Skip to main content
Log in

What determines preferences for an electoral system? Evidence from a binding referendum

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Much has been written about politicians’ preferences for electoral systems, yet little is known about the preferences of voters. In 1993, New Zealand had a binding electoral referendum on the same day as the general election where voters chose between keeping a single plurality system (First Past the Post) or introducing a pure proportional one (Mixed Member Proportional). This paper merges data from all nationwide polling stations to Census data on local voters to examine what drives citizens’ preferences for an electoral system. We find that strategic partisan interest was a key driver: voters overwhelmingly preferred the system that most benefited their favorite party. However, socioeconomic characteristics and social values also mattered; people who held more progressive values, were outside the dominant religion and lived in urban areas were much more likely to vote to change to a proportional system. Survey data show that these findings hold at the individual level, and further, that individuals who were angry with the economy were much more likely to vote against the status quo, regardless of their background, party preferences or social values. This behavior is likely to have ultimately balanced the result in favor of Mixed Member Proportional.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Carey and Hix (2013) and Grofman (2016) for a comprehensive summary.

  2. Nakaguma (2015) uses a similar strategy to understand preferences for the form of government, presidential versus parliamentary, using data from the 1993 Brazilian referendum.

  3. The only exceptions we know of are Aimer and Miller (2002) which also examines the New Zealand referendum but only uses the NZES in a descriptive manner and Fournier et al. (2011) which examines a sample of citizens who chose to be part of a long-term deliberative process (one year, 20+ meetings). As the authors acknowledge, this has obvious self-selection issues.

  4. Fournier et al. (2011) is an exception but relied on self-selected participants who were all members of local assemblies in the Netherlands, Ontario and British Columbia.

  5. Voter anger was particular relevant at the time of this referendum because in the late 1980s New Zealand underwent a massive free-market de-regularization where campaign promises had been repeatedly broken by both major parties (Roper and Leitch 1995).

  6. However rational political agents may be assumed to be, the literature also recognizes that most electoral reforms cannot simply be explained by short-term self interest motivations (see, for instance, Benoit 2004; Katz 2005; Norris 2011).

  7. In particular, Aldrich et al. (2014) show that when voters expect a landslide victory of their favorite party, they prefer a ‘winner-take-all’ system, whereas when they are uncertain that their party will get the majority of votes, they prefer a proportional split. This is consistent with elites’ choices as shown in Trebbi et al. (2008).

  8. See Sidanius et al. (1994) and all work cited therein for a discussion on hierarchy-enhancing ideologies and social dominance theory. This hypothesis is also consistent with prospect theory: in their seminal piece, Quattrone and Tversky (1995) show that in the political arena people behave similarly as when making economic decisions. I.e., risk-averse in gains and risk-seeking in losses.

  9. See, for instance, Hooghe and Dassonneville (2018a, b), Kselman and Niou (2011) or Pop-Eleches (2010).

  10. It was “made in a context of ongoing pressure for a referendum on the electoral system, increasing public dissatisfaction with the political process and intensifying concern about the government’s willingness to override public opinion” (Vowles 2008, p. 24).

  11. The four possible alternatives were Single Transferable Vote (STV), Supplementary Member (SM), Alternative Vote (AV) and Mixed Member Proportional (MMP).

  12. A non-binding referendum was held in 2011, in which 57% of the population voted to keep MMP.

  13. Unless there is an ’overhang’, a situation in which the number of MPs may increase in very small numbers. Overhang situations arise when a party wins more districts than the number of MPs designated via the party vote.

  14. Parties are required to get greater than five percent of the overall party vote or win an electoral seat to get their full allocation of seats in parliament.

  15. As an example, suppose that a party wins 35% of the party votes and wins in 20 of the 71 electorates with the ‘electorate vote’. Given that 35% of 120 is 42, this party gains 42 MPs. The first 20 MPs are those who have won the local race via the electorate vote. The other 22 are the first 22 members of the nationwide party list. On the other hand, if a party wins more electorates than the MPs allocated with its share of the party vote, then a situation of an overhang arises. For example, if a party wins 6% of the party votes (which translates into 7 MPs) and 9 electorates, then the number of total MPs rises to 122, and the party gets to keep all its 9 locally elected MPs.

  16. The “Electoral Act (1993)”, reprinted as of July 1, 2017, can be found at http://www.legislation.govt.nz/act/public/1993/0087/latest/DLM307519.html.

  17. Labour traditionally won all of the Māori seats which may be an additional reason why many party members were supportive of changing to MMP.

  18. Electoral Amendment Act, 1945, Nov. 12, No. 10; Electoral Amendment Act, 1950, Oct. 6, No. 32; Electoral Amendment Act, 1956, Oct. 26, No. 107.

  19. According to the ‘Voter and non-Voter Survey Report’ issued by the Electoral Commission, 93% voted in a polling station closest to their home in 2008, whereas 92% did so in 2011. There is no data available for previous elections, but there is no reason to suspect that patterns have recently changed in any particular direction.

  20. We are able to geolocate all but seven polling stations which we exclude from our analysis.

  21. The few area units that have three or more polling stations are generally large ones in rural areas. In the Supplementary Materials (Tables IV, VI and VIII) we show that when we cluster standard errors at the area unit level all results hold.

  22. This dataset is not publicly available and was obtained directly from the Electoral Commission. It contains data from 1998. Since the changes in roll composition were minor from 1993 to 1998, we take this as an adequate proxy for the 1993 roll composition.

  23. A special vote is a vote made by an elector who is unable to visit a polling place in their own electorate on election day, or is not on the electoral roll on election day.

  24. Table II in the Supplementary Materials shows the descriptive statistics for the sociodemographic characteristics we include in the regression.

  25. Our preferred specification in all tables is the last column. We report different specifications to provide evidence that results are consistent throughout, and not a result of our particular choice.

  26. Table III in the Supplementary Materials shows that results are robust to including all polling stations from Māori electorates.

  27. Table V in the Supplementary Materials shows that all results hold when including Māori and votes in polling stations that are not located geographically (i.e., “special” votes).

  28. Technically, citizens can also cast their vote in other electorates, but this involves a serious amount of paperwork and very few voters resort to it.

  29. Unfortunately, the 1993 NZES survey did not include respondents’ perceptions of the left (0)–right (10) position of these parties, but the 1996 survey did so. On average, New Zealand First was placed at 5.4, whereas the Christian Coalition, the coalition that included Christian Heritage and the Christian Democrat Party, was placed at 6.9. For reference, National and Labour were at 6.9 and 3.7.

  30. We would like to note that these results hinge on a small subset of our respondents: in our sample, there are 102 voters of New Zealand First (7.9% of the total) and 18 of Christian Heritage (1.4%).

  31. Most specifications show that Māori are significantly more likely to support MMP. Nonetheless, Māori are highly underrepresented in the 1993 sample. Hence, given the small number of observations, we prefer to take this result with a grain of salt.

  32. For more on the discussion of the growth (or lack thereof) of anti-establishment voting and policy platforms, see Goodwin and Heath (2016), Hooghe and Dassonneville (2018a, b) and Hanley and Sikk (2016).

References

  • Aimer, P., & Miller, R. (2002). Partisanship and principle: Voters and the New Zealand electoral referendum of 1993. European Journal of Political Research, 41, 795–809.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich, J., Reifler, J., & Munger, M. C. (2014). Sophisticated and myopic? Citizen preferences for Electoral College reform. Public Choice, 158, 541–558.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bawn, K. (1993). The logic of institutional preferences: German electoral law as a social choice outcome. American Journal of Political Science, 37, 965–989.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benoit, K. (2004). Models of electoral system change. Electoral Studies, 23, 363–389.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benoit, K. (2007). Electoral laws as political consequences: Explaining the origins and change of electoral institutions. Annual Review of Political Science, 10, 363–390.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blais, A., Laslier, J.-F., Poinas, F., & Van Der Straeten, K. (2015). Citizens’ preferences about voting rules: Self-interest, ideology, and sincerity. Public Choice, 164, 423–442.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C. (1999). Setting the rules of the game: The choice of electoral systems in advanced democracies. American Political Science Review, 93(3), 609–624.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bol, D. (2016). Electoral reform, values and party self-interest. Party Politics, 22(1), 93–104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowler, S., Donovan, T., & Karp, J. A. (2006). Why politicians like electoral institutions: Self-interest, values, or ideology? The Journal of Politics, 68(2), 434–446.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carey, J., & Hix, S. (2013). Policy consequences of electoral rules. In M. Htun & G. Bingham Powell (Eds.), Political science, electoral rules, and democratic governance (pp. 46–55). Washington, DC: American Political Science Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Colomer, J. M. (2004). The strategy and history of electoral system choice. In Handbook of electoral system choice.

  • Duverger, M. (1951). Les Partis Politiques, (2 éd.). rev. et mise à jour. ed. Paris: A. Colin.

  • Duverger, M. (1955). The political role of women. Paris: United Nations Economic and Social Council.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fournier, P., van der Kolk, H., Carty, R. K., Blais, A., & Rose, J. (2011). When citizens decide: Lessons from citizen assemblies on electoral reform. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibson, J., Kim, B., Stillman, S., & Boe-Gibson, G. (2013). Time to vote? Public Choice, 156(3–4), 517–536.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin, M. J., & Heath, O. (2016). The 2016 referendum, Brexit and the left behind: An aggregate-level analysis of the result. The Political Quarterly, 87(3), 323–332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grofman, B. (2016). Perspectives on the comparative study of electoral systems. Annual Review of Political Science, 19, 523–540.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanley, S., & Sikk, A. (2016). Economy, corruption or floating voters? Explaining the breakthroughs of anti-establishment reform parties in eastern Europe. Party Politics, 22(4), 522–533.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hobolt, S. B. (2016). The Brexit vote: A divided nation, a divided continent. Journal of European Public Policy, 23(9), 1259–1277.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hooghe, M., & Dassonneville, R. (2018a). A spiral of distrust: A panel study on the relation between political distrust and protest voting in Belgium. Government and Opposition, 53(1), 104–130.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hooghe, M., & Dassonneville, R. (2018b). Explaining the Trump vote: The effect of racist resentment and anti-immigrant sentiments. PS: Political Science & Politics, 51(3), 528–534.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2006). Electoral institutions and the politics of coalitions: Why some democracies redistribute more than others? American Political Science Review, 100, 165–181.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kauffman, E. (2016). It’s NOT the economy, stupid: Brexit as a story of personal values. British Politics and Policy at LSE. http://blogs.lse.ac.uk/politicsandpolicy/personal-values-brexit-vote/.

  • Katz, R. S. (2005). Why are there so many (or so few) electoral reforms? In M. Gallagher & P. Mitchell (Eds.), The politics of electoral systems (pp. 57–76). Oxford: OUP Oxford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kedar, O., Harsgor, L., & Sheinerman, R. A. (2016). Are voters equal under proportional representation? American Journal of Political Science, 60(3), 676–691.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krosnick, J. A. (1999). Survey research. Annual Review of Psychology, 50, 537–567.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kselman, D., & Niou, E. (2011). Protest voting in plurality elections: A theory of voter signaling. Public Choice, 148(3), 395–418.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leonard, R. (2017) Why Rural America Voted for Trump. The New York Times. January 5, 2017. https://www.nytimes.com/2017/01/05/opinion/why-rural-america-voted-for-trump.html.

  • Levine, S., & Roberts, N. S. (1993). The New Zealand electoral referendum of 1992. Electoral Studies, 12(2), 158–167.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1984). Democracies: Patterns of majoritarian & consensus government in twenty-one countries. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lizzeri, A., & Persico, N. (2001). The provision of public goods under alternative electoral incentives. American Economic Review, 91, 225–239.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lynskey, D. (2017). ‘I thought I?d put in a protest vote’: The people who regret voting leave. The Guardian, 25 November 2017. https://www.theguardian.com/politics/2017/nov/25/protest-vote-regret-voting-leave-brexit. Accessed 20 January 2018.

  • Matland, R. E., & Studlar, D. T. (1996). The contagion of women candidates in single-member district and proportional representation electoral systems: Canada and Norway. The Journal of Politics, 58(3), 707–733.

    Google Scholar 

  • McAllister, I. (1982). The Australian democrats: Protest vote or portent of realignment? Politics, 17(1), 68–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milesi-Ferretti, G.-M., Perotti, R., & Rostagno, M. (2002). Electoral systems and public spending. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(2), 609–657.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morelli, M. (2004). Party formation and policy outcomes under different electoral systems. The Review of Economic Studies, 71(3), 829–853.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nagel, J. H. (2004). New Zealand: Reform by (nearly) immaculate design. In J. M. Colomer (Ed.), The Handbook of Electoral System Choice (pp. 530–543). New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nakaguma, M. Y. (2015). Choosing the form of government: Theory and evidence from Brazil. The Economic Journal, 125(589), 1986–2023.

    Google Scholar 

  • New Europe. (2017). Voting in the Catalan referendum becomes an act of protest. New Europe, 2 October 2017. https://www.neweurope.eu/article/voting-catalan-referendum-becomes-act-protest/. Accessed 20 January 2018.

  • New Zealand Parliamentary Library. The origins of the Māori seats, Parliamentary Library Research Paper. https://www.parliament.nz/resource/en-NZ/00PLLawRP03141/e27e432e971eb1f60ea75b00c987a39e4b2e62ce (2003, updated 2009 version).

  • Pop-Eleches, G. (2010). Throwing out the bums: Protest voting and unorthodox parties after communism. World Politics, 62(2), 221–260.

    Google Scholar 

  • Norris, P. (1985). Women’s legislative participation in Western Europe. West European Politics, 8(4), 90–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Norris, P. (2011). Cultural explanations of electoral reform: A policy cycle model. West European Politics, 34(3), 531–550.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2004). Constitutional rules and fiscal policy outcomes. American Economic Review, 94(1), 25–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., Roland, G., & Tabellini, G. (2007). Electoral rules and government spending in parliamentary democracies. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 2, 155–188.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., Tabellini, G., & Trebbi, F. (2003). Electoral rules and corruption. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1(4), 958–989.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pino, F. Is there gender bias among voters? Evidence from the Chilean congressional elections. ECARES Working Paper 2014-53. http://www.franciscopino.com/Site/Research.html.

  • Quattrone, G. A., & Tversky, A. (1995). Contrasting rational and psychological analyses of political choice. American Political Science Review, 82(3), 719–736.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roper, J., & Leitch, S. (1995). The electoral reform campaigns in New Zealand: A political communication case study. Australian Journal of Communication, 22(1), 123–135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sidanius, J., Pratto, F., & Rabinowitz, J. L. (1994). Gender, ethnic status, and ideological asymmetry: A social dominance interpretation. Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 25(2), 194–216.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trebbi, F., Aghion, P., & Alesina, A. (2008). Electoral rules and minority representation in US cities. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(1), 325–357.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vowles, J. (2008). Systemic failure, coordination, and contingencies: Understanding electoral system change in New Zealand. In A. Blais (Ed.), To keep or to change first past the post? The politics of electoral reform (pp. 163–182). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (2007). Choosing the rules: Preferences over voting systems for assemblies of representatives. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2017.01.016.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wenzel, J. P., Bowler, S., & Lanoue, D. J. (2000). Citizen opinion and constitutional choices: The case of the UK. Political Behavior, 22(3), 241–265.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Financial support from Yale-NUS College is gratefully acknowledged. We would like to thank Kai Ostwald, Julien Labonne, Risa Toha, Rene Saran and the audiences at the National University of Singapore, the University of Montréal, and the Political Economy Workshop at the University of New South Wales for their comments. We would like to especially thank Liang Yun, Yaow Yu Hung and Weiliang Tan for excellent research assistance. All errors are ours.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Guillem Riambau.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 1316 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Riambau, G., Stillman, S. & Boe-Gibson, G. What determines preferences for an electoral system? Evidence from a binding referendum. Public Choice 186, 179–208 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00770-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00770-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation