Skip to main content
Log in

Congestion-based leadtime quotation and pricing for revenue maximization with heterogeneous customers

  • Published:
Queueing Systems Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies a queuing model where two customer classes compete for a given resource and each customer is dynamically quoted a menu of price and leadtime pairs upon arrival. Customers select their preferred pairs from the menu and the server is obligated to meet the quoted leadtime. Customers have convex–concave delay costs. The firm does not have information on a given customer’s type, so the offered menus must be incentive compatible. A menu quotation policy is given and proven to be asymptotically optimal under traditional large-capacity heavy-traffic scaling.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We adopt the equivalent definition of cost to facilitate comparison with the lower bound advanced by van Mieghem [49].

References

  1. Afèche, P.: Incentive-compatible revenue management in queuing systems: optimal strategic delay and other delay tactics. Working paper, Rotman School of Management, Toronto, Canada (2010)

  2. Akan, M., Ata, B., Olsen, T.L.: Congestion-based leadtime quotation for heterogeneous customers with convex–concave delay costs: optimality of a cost-balancing policy based on convex hull functions. Oper. Res. (2012, forthcoming)

  3. Akan, M., Ata, B., Dana, J.: Revenue management by sequential screening. Working paper (2008)

  4. Antonides, G., Verhoef, P.C., van Aalst, M.: Consumer perception and evaluation of waiting time: a field experiment. J. Consum. Psychol. 12(3), 193–202 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Ata, B., Kumar, S.: Heavy traffic analysis of open processing networks with complete resource pooling: asymptotic optimality of discrete review policies. Ann. Appl. Probab. 15(1), 331–391 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Ata, B., Olsen, T.L.: Near-optimal dynamic leadtime quotation and scheduling under convex–concave customer delay costs. Oper. Res. 57(3), 753–768 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Besbes, O., Maglaras, C.: Revenue optimization for a make-to-order queue in an uncertain market environment. Oper. Res. 57(6), 1438–1450 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Borst, S., Mandelbaum, A., Reiman, M.I.: Dimensioning large call centers. Oper. Res. 52(1), 17–34 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Çelik, S., Maglaras, C.: Dynamic pricing and lead-time quotation for a multiclass make-to-order queue. Manag. Sci. 54, 1132–1146 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Chatterjee, S., Slotnick, S.A., Sobel, M.J.: Delivery guarantees and the interdependence of marketing and operations. Prod. Oper. Manag. 11(3), 393–410 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Charnsirisakskul, K., Griffin, P., Keskinocak, P.: Order selection and scheduling with lead-time flexibility. IIE Trans. 36, 697–707 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Charnsirisakskul, K., Griffin, P., Keskinocak, P.: Pricing and scheduling decisions with lead-time flexibility. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 171(1), 153–169 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Csorgo, M., Horvath, L.: Weighted Approximations in Probability and Statistics. Wiley, New York (1993)

    Google Scholar 

  14. Dellaert, N.P.: Due-date setting and production control. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 23, 59–67 (1991)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Duenyas, I.: Single facility due-date setting with multiple customer classes. Manag. Sci. 41(4), 608–619 (1995)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Duenyas, I., Hopp, W.J.: Quoting customer lead times. Manag. Sci. 41(1), 43–57 (1995)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Duran, S., Gülcü, A., Keskinocak, P., Swann, J.L.: Leadtime quotation and order acceptance when demand depends on service performance. Working paper, Georgia Institute of Technology, Atlanta, GA (2006)

  18. Easton, F.F., Moodie, D.R.: Pricing and lead time decisions for make-to-order firms with contingent orders. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 116(2), 305–318 (1999)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G., O’Donoghue, T.: Time discounting and time preference: a critical review. J. Econ. Lit. 40, 350–401 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Gurvich, I., Whitt, W.: Scheduling flexible servers with convex delay costs in many-server service systems. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 11(2), 237–253 (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  21. Ha, A.: Incentive-compatible pricing for a service facility with joint production and congestion externalities. Manag. Sci. 44, 1623–1636 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Ha, A.: Optimal pricing that coordinates queues with customer-chosen service requirements. Manag. Sci. 47(7), 915–930 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Hassin, R., Haviv, M.: To Queue or Not to Queue: Equilibrium Behavior in Queueing Systems. International Series in Operations Research & Management Science. Kluwer Academic, Norwell (2003)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  24. Kahneman, D., Tversky, A.: Advances in prospect theory: cumulative representation of uncertainty. J. Risk Uncertain. 5, 297–324 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Katta, A.-K., Sethuraman, J.: Pricing strategies and service differentiation in queues—a profit maximization perspective. Working paper, Columbia University, New York, NY (2005)

  26. Kapuscinski, R., Tayur, S.: Reliable due-date setting in a capacitated mto system with two customer classes. Oper. Res. 55, 56–74 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Keskinocak, P., Ravi, R., Tayur, S.: Scheduling and reliable lead time quotation for orders with availability intervals and lead time sensitive revenues. Manag. Sci. 47(2), 264–279 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Keskinocak, P., Tayur, S.: Due-date management policies. In: Simchi-Levi, D., David Wu, S., Max Shen, Z. (eds.) Handbook of Quantitative Supply Chain Analysis: Modeling in the E-Business Era. International Series in Operations Research and Management Science, pp. 485–553. Kluwer Academic, Norwell (2004)

    Google Scholar 

  29. Kumar, S., Randhawa, R.S.: Exploiting market size in service systems. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 12(3), 511–526 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. Leclerc, F., Schmitt, B.H., Dube, L.: Waiting time and decision making: is time like money? J. Consum. Res. 22(1), 110–119 (1995)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Lederer, P.J., Li, L.D.: Pricing, production, scheduling, and delivery-time competition. Oper. Res. 45(3), 407–420 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Maglaras, C.: Revenue management for a multiclass single-server queue via a fluid model analysis. Oper. Res. 54(5), 914–932 (2006)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Maglaras, C., Zeevi, A.: Pricing and capacity sizing for systems with shared resources: approximate solutions and scaling relations. Manag. Sci. 49(8), 1018–1038 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Maglaras, C., Zeevi, A.: Pricing and design of differentiated services: approximate analysis and structural insights. Oper. Res. 53(2), 242–262 (2005a)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Maglaras, C., Zeevi, A.: Effects of substitution and customer choice on heavy-traffic. Working paper, Columbia University, New York, NY (2005b)

  36. Mandelbaum, A., Stolyar, A.L.: Scheduling flexible servers with convex delay costs: heavy-traffic optimality of the generalized -rule. Oper. Res. 52(6), 836–855 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Marchand, M.G.: Priority pricing. Manage. Sci., Theory Ser. 20(7), 1131–1140 (1974)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Mendelson, H., Whang, S.: Optimal incentive-compatible priority pricing for the m/m/1 queue. Oper. Res. 38(5), 870–883 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Palaka, K., Erlebacher, S., Kropp, D.H.: Lead-time setting, capacity utilization, and pricing decisions under lead-time dependent demand. IIE Trans. 30(2), 151–163 (1998)

    Google Scholar 

  40. Plambeck, E.L.: Optimal leadtime differentiation via diffusion approximations. Oper. Res. 52, 213–228 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Plambeck, E.L., Ward, A.R.: Optimal control of high-volume assemble-to-order systems with maximum leadtime quotation and expediting. Queueing Syst. 60(1–2), 1–69 (2008)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Plambeck, E.L., Kumar, S., Harrison, J.M.: A multiclass queue in heavy traffic with throughput time constraints: asymptotically optimal dynamic controls. Queueing Syst. 39, 23–54 (2001)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Rao, S., Petersen, E.R.: Optimal pricing of priority services. Oper. Res. 46(1), 46–56 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Rogers, L.C.G., Williams, D.: Diffusions, Markov Processes and Martingales. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (2000)

    Google Scholar 

  45. Royden, H.: Real Analysis, 3rd edn. McMillan, New York (1988)

    Google Scholar 

  46. Shen, Z.-J., Su, X.: Customer behavior modeling in revenue management and auctions: a review and new research opportunities. Prod. Oper. Manag. 16(6), 713–728 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  47. Stolyar, A.L.: Maxweight scheduling in a generalized switch: state space collapse and workload minimization in heavy traffic. Ann. Appl. Probab. 14(1), 1–53 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Tang, K., Tang, J.: Time-based pricing and leadtime policies for a build-to-order manufacturer. Prod. Oper. Manag. 11(3), 374–392 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. Van Mieghem, J.A.: Dynamic scheduling with convex delay costs: the generalized rule. Ann. Appl. Probab. 5, 809–833 (1995)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. Van Mieghem, J.A.: Price and service discrimination in queuing systems: incentive compatibility of gcμ scheduling. Manag. Sci. 46(9), 1249–1267 (2000)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Wang, L., Kapuscinski, R.: Joint price and due date quotation: monopolistic and competitive cases. Working paper, University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, MI (2007)

  52. Weng, Z.K.: Manufacturing lead times, system utilization rates and lead-time-related demand. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 89(2), 259–268 (1996)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  53. Whitt, W.: Stochastic-Process Limits. Springer, Berlin (2002)

    Google Scholar 

  54. Wolff, R.W.: Stochastic Modeling and the Theory of Queues. Prentice Hall, New York (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  55. Yahalom, T., Harrison, J.M., Kumar, S.: Designing and pricing incentive compatible grades of service in queuing systems. Working paper, Stanford University, Stanford, CA (2006)

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Marty Lariviere and Mustafa Akan for useful discussions and Tinglong Dai for his technical assistance. This research was supported in part by the Boeing Center for Technology, Information, and Manufacturing.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tava Lennon Olsen.

Appendices

Appendix A: Technical proofs in Sects. 3 and 4

Proof of Lemma 1

First, observe that (c 1-c 2)(⋅) is increasing on \((0,\underline{x}_{2}\vee d_{1})\). To see this, note that

$$(c_{1}-c_{2})^{\prime}(x)=c_{2}^{\prime}(x+d_{2}-d_{1})-c_{2}^{\prime}(x).$$

For xd 1, we have x+d 2-d 1d 2. Thus, (c 1-c 2)′(x)>0 for xd 1. Next, suppose without loss of generality that \(\underline{x}_{2}>d_{1}\) and \(x\in(d_{1},\underline{x}_{2})\). Then, since \(c_{2}^{\prime}(x)<\nobreak c\) for \(x\leq\underline{x}_{2}\), and \(c_{2}^{\prime}(x+d_{2}-d_{1})\geq c\), we conclude that (c 1-c 2)′(x)>0. Thus, (c 1-c 2) is increasing on \([0,\underline{x}_{2}\vee d_{1})\). Then observe that \((c_{1}-c_{2})^{\prime}(x)=c_{2}^{\prime }(x+d_{2}-d_{1})-c_{2}^{\prime}(x)\) is decreasing over \((\underline{x}_{2}\vee d_{1},d_{2})\) since the first term on the right hand side is decreasing while the second one is increasing. Also note that \((c_{1}-c_{2})^{\prime }(\underline{x}_{2}\vee d_{1})\geq0\) whereas (c 1-c 2)′(d 2)<0. Thus, there exists a unique \(d^{\ast}\in(\underline{x}_{2}\vee d_{1},d_{2})\) such that (c 1-c 2)′(d )=0. To conclude that d is the unique maximizer note that (c 1-c 2)′(x)<0 for \(x\in\lbrack d_{2},\overline{x}_{2}]\), while (c 1-c 2)′(x)=0 for \(x>\overline{x}_{2}\), which also proves that (c 1-c 2)(⋅) is constant on \([\overline{x}_{2},\infty)\).

Now if x 2d , then (2) follows immediately because (c 1-c 2)(⋅) is increasing on [0,d ]. If x 2>d then to prove (2), it suffices to show that

$$ (c_{1}-c_{2}) (\overline{x}_{2})\geq (c_{1}-c_{2}) (\underline{x}_{1}).$$
(31)

This is because \((c_{1}-c_{2})(x_{2}) \ge (c_{1}-c_{2})(\overline{x}_{2})\) by the first part of the lemma. Moreover, because \((c_{1}-c_{2})(\underline{x}_{1}) \ge (c_{1}-c_{2})(x_{1})\) (again by the first part of the lemma and because \(\underline{x}_{1}<d^{\ast}\)) it suffices to show (31). To this end, we consider the following two cases: Case (i) \(c_{1}^{\prime}(0)\geq c\); Case (ii) \(c_{1}^{\prime}(0)<c\). In Case (i), we have \(\underline{x}_{1}=0\). Thus, proving (2) reduces to checking \((c_{1}-c_{2})(\overline{x}_{2})\geq0\), which follows from Assumption 1(vi).

In Case (ii), we have

where we use the fact that 0< \(\underline{x}_{1}\) to conclude that \(c_{1}^{\prime}(x)=c_{2}^{\prime}(x+d_{1}-d_{2})<c\) for \(x<\underline{x}_{1} \). □

Proof of Proposition 1

Given a feasible policy for which there exists an interval (t 1,t 2) such that Δ1(t)>0, we can improve the objective by modifying Δ1(⋅) on (t 1,t 2) such that Δ1(t)=0. This also relaxes the constraint (12). Thus, without loss of optimality, we have Δ1(t)=0 for all t. Similarly, it follows that Δ2(t)=(c 1-c 2)(τ 1(t)) for all t. □

Proof of Proposition 3

First, we verify that q i (⋅) is monotone. To that end, note that if \(W>\lambda_{1} \underline{\tilde{x}}_{1}+\lambda_{2} \underline{x}_{2}\), then \(q_{1}(W)=\underline{\tilde{x}}_{1}\), and \(q_{2}(W)=W-\underline{\tilde{x}}_{1}\), and the result follows. Otherwise, i.e., \(W\le \lambda_{1}\underline{\tilde{x}}_{1}+\lambda_{2} \underline{x}_{2}\), then a necessary condition for optimality is that

$$ \biggl \vert \tilde{h}_1^\prime \biggl(\frac{q_1}{\lambda_1} \biggr)-h_2^\prime \biggl(\frac{q_2}{\lambda_2} \biggr)\biggr \vert $$
(32)

is minimized over q 1,q 2≥0 such that q 1+q 2=W.

Let W 2>W 1 and suppose that q i (W 2)<q i (W 1) for some i∈{1,2}, then we must have q j (W 2)>q j (W 1)+(W 2-W 1) for ji. Notice that setting q i (W 2)=q i (W 1) and q j (W 2)=q j (W 1)+W 2-W 1 decreases the difference in (32) by the strict convexity of \(\tilde{h}_{1}\) on \((0, \underline{\tilde{x}}_{1}) \) and h 2 on \((0, \underline{x}_{2})\) (which follows from strict convexity of c i on [0,α i ]). Thus, q i (⋅) is monotone. That is, for W 2>W 1,

(33)
(34)

Putting q 1(W)=W-q 2(W) in (34) gives

$$q_2(W_2)-q_2(W_1)\le W_2-W_1. $$
(35)

Then combining (33) and (35) gives the Lipschitz continuity of q 2(⋅):

$$q_2(W_2)-q_2(W_1)\le |W_2-W_1|.$$

The Lipschitz continuity of q 1(⋅) follows similarly. Finally, we note by the minimality of q 1(⋅) (among multiple optimal solutions) that

$$\frac{q_1(W)}{\lambda_1}\le \frac{q_2(W)}{\lambda_2} \quad \mbox{and}\quad \frac{q_1(W)}{\lambda_1}\le \underline{\tilde{x}}_1,$$

from which we conclude that q 2(W)≥ 2/(λ 1+λ 2). □

Appendix B: Proofs of auxiliary results in Sect. 6.2

Proof of Lemma 2

It suffices to show that for i=1,2

$$\mathbb{P} \biggl(\bigl \vert A_i^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)-A_i^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)-\lambda_i^n\bigl(t_k^n-t_{k-1}^n\bigr) \bigr \vert >\frac{\zeta}{2}n^\beta \biggr) \le \frac{C_1}{2}e^{-C_2\zeta^2n^{2\beta-1+\alpha_1}}.$$

By Theorem 2.1 of Csorgo and Horvath [13], there exists a standard Brownian motion \(\tilde{B}_{i}\) and an error process \(\tilde{\varepsilon}_{i}^{n}\) for each n such that

$$A_i^n(t)=\lambda_i nt+\sqrt{\lambda_i n}\tilde{B}_i(t)+\tilde{\varepsilon}_i^n(t)\quad \mbox{for }t\ge 0,$$

where for positive constants \(\tilde{C}_{1}, \tilde{C}_{2}\)

$$\mathbb{P} \Bigl(\sup_{0\le t\le T}\bigl \vert \tilde{\varepsilon}^n(t)\bigr \vert >\tilde{C}_1 \log (\lambda_inT)+x \Bigr)\le \tilde{C}_1 e^{-\tilde{C}_2x}.$$

Using this result, we write for n sufficiently large that

Note by a straightforward application of Markov’s inequality that

$$\mathbb{P} \bigl(\bigl \vert \tilde{B}_i(1)\bigr \vert >x \bigr)\le 2\exp\bigl\{-x^2/2\bigr\} \quad \mbox{for } x>0.$$

Then for i=1,2,

where the last inequality follows for n sufficiently large because \(\frac{1-\alpha_{1}}{2}<\beta<1-\alpha_{1}\).

Then letting

$$C_1=2(2+\tilde{C}_1) \quad \mbox{and}\quad C_2=\frac{1}{32(\lambda_1+\lambda_2)},$$

the result follows. □

Appendix C: Proofs of technical results in Sect. 6.3

Proof of Lemma 3

Fix T>0, and note that , which provides the induction basis. As the induction hypothesis assume that

for j=0,1,…,k-1. Then it suffices to show that

(36)

To this end, note that

(37)

Consider the first term on the right-hand side:

Next, we consider each term on the right-hand side:

(38)

for sufficiently large n, where the first inequality follows since \(q_{2} ( \widehat{Q}^{n}(t_{k}^{n}) ) \geq 0\), and

$$Q_{2}^{n}\bigl(t_{k-1}^{n}\bigr)\leq Q^{n}\bigl(t_{k-1}^{n}\bigr)\leq W^{n}\bigl(t_{k-1}^{n}\bigr)+\varepsilon \leq \frac{2\delta }{3n^{\varepsilon }}\sqrt{n}$$

for sufficiently large n. The third inequality follows from the fact that

$$\widehat{Q}_{2}^{n}\bigl(t_{k}^{n}\bigr)-\widehat{Q}_{2}^{n}\bigl(t_{k-1}^{n}\bigr)\leq \frac{A_{2}^{n}(t_{k}^{n})-A_{2}^{n}(t_{k-1}^{n})}{\sqrt{n}}.$$

The fourth inequality follows independence of the increments of the Poisson process, while the last inequality follow from Lemma 2 for n sufficiently large where the right-hand side \(\delta \sqrt{n}/(3n^{\varepsilon })\) was replaced by its half to account for centering of the left-hand side.

Similarly,

Note that the second term on the right-hand side is zero for n sufficiently large since

$$q_2 \bigl(\widehat{Q}^n \bigl(t_k^n\bigr) \bigr)\le \widehat{Q}^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)\le \widehat{W}^n \bigl(t_k^n\bigr) +\frac{3}{\sqrt{n}} \le \frac{2\delta}{3n^\varepsilon}+\frac{3}{\sqrt{n}}<\frac{\delta}{n^\varepsilon}.$$

Moreover, for sufficiently large n,

(39)

Then combining (38)–(39) we conclude that

(40)

Next, consider

and note that

where

First, consider \(p_{1}^{n}\) and recall that on we have

$$\bigl \vert \widehat{Q}_{2}^{n}\bigl(t_{k-1}^{n}\bigr)-q_{2} \bigl( \widehat{Q}^{n}\bigl(t_{k-1}^{n}\bigr) \bigr) \bigr \vert \leq \frac{\delta }{n^{\varepsilon }}.$$

Thus, on the event of interest we have

$$\widehat{q}_{2} \bigl( \widehat{Q}^{n}\bigl(t_{k-1}^{n}\bigr) \bigr) <\widehat{Q}_{2}^{n}\bigl(t_{k-1}^{n}\bigr)\leq q_{2} \bigl(\widehat{Q}^{n}\bigl(t_{k-1}^{n}\bigr) \bigr)+\frac{\delta }{n^{\varepsilon }}.$$

Also note that

Since \(\widehat{W}_{n}(t_{k-1}^{n})>\frac{\delta}{3n^{\varepsilon}}\) on the event of interest, for sufficiently large n we have

$$W^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)>\frac{ \delta n^{0.5-\varepsilon}}{3}>\mu^n\kappa^n.$$

Thus, the incremental idleness during [t k-1,t k ] will be zero. Then

$$W^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)-W^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)=A_1^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)+A_2^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)-A_1^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)-A_2^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)-\mu^n\kappa^n.$$

Moreover, since |Q n(t)-W n(t)]|≤3 for all t≥0, we write

$$\bigl \vert Q^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)-Q^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)\bigr \vert \le \bigl \vert A_1^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)+A_2^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)-A_1^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)-A_2^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)-\mu^n\kappa^n\bigr \vert +6,$$

and therefore,

by Lipschitz continuity of q 2(⋅). Then we can write

(41)

Also note that since (by Proposition 3)

we have \(Q_{2}^{n}(t)>0\) for all \(t\in \lbrack t_{k-1}^{n},t_{k}^{n}]\) for n sufficiently large.

Moreover, since \(\widehat{Q}_{2}^{n}(t_{k-1}^{n})>q_{2} (\widehat{Q}^{n}(t_{k-1}^{n}) )\), the flexible server works on class 2 during \([t_{k-1}^{n}, t_{k}^{n}]\). Then

(42)

Combining (41)–(42), we see that a necessary condition for the event of interest is that

On the event of interest, we have \(Q_{2}^{n}(t_{k-1}^{n})\leq \sqrt{n}q_{2} ( \widehat{Q}_{2}^{n}(t_{k-1}^{n}) ) +\frac{\delta \sqrt{n}}{n^{\varepsilon }}\). Thus, we conclude that

Then for sufficiently large n,

Then we conclude by Lemma 2 that

(43)

Next, consider \(p_{4}^{n}\) and note that

(44)

We first bound the first term on the right-hand side of (44):

where the first term on the right is zero for n sufficiently large. To bound the second term on the right note that we can argue as in bounding \(p_{1}^{n}\) that

Then for n sufficiently large

by Lemma 2. Thus we have the following bound for the first term on the right-hand side of (44).

(45)

For bounding the second term on the right-hand side of (44) note that, the flexible server gives priority to class 1 on \([t_{k-1}^{n}, t_{k}^{n}]\), and since

$$\widehat{Q}_2^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)\le q_2 \bigl(\widehat{Q}^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr) \bigr)-\frac{\delta}{2n^\varepsilon},$$

we have

$$\widehat{Q}_1^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)>q_1 \bigl(\widehat{Q}^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr) \bigr)+\frac{\delta}{2n^\varepsilon}\ge \frac{\delta}{2n^\varepsilon} >\frac{\mu^n\kappa^n}{\sqrt{n}}$$

for n sufficiently large, which in return implies that \(Q_{1}^{n}(t)>0\) for all t∈[t k-1,t k ]. Therefore, the flexible server cannot serve any class 2 jobs during [t k-1,t k ].

Note that on the event of interest we have

$$q_2 \bigl(\widehat{Q}^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr) \bigr)-\frac{\delta}{2n^\varepsilon}\le q_2 \bigl(\widehat{Q}\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr) \bigr)-\frac{\delta}{2n^\varepsilon}.$$

Also note that

$$W^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)=W^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)+A^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)-A^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)-\mu^n\kappa^n+L^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)-L^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr).$$

However, since \(\widehat{W}^{n}(t_{k-1}^{n})>\frac{\delta}{3n^{\varepsilon}}\), we have \(L^{n}(t_{k}^{n})-L^{n}(t_{k-1}^{n})=0\) for n sufficiently large. Hence

$$W^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)-W^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)=A^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)-A^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)-\mu^n\kappa^n.$$

Moreover, since |Q n(t)-W n(t)|≤3 for all t, we write

$$\bigl \vert Q^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)-Q^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)\bigr \vert \le \bigl \vert A_1^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)+A_2^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)-A_1^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)-A_2^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)-\mu^n\kappa^n\bigr \vert +6,$$

and therefore,

(46)

In particular,

(47)

Furthermore, since the flexible server exerts no effort on class 2, we have

(48)

Combining (47) and (48), a necessary condition for \(\widehat{Q}_{2}^{n}(t_{k}^{n})<q_{2} (\widehat{Q}^{n}(t_{k}^{n}) )-\frac{\delta}{n^{\varepsilon}}\) is that

Since \(\widehat{Q}_{2}^{n}(t_{k-1}^{n})>q_{2} ( \widehat{Q}^{n}(t_{k-1}) ) -\frac{\delta }{n^{\varepsilon }}\) on the event of interest for sufficiently large n,

We can thus argue as in the case of bounding \(p_{1}^{n}\) that for sufficiently large n,

(49)

Then combining (45) and (49), we conclude that for sufficiently large n

(50)

Next consider \(p_{2}^{n}\), and note that a necessary condition on for \(\widehat{Q}_{2}^{n}(t_{k}^{n})>q_{2} ( \widehat{Q}^{n}(t_{k}^{n}) )+\frac{\delta }{n^{\varepsilon }}\) and \(\widehat{Q}_{2}^{n}(t_{k-1}^{n})<q_{2} ( \widehat{Q}^{n}(t_{k-1}^{n}) ) \) is that at least one of the following holds:

$$\widehat{Q}_{2}^{n}\bigl(t_{k}^{n}\bigr)-\widehat{Q}_{2}^{n}\bigl(t_{k-1}^{n}\bigr)>\frac{\delta }{3n^{\varepsilon }},\qquad q_{2} \bigl( \widehat{Q}^{n}\bigl(t_{k-1}^{n}\bigr) \bigr) -q_{2} \bigl(\widehat{Q}^{n}\bigl(t_{k}^{n}\bigr) \bigr) >\frac{\delta }{3n^{\varepsilon }}.$$

Otherwise,

which is a contradiction. Therefore,

Note that for sufficiently large n,

$$\mathbb{P} \biggl(A_2^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)-A_2^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)>\frac{\delta}{3n^\varepsilon}\sqrt{n} \biggr) \le C_1 \exp\biggl \{-C_2\frac{\delta^2}{36}n^{\alpha_1-2\varepsilon}\biggr\}.$$

Moreover, since \(W^{n}(t_{k-1}^{n})>\frac{\delta \sqrt{n}}{3n^{\varepsilon}}\), for sufficiently large n, we have

$$W^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)-W^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)=A_1^n\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)+A_2\bigl(t_k^n\bigr)-A_1^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)-A_2^n\bigl(t_{k-1}^n\bigr)-\mu^n\kappa^n.$$

Thus,

Note that for sufficiently large n,

Therefore, for sufficiently large n

(51)

Similarly, note that

Note that for sufficiently large n

(52)

Also note that, as in the case of bounding \(p^{n}_{2}\),

(53)

Then combining (52) and (53), we have

(54)

Then combining (40), (43), (50), (51), and (54) we conclude for sufficiently large n that

where C 3=13C 1 and \(C_{4}=\frac{C_{2}z_{2}^{2}}{16(L_{2}+1)^{2}}\), and the last inequality follows since ε<0.5-α 2. □

Proof of Lemma 4

First, note that on the set of (for sufficiently large n) the number of class 2 jobs arriving in each period exceeds \(\mu_{2a}^{n}\) but is less than \(\mu_{2a}^{n}+3\mu_{2b}^{n}\). Next, recall that \(Q_{2a}^{n}(0)=Q_{2b}^{n}(0)=0\). So, k=0 constitutes an induction basis. As the induction hypothesis assume that (29) holds for k=1,…,j, and consider k=j+1. If \(Q_{2a}^{n}(t_{j+1}^{n})<\lfloor \lambda_{2} \underline{x}_{2}\sqrt{n} \rfloor\), then there are two possibilities during \([t_{j}^{n}, t_{j+1}^{n}]\) under the proposed policy: Either there were not enough arrivals during \([t_{j}^{n}, t_{j+1}^{n}]\) to have \(Q_{2a}^{n}(t_{j+1}^{n})=\lfloor \lambda_{2} \underline{x}_{2} \sqrt{n}\rfloor\), or the server pool 2a received help from other server pools during \([t_{j}^{n}, t_{j+1}^{n}]\) . In the latter case, (since the other server pools cannot help class 2a before helping class 2b when they are idle) it must be that \(Q_{2b}^{n}(t) = 0\) for some \(t\in [t_{j}^{n}, t_{j+1}^{n}]\). Thus, on the set , in this case

$$Q_{2b}^n \bigl(t_{j+1}^n\bigr)\le A_2^n \bigl(t_{j+1}^n\bigr)-A_2^n\bigl(t_j^n\bigr)-\mu_{2a}^n\le 3\mu_{2b}^n.$$

If the server pool 2a did not receive help during \([t_{j}^{n}, t_{j+1}^{n}]\) , i.e., the former case, then at most \(\mu_{2b}^{n}\) jobs are routed to class 2b during \([t_{j}^{n}, t_{j+1}^{n}]\). Then we have two further subcases to consider.

Case (i). \(Q_{2a}^{n}(t_{j}^{n})=\lfloor \lambda_{2}\underline{x}_{2}\sqrt{n}\rfloor\). This is not possible because with no help to server pool 2a we would have \(Q_{2a}^{n}(t_{j+1}^{n})=\lfloor \lambda_{2}\underline{x}_{2}\sqrt{n}\rfloor\) on the set , which is a contradiction.

Case (ii). \(Q_{2a}^{n}(t_{j}^{n})<\lfloor \lambda_{2}\underline{x}_{2}\sqrt{n}\rfloor\), which is the only remaining possibility. Then by the induction hypothesis \(Q_{2b}^{n}(t_{j}^{n})\le 3\mu_{2b}^{n}\). Thus

$$Q_{2b}^n\bigl(t_{j+1}^n\bigr)\le \bigl[Q_{2b}^n\bigl(t_j^n\bigr)-\mu_{2b}^n \bigr]^++\mu_{2b}^n \le 3\mu_{2b}^n.$$

 □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ata, B., Olsen, T.L. Congestion-based leadtime quotation and pricing for revenue maximization with heterogeneous customers. Queueing Syst 73, 35–78 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11134-012-9288-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11134-012-9288-8

Keywords

Mathematics Subject Classification (2000)

Navigation