Skip to main content
Log in

More political representation, more economic development? Evidence from Turkey

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

I investigate the effect of political representation on local economic development, as measured by nighttime light intensity (NTLI), in Turkey between 1996 and 2013 (i.e., between legislative term 20 and 24). Parliamentary seats are apportioned by a rule that generates randomness in the extent of provincial representation in the Turkish Parliament. By exploiting that exogenous variation, I estimate the impact of one additional Member of Parliament (MP) representing a province on that province’s economic growth. Specifically, I show that an extra MP increases the NTLI of her province by 1% in a given year, which corresponds to an annual increase of 0.095% in real GDP. The increase likely is driven by MPs who are members of the government party. By investigating the mechanisms, I find that additional provincial representation increases the number of discussions of that particular province in public parliamentary meetings, as well as the funds allocated to that province. Taken together, my results suggest that some of Turkey’s regional economic growth is associated with legislative representation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Early Athens, the Paris Commune, and some US states historically have adopted direct democracy.

  2. Their results, whose sample period is from 1972 to 1990, are sensitive to the time period studied; the positive effect of more effective representation on federal spending seems to hinge on events that happened between 1972 and 1982 (Matthews et al. 2011).

  3. The main reason could be the difficulty of applying a clear and valid identification strategy. It is possible that a district’s political representation is correlated with unobserved determinants of its economic growth. In general, more representation often is associated with larger population, which, in turn, might be associated with such unobservables. Different regions with different populations could have different technological bases, different discount rates, and different incentives for human capital formation and knowledge expansion, all of which are difficult to quantify, but influence a region’s economic fortunes (Simon 1986; Becker et al. 1999). It also is challenging to distinguish empirically between the effects of political representation from the effects of either population levels or changes in them (Elis et al. 2009). Although Elis et al. (2009) utilize the method of equal population proportions in the US House to capture the causal effect of representation on the distribution of federal outlays, they rely on a relatively small sample of 53 observations.

  4. Factors that influence a district’s economic development directly include economic institutions, capital, knowledge, technology, population, natural resources, geography, political stability, distributive policies and governmental size (Lewis 2003; Acemoglu et al. 2005; Rodrik 2012, 2014, 2018), democracy (Barro 1996; Tavares and Wacziarg 2001; Acemoglu et al. 2019), and political institutions (Przeworski and Limongi 1993).

  5. According to Column (2) of Table 9 in “Appendix”, the annual effect is (1.25/4.22/4) * 100 = 7.4%.

  6. Term 24 actually spans from 2011 to 2015, but the nighttime light data are not available after 2013. I use a province’s average NTLI per term as the proxy of provincial economic development, thus the estimated effect could be a lower bound.

  7. In term 20, Turkey had 79 provinces because Duzce belonged to Bolu and Osmaniye belonged to Adana; in term 21, it had 80 provinces because Duzce still belonged to Bolu while Osmaniye was separated from Adana. Since term 22, Turkey has been composed of 81 provinces.

  8. The number of MPs representing a province actually consists of three parts. Hereinafter, I focus on the two parts coming from the second and third step of the apportionment rule. Because in the first step each province gets at least one seat, in regressions whether or not that step is included will result only in a difference in the constant term.

  9. The total population of Turkey was approximately 60 million in 1995, and it went up to approximately 72 million in 2010. That is, each MP represented about 60 million/469 = 127,932 individuals in 1995 and 72 million/469 = 135,518 individuals in 2010.

  10. A constitutional referendum in 2007 changed the timing of subsequent elections to every four years.

  11. In fact, the unanticipated changes in the election dates did not happen only in my sample period. Throughout Turkish history, only a handful elections were held when they were scheduled. That feature primarily is explained by the country’s political instability, possibly caused by multi-party elections and a number of interventions of the military through coups.

  12. The Turkish Statistical Institute (TSI) stopped producing province-level GDP statistics in 2001 and restarted it in 2004. Besides the missing 2 years of GDP information (2002 and 2003), the two series are not comparable, as the TSI started using a different method for computing GDP in 2004.

  13. I show the results of two subsamples in Table 11 in “Appendix”. Columns (1) and (2) show the outcomes of terms 20 and 21; columns (3) and (4) show the results of terms 22, 23 and 24.

  14. The original index values range from 0 to 63, which are multiplied by 1000 in my sample.

  15. The average \(NTLI\) is 3.372; therefore, the percentage increase is computed as (0.135/3.372) * 100, which is an increase of 4% in a parliamentary term or, an increase of 1% per year.

  16. I also have checked whether the results are sensitive to my selection of a bandwidth equal to 0.169. I re-estimate Eq. (4) using bandwidths such as 0.1, 0.2, 0.25, 0.3, and so on. The results remain virtually unchanged.

  17. In Turkey, government spending is first drawn up by the governing party without any public information; the draft is then discussed in parliamentary meetings for the 550 MPs to vote for or against it. Because the governing party has the largest representation at the national level, such a draft is very likely to pass, an outcome that aligns with the findings of Ansolabehere and Snyder (2006). In Turkey, the governing party has changed from time to time. It was RP (the Welfare Party) in term 20, DSP (the Democratic Left Party) in term 21, and AKP (the Justice and Development Party) in terms 22, 23 and 24.

  18. \(An\;additional\;seat\;to\;gov._{pt}\) and \(An\;additional\;seat\;to\;oppo._{pt}\) represent the extra seats assigned to the governing party, and to the opposition party in Province \(p\) for Term \(t,\) respectively; they add up to \(An\;additional\;seat_{pt}\). \(Seats\;prop.\;to\;pop.\;won\;by\;gov._{pt}\) stands for the number of seats allocated to the governing party that are proportional to population in Province \(p\) for Term \(t\); \(Seats\;prop.\;to\;pop.\;won\;by\;oppo._{pt}\) is the difference between \(Seats\;prop.\;to\;pop._{pt}\) and \(Seats\;prop.\;to \;pop.\;won\;by \;gov._{pt}\).

  19. The Turkish Parliament organizes parliamentary sittings according to the Rule of Procedure. MPs can speak if either their names are on the list of speakers or they are granted permission by the Speaker (Head). Once MPs are given the floor, they express their opinions about the subject being discussed. Those subjects include budget, education, culture, youth, development, tourism, and environment, and the like.

  20. The content is translated into English. The original language is Turkish. It is cited from the speech given by MP Ugur Bayraktutan, representing Artvin, on Nov. 13, 2012.

  21. The content of every parliamentary session is recorded in the Journal of Minutes of Turkiye Buyuk Millet Meclisi (TBMM). The speeches all are available on the official website of TBMM, where each word spoken by every MP is written down. For instance, in the speech above by MP Ugur Bayraktutan, the number of times that Artvin Province is mentioned is counted as 1.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robison, J. (2005). The rise of Europe: Atlantic trade, institutional change, and economic growth. American Economic Review, 95(3), 546–579.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Naidu, S., Restrepo, P., & Robison, J. A. (2019). Democracy does cause growth? Journal of Political Economy, 127(1), 47–100.

    Google Scholar 

  • Agren, H., Dahlberg, M., & Mork, E. (2006). Do politicians’ preferences correspond to those of the voters? An investigation of political representation. Public Choice, 130, 137–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aidt, T. S., & Shvets, J. (2012). Distributive politics and electoral incentives: Evidence from seven US state legislatures. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 4(3), 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ansolabehere, S., Gerber, A., & Snyder, J. (2002). Equal votes, equal money: Court-ordered expenditures in the American states. American Political Science Review, 94(4), 767–777.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ansolabehere, S., & Snyder, J. M. (2006). Party control of state government and the distribution of public expenditures. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 108(4), 547–569.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atlas, C. M., Gilligan, T. W., Hendershott, R. J., & Zupan, M. A. (1995). Slicing the federal government net spending pie: Who wins, who loses, and why. American Economic Review, 85(3), 624–629.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J. (1996). Democracy and growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S., Glaeser, E. L., & Murphy, K. M. (1999). Population and economic growth. American Economic Review, 89(2), 145–149.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen, X., & Nordhaus, W. D. (2011). Using luminosity data as a proxy for economic statistics. PNAS, 108(21), 8589–8594.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewar, M. E. (1998). Why state and local economic development programs cause so little economic development. Economic Development Quarterly, 12(1), 68–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doll, C. N. H., Muller, J., & Elvidge, C. D. (2000). Night-time imagery as a tool for global mapping of socioeconomic parameters and greenhouse gas emissions. Ambio, 29(3), 157–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doll, C. N. H., Muller, J., & Morley, J. G. (2006). Mapping regional economic activity from night-time light satellite imagery. Ecological Economics, 57, 75–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson, D., & Storeygard, A. (2016). The view from above: Applications of satellite data in economics. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 30(3), 171–198.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elis, R., Malhotra, N., & Meredith, M. (2009). Apportionment cycles as natural experiments. Political Analysis, 17, 358–376.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elvidge, C. D., Baugh, K. E., Kihn, E. A., Kroehl, H. W., & Davis, E. R. (1997). Mapping city lights with nighttime data from the DMSP operational linescan system. Photogrammetric Engineering & Remote Sensing, 63(6), 727–734.

    Google Scholar 

  • Folke, O. (2014). Shades of brown and green: Party effects in proportional election systems. Journal of the European Economic Association, 12(5), 1361–1395.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helland, L., & Sorensen, R. J. (2009). Geographical redistribution with disproportional representation: A politico-economic model of Norwegian road projects. Public Choice, 139, 5–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, V. J., Storeygard, A., & Weil, D. N. (2011). A bright idea for measuring economic growth. American Economic Review, 101(3), 194–199.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henderson, V. J., Storeygard, A., & Weil, D. N. (2012). Measuring economic growth from outer space. American Economic Review, 102(2), 994–1028.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodler, R., & Raschky, P. A. (2014). Regional favoritism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(2), 995–1033.

    Google Scholar 

  • Imbens, G. W., & Kalyanaraman, K. (2012). Optimal bandwidth choice for the regression discontinuity estimator. Review of Economic Studies, 79, 933–959.

    Google Scholar 

  • Imbens, G. W., & Lemieux, T. (2008). Regression discontinuity designs: A guide to practice. Journal of Econometrics, 142(2008), 615–635.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kang, W. C. (2015). Electoral cycles in pork barrel politics: Evidence from South Korea 1989–2008. Electoral Studies, 38, 46–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, B. (2008). Legislative representation, bargaining power and the distribution of federal funds: Evidence from the US Congress. Economic Journal, 118, 1785–1803.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, F. E. (1998). Representation and public policy: The consequences of senate apportionment for the geographic distribution of federal funds. Journal of Politics, 60(1), 34–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lessmann, C., & Seidel, A. (2017). Regional inequality, convergence, and its determinants—A view from outer space. European Economic Review, 92, 110–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S. D., & Poterba, J. M. (1999). Congressional distributive politics and state economic performance. Public Choice, 99, 185–216.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, A. W. (2003). Theory of economic growth. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, X., Ge, L., & Chen, X. (2013). Detecting Zimbabwe’s decadal economic decline using nighttime light imagery. Remote Sensing, 5, 4551–4570.

    Google Scholar 

  • Matthews, M. B., Shughart, W. F., & Stevenson, T. P. (2011). Political arithmetic: New evidence on the “small-state bias” in federal spending. Journal of Public Finance and Public Choice, 29(1–3), 55–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCrary, J. (2008). Manipulation of the running variable in the regression discontinuity design: A density test. Journal of Econometrics, 142(2008), 698–714.

    Google Scholar 

  • Michalopoulos, S., & Papaioannou, E. (2013). Pre-colonial ethnic institutions and contemporary African development. Econometrica, 81(1), 113–152.

    Google Scholar 

  • Michalopoulos, S., & Papaioannou, E. (2014). National institutions and subnational development in Africa. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(1), 151–213.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milligan, L. S., & Smart, M. (2005). Regional grants as pork barrel politics. CESifo working paper series No. 1453.

  • Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III (Part III, pp. 264–358). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Nordhaus, W. D., & Chen, X. (2015). A sharper image? Estimates of the precision of nighttime lights as a proxy for economic statistics. Journal of Economic Geography, 15, 217–246.

    Google Scholar 

  • Potrafke, N. (2013). Evidence on the political principal-agent problem from voting on public finance for concert halls. Constitutional Political Economy, 24(3), 215–238.

    Google Scholar 

  • Przeworski, A., & Limongi, F. (1993). Political regimes and economic growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(3), 51–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodden, J. (2002). Strength in numbers? Representation and redistribution in the European Union. European Union Politics, 3(2), 151–175.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (2012). Why we learn nothing from regressing economic growth on policies. Seoul Journal of Economics, 25(2), 137–151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (2014). The past, present, and future of economic growth. Challenge, 57(3), 5–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (2018). An African growth miracle? Journal of African Economics, 27(1), 10–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. A., & Weingast, B. R. (1981). Political preferences for the pork barrel: A generalization. American Journal of Political Science, 25(1), 96–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, J. L. (1986). Theory of population and economic growth. New York: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stein, R. M., & Bickers, K. N. (1994). Congressional elections and the pork barrel. Journal of Politics, 56(2), 377–399.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tavares, J., & Wacziarg, R. (2001). How democracy affects growth. European Economic Review, 45(2001), 1341–1378.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veiga, L. G., & Veiga, F. J. (2013). Intergovernmental fiscal transfers as pork barrel. Public Choice, 155, 335–353.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I thank Duha Altindag for his valuable suggestions and advices, Kang Sun for his technical support, Nicolas Ziebarth, Hyeongwoo Kim, Chris Vickers, Aditi Sengupta, and Gilad Sorek for their professional help. I thank Chris Elvidge for his explanation of the nighttime light intensity data.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jie Zhang.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 The D’Hondt method

The Turkish Parliament applies the party list (closed list) system. Given the predetermined number of seats for each province (N), each party submits a list of candidates ordered from 1 to N. The quotient is calculated for every candidate, which is equal to the vote share obtained by the party divided by the ranking of the specific candidate. For example, the quotient of the top-ranked candidate is exactly the vote share of the party, the second-ranked candidate has a quotient equal to half of the vote share, and the third-ranked candidate has a quotient equal to one-third of the vote share, and so on. As a result, higher-ranked candidates, such as the candidates who rank first, are elected before the lower-ranked candidates, such as those Nth ranked, within the same party in a province. Finally, all quotients are ordered from the largest to smallest, and the top N candidates with the top N quotients will be sent to the parliament and become MPs in the subsequent legislative term.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Discontinuity of the number of seats based on province’s decimal (term 20)

Table 9 Effect of an additional seat on budget: budget as the outcome variable
Table 10 Seats allocation to competing parties in each province
Table 11 Relation between real GDP and NTLI growth
Table 12 Balance test of the RD design
Table 13 Balance test of an additional seat to the government versus opposition party

Table 10 provides a numerical example to describe how the D’Hondt method is used in practice. In that example, five parties, V to Z, compete for six contestable seats from a given province. Each party has a ticket on which six candidates are ordered and for each candidate, the quotient is calculated. Column (2) of Panel A shows the vote share distribution of the five parties, followed by the quotients of all candidates for each party. According to the values of the quotients, the first-ranked candidates of parties W, X, Y and Z, together with the second-ranked candidates from parties Y and Z, win seats. Now, suppose that 2% of the vote share transfers from Party Y to Party V, with everything else remaining fixed, as reflected in Panel B. Following the same procedure as before, it is the first-ranked candidates of the five parties, together with the second-ranked candidate from Party Z, who win seats. A small change in the vote share among parties consequently could lead to different candidates being elected.

1.2 Nighttime light intensity (NTLI) and its relationship with GDP

I use the NTLI to measure a region’s economic development. That is because, in Turkey, no consistent measurement of GDP by province is available during my sample period (1995–2013). An extensive literature has shown that NTLI is a valid proxy for regional economic development. In fact, a variety of existing papers have used NTLI and GDP interchangeably.

I estimate the correlation between NTLI and GDP using my subsamples based on the equation specified below, which follows Henderson et al. (2012):

$$Ln\left({Real\;GDP_{pt}} \right) = c + \gamma Ln\left({NTLI_{pt}} \right) + \mu_{p} + \tau_{t} + \epsilon_{pt},$$
(8)

where \(Real\;GDP_{pt}\) and \(NTLI_{pt}\) indicate the real GDP and NTLI of Province \(p\) in parliamentary Term \(t\), respectively. I also include province fixed effects (\(\mu_{p}\)) and term dummies (\(\tau_{t}\)) in the regression. The results of the two subsamples are reported in Table 11. The estimated \(\gamma\) s are positive and statistically significant. On average, the estimators show that a 1% increase in the NTLI of a province is associated with an approximately 0.095% increase in its real GDP. The results verify that NTLI is a good measurement of regional economic development in my setting (Tables 12, 13).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Zhang, J. More political representation, more economic development? Evidence from Turkey. Public Choice 187, 275–299 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00773-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00773-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation