works have very few citations in economics journals, though they have been cited often in entrepreneurship research.

  11. In Sautet’s view, “Kirzner’s economic theory rests on the notion of purpose in action” (Sautet, 2018, p. 127; emphasis added). Note that for Mises this is a confused claim: for him, action is purposeful behavior.

  12. Sautet approaches such an expansive definition. For example: “By discovering vines that can be used as nets, Crusoe, in the deepest sense, created the nets” (Sautet, 2018, p. 131). Or: “discovery is precisely how purpose comes to exist” (Sautet, 2018, p. 128). The second example not only contradicts Sautet’s concession to Salerno quoted above, but also makes discovery so broad that it applies to virtually anything: exactly what Sautet accuses the JBA of doing (see below).

  13. This claim is made as part of Sautet’s attempt to associate the JBA with Ludwig Lachmann’s radical subjectivism; see below.

  14. Sautet attempts to associate Mises with Kirzner’s equilibration theory, citing a remark from Roger Garrison in support (Sautet, 2018, p. 129n14). In that paper, Garrison argues that, “We must take Ludwig von Mises literally when he suggests that the only way we can conceive of markets is to conceive of a tendency toward equilibrium” (Garrison, 1982, p. 133). Yet the quote Garrison cites is taken from Mises’s discussion of the “plain state of rest”: a momentary, actually existing equilibrium that Kirzner explicitly argues is not useful as a description of equilibrium or market-clearing (Mises, 1949, p. 245; Kirzner, 1999; Klein, 2008).

  15. High’s article plays no role in Foss and Klein (2012), and is mentioned only once, in a footnote.

  16. Sautet makes a basic error by claiming that, according to Mises, the pure entrepreneur earns neither profits nor losses: Mises explicitly says that the pure entrepreneur earns profits but not losses (Sautet, 2018, p. 135; Mises, 1949, p. 254). Sautet is perhaps confusing the pure entrepreneur with the conditions of the Evenly Rotating Economy, in which profit and loss do not exist.

  17. Mises’s essay “Profit and Loss” is his clearest exposition of the meaning of entrepreneurship, and avoids the ambiguity found in some passages of Human Action. This essay is rarely cited by Kirznerians, however.

  18. Fetter (1915, pp. 321-322n1) clarified the confusion surrounding the use of the word “residual” to describe entrepreneurial profit.

  19. In oral conversation Kirzner has described uncertainty as a “veil” and insisted that alertness must be able to “pierce the veil” for entrepreneurship to facilitate coordination. Whether or not this is a useful metaphor, it is not an explanation for how and why alertness is able to do this.

  20. Before making this criticism Sautet mentions the idea of residual control, so he must be aware of it (Sautet, 2018, p. 132).

  21. Without a distinction like this, there is essentially no difference between entrepreneurs and non-entrepreneurs in Kirzner’s theory: entrepreneurs and managers (as well as laborers and anyone else) are all alert discoverers. As a result, entrepreneurship loses meaning, and is certainly not a basis for distinguishing different types of income.

  22. Mises also uses this idea to distinguish between nominal and real entrepreneurs under “socialism of the German pattern” (Mises, 1949, pp. 713–714).

  23. Note the necessity of physical resources in the example: apparently Sautet’s theory is “materialist” too!

  24. As part of this argument, Sautet repeats his earlier claims about materialism and labor-mixing.

  25. Note too that most of the core sources Sautet cites were published in the 1980s and early 1990s.

References

  • Alchian, A.A. (1965). Some economics of property rights. Il politico, 30(4), 816–829.

  • Becker, G. S. (1963). Rational action and economic theory: A reply to I Kirzner. Journal of Political Economy,71(1), 82–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, M. C., & Knudsen, T. (2003). The entrepreneur at a crucial juncture in Schumpeter’s work: Schumpeter’s 1928 handbook entry entrepreneur. Advances in Austrian Economics, 6, 199–233

  • Boettke, P. J. (2005). “Kirzner?” The Austrian Economists, September 10. http://austrianeconomists.typepad.com/weblog/2005/09/kirzner.html. Accessed 16 Sept 2008.

  • Boettke, P., & Sautet, F. (2011). The genius of Mises and the brilliance of Kirzner. In E. Chamlee-Wright (Ed.), The annual proceedings of the wealth and well-being of nations (Vol. III, pp. 31–43). Beloit College Press.

  • Fetter, F. (1915). Economic Principles. The Century Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foss, N. J. & Klein, P. J. (2005). Entrepreneurship and the economic theory of the firm: any gains from trade? In R. Agarwal, A.A. Sharon, & O. Sorenson (Eds.), Handbook of entrepreneurship research: disciplinary perspectives. Springer.

  • Foss, N. J., Klein, P. G., Lien, L. B., Zellweger, T., & Zenger, T. (2020). Ownership competence. Strategic Management Journal,42(2), 302–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foss, K., Foss, N. J., & Klein, P. G. (2007). Original and derived judgment: An entrepreneurial theory of economic organization. Organization Studies,28(12), 1893–1912.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foss, N., & Klein, P. (2012). Organizing entrepreneurial judgment: A new approach to the firm. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Foss, N. J., & Klein, P. G. (2015). Introduction to a forum on the judgment−based approach to entrepreneurship: Accomplishments, challenges, new directions”. Journal of Institutional Economics,11(3), 585–599.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foss, N., & Klein, P. (2020). Entrepreneurial opportunities: Who needs them? Academy of Management Perspectives,34, 366–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garrison, R. W. (1982). Austrian economics as the middle ground: Comment on Loasby. In I. M. Kirzner (Ed.), Method, process, and Austrian economics: Essays in honor of Ludwig von Mises (pp. 131–138). Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greaves, P. L., Jr. (1974). Review of Competition and Entrepreneurship by Israel M. Kirzner. Wertfrei: A Review of Praxeological Science,1, 17–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hazlitt, H. (1974). Review of Competition and Entrepreneurship by Israel M. Kirzner. the Freeman,24(December), 756–760.

    Google Scholar 

  • High, J. (1982). Alertness and judgment: Comment on Kirzner. In I. M. Kirzner (Ed.), Method, process, and Austrian economics: Essays in honor of Ludwig von Mises (pp. 161–168). Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (2018). Reflections on ethics, freedom, welfare economics, policy, and the legacy of Austrian economics. P. J. Boettke & F. Sautet (Eds). Liberty Fund.

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1999). Mises and his understanding of the capitalist system. Cato Journal,19, 215.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1985). Discovery and the Capitalist Process. University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1973). Competition and entrepreneurship. University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1963). Rational action and economic theory: Rejoinder. Journal of Political Economy,71(1), 84–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1962). Rational action and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy,70(4), 380–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, P. G., Mahoney, J. T., McGahan, A. M., & Pitelis, C. N. (2010). Toward a theory of public entrepreneurship. European Management Review.,7(1), 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, P. G., & Bylund, P. L. (2014). The place of Austrian economics in contemporary entrepreneurship research. Review of Austrian Economics,27(3), 259–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klein, P. G., & Foss, N. J. (2010). Alertness, action, and the antecedents of entrepreneurship. Journal of Private Enterprise,25(2), 145.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klein, P. G. (2008). The mundane economics of the Austrian school. The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics,11(3), 165–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. H. (1921). Risk, uncertainty and profit. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

  • Lachmann, L. M. (1956). Capital and Its Structure. Sheed Andrews and McMeel. 1978.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lachmann, L. M. (1986). The market as an economic process. Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, D. T. (1979). Alternative views of Mengerian entrepreneurship. History of Political Economy,11(2), 271–285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCaffrey, M. (2018). “William Baumol’s “entrepreneurship: Productive, unproductive, and destructive.” In G. Javadian, V. K. Gupta, D. K. Dutta, G. C. Guo, A. E. Osorio, & B. Ozkazanc-Pan (Eds.), Foundational research in entrepreneurship studies: Insightful contributions and future pathways (pp. 179–201). Palgrave MacMillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • McCaffrey, M. (2016). Good judgment, good luck: Frank Fetter’s neglected theory of entrepreneurship. Review of Political Economy,28(4), 504–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCaffrey, M. (2014). On the theory of entrepreneurial incentives and alertness. Entrepreneurship Theory and Practice,38(4), 891–911.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCaffrey, M. (2013). Conflicting views of the entrepreneur in turn-of-the-century Vienna. History of Economics Review,58(2), 27–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCaffrey, M. (2009). Entrepreneurship, economic evolution, and the end of capitalism: Reconsidering Schumpeter’s thesis. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics.,12(4), 3–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCaffrey, M. & Salerno, J. T. (2011). A theory of political entrepreneurship. Modern Economy, 2(4), 552–560.

  • McCaffrey, M., & Salerno, J. T. (2014). Böhm-Bawerk’s approach to entrepreneurship. Journal of the History of Economic Thought,36(4), 435–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Mises, L. (2007). Profit and loss. Ludwig von Mises Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Mises, L. (1998) [1949]. Human action: Scholar’s edition. Ludwig von Mises Institute.

  • von Mises, L. (1978) [2009]. Memoirs. The Ludwig von Mises Institute.

  • Salerno, J. T. (1993). Mises and Hayek dehomogenized. Review of Austrian Economics,6, 113–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Möller, U., & McCaffrey, M. (2021). “Entrepreneurship and firm strategy: Integrating resources, capabilities, and judgment through an Austrian framework.” Entrepreneurship Research Journal. Forthcoming.

  • Rothbard, M. N. (1987). Breaking out of the Walrasian box: The cases of Schumpeter and Hansen. The Review of Austrian Economics,1(1), 97–108.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. N. (1985). Professor Hébert on entrepreneurship. Journal of Libertarian Studies,7(2), 281–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard, M. N. (1974). Review of competition and entrepreneurship by Israel M Kirzner. Journal of Economic Literature,12, 902–904.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salerno, J. T. (2009). Lionel Robbins: Neoclassical maximizer or proto-praxeologist? Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics,12(4), 98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salerno, J. T. (2008). The entrepreneur: Real and imagined. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics,11(3), 188–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1950) [2003]. Capitalism, socialism, and democracy (3rd ed.). Routledge.

  • Sautet, F. (2018). The battle for the essence of entrepreneurship a review essay on Nicolai Foss and Peter Klein’s organizing entrepreneurial judgment: A new approach to the firm. Review of Austrian Economics,31, 123–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Matthew McCaffrey.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The title refers to Rothbard’s “Breaking Out of the Walrasian Box: The Cases of Schumpeter and Hansen” (1987).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

McCaffrey, M., Foss, N.J., Klein, P.G. et al. Breaking out of the Kirznerian box: A reply to Sautet. Rev Austrian Econ 36, 1–21 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-021-00552-x

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-021-00552-x

Keywords

Navigation