Skip to main content
Log in

A neo-institutionalism of measurement, without measurement: A comment on Douglas Allen’s The Institutional Revolution

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In his elegant book Douglas Allen claims that an improvement in the measurement of Nature made for lower transaction costs and the Industrial Revolution. His argument is a typical example of neo-institutionalism in the style of Douglass North (1990) and North et al. (2009). A fall in a wedge of inefficiency is supposed to provide Good Incentives, and the modern world. But the elimination of wedges lead merely to Harberger Triangles of improved efficiency—not to the factor of 100 in properly measured real income per head, which is the Great Enrichment 1800 to the present to be explained. Allen does yeoman work in explaining some of the peculiarities of British public administration, such as the reliance on aristocratic honor and on the prize system in naval warfare. But he attributes to public administration an implausible effect on private incomes. The merging of power and plenty is mistaken. Further, the alleged increase in a modern ability to measure marginal products is implausible. Large modern enterprises face greater, not smaller, problems of assessing the contribution of individuals. Allen’s book on measurement does not measure, and the probable order of magnitude of the items he focuses on is too small to explain any but the details of administration.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. New York: Crown Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, R. C. (2009). The British industrial revolution in global perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Broadberry, S. N., & Bishnupriya, G. (2005). The early modern price divergence: Wages, prices and economic development in Europe and Asia, 1500–1800. CERP discussion paper 4947. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2002). Efflorescences and economic growth in world history: rethinking the ‘rise of the West’ and the industrial revolution. Journal World History, 13, 323–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenfeld, L. (2001). The spirit of capitalism: Nationalism and economic growth. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, E. L. (1988). Growth recurring: Economic change in world history. Oxford: Clarendon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, E. L. (2010). Locating the industrial revolution: Inducement and response. London: World Scientific.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I. M. (1976). Equilibrium vs. market processes. In E. Dolan (Ed.), The foundations of modern Austrian economics. Kansas: Sheed and Ward.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klamer, A., & McCloskey, D. N. (1995). One quarter of GDP is persuasion. American Economic Review, 85(2), 191–195.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. N. (1991). Economic science: a search through the hyperspace of assumptions? Methodus, 3(1), 6–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. N. (2001). Women’s work in the market. In I. Zweiniger-Bargielowska (Ed.), Women in Twentieth-Century Britain: Economic, social, and cultural change (pp. 1900–2000). London: Longmans.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. N. (1994). Knowledge and persuasion in economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (2009). Intellectual property rights, the industrial revolution, and the beginnings of modern economic growth. American Economic Review, 99(May), 349–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (2005). Understanding the process of economic change. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C., Wallis, J. J., & Weingast, B. R. (2009). Violence and social orders: A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C., & Thomas, R. P. (1973). The rise of the western world: A new economic history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ó Gráda, C. (2009). Famine: A short history. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Brien, P. K (2011). The contributions of warfare with revolutionary and Napoleonic France to The Consolidation and Progress of the British Industrial Revolution. Department of Economic History, London School of Economics Working Papers No. 150/11

  • Parthasarathi, P. (2011). Why Europe grew rich and Asia did not. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • van Zanden, J. L. (2004). The skill premium and the ‘great divergence.’ http://www.iisg.nl/hpw/papers/vanzanden.pdf

  • van Zanden, J. L. (2009). The long road to the industrial revolution: The European economy in a global perspective, 1000–1800. Leiden: Brill.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Deirdre N. McCloskey.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

McCloskey, D.N. A neo-institutionalism of measurement, without measurement: A comment on Douglas Allen’s The Institutional Revolution . Rev Austrian Econ 26, 363–373 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-013-0236-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-013-0236-6

Keywords

Navigation