Skip to main content
Log in

A theory of predatory welfare state and citizen welfare: the French case

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we argue that the welfare state is an outcome of modern mass (total) warfare. The total war economy requires the participation of all citizens, erasing the differences between the military and citizens. Consequently, the war economy benefits from succoring the civilian population. The total war effect explains why a predatory state undertakes welfare programs, one of the contributions of the present paper. While the welfare state is closely related to total warfare, social welfare is not. Fraternal social welfare organizations in the United States predate the New Deal and the rise of welfare state. Similarly, the French welfare system was born as citizen welfare and not as state welfare. In fact, welfare programs were initiated in 1871 during the Paris Commune by workers under the name of la sociale and were recreated as self-managed citizen groups in 1945 before being displaced by government welfare programs. A second contribution of this paper is to explore the re-appropriation effect, or the way self-managed citizen welfare was transformed into a welfare state through a three-stage reform process manifesting itself in 1946, 1967 and 1996.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. By a predatory state, we mean a state that “would specify a set of property rights that maximized the revenue of the group in power, regardless of its impact on the wealth of the society as a whole” (North 1981, p. 22). It would promote the private interests of dominant interest groups inside the state (such as politicians, the army and bureaucrats) or influential private groups with strong lobbying powers (Vahabi 2016a, b). Mainstream economics disregards such a type of state and assumes a contractual state that plays the role of social-wealth-maximizer. Does a predatory state mean a budget-maximizing state or a bellicose one? Following Usher (1992), we consider taxation to be a form of predation and budget-maximizing to be a characteristic feature of a predatory state. Predation is not inconsistent with a bellicose state, since war often has provided an excellent pretext for maximizing the state budget. Not only has the army benefited from a war economy and politicians from an uncontested political authority; some private enterprises have secured colossal rents thanks to their privileged partnerships with the state’s most influential groups. Max Weber has called it ‘booty’ or ‘political capitalism’ (Weber 1922/1968, pp. 164–166; see also Vahabi 2004).

  2. In another vein, Ly (2007) examines charitable donations to terrorist organizations to show the symbiotic relationship of welfare and warfare.

  3. Skocopol (1992) argues that, compared to the British or European welfare states, the United States has a maternalist rather than a paternalist welfare state.

  4. For the data, see Overbye (1995, p. 314). According to The Economist (July 14th–20th 2018, p. 12): “Spending on ‘social protection’, such as pensions, unemployment insurance and assistance for the hard up, has risen from an average of about 5% of GDP in rich countries in 1960–20% today.” Elaborating the ascendancy of a predatory state in the United States, Galbraith (2009) also underlines that state intervention in healthcare, higher education, housing, and social security accounts for nearly 40% of US GDP. Moreover, the direct contribution of nonmilitary public spending at the federal, state, and local levels amounts to another 14% of GDP: “the United States is not a ‘free-market” economy with an underdeveloped or withered state sector” (Galbraith 2009, p. 112).

  5. Interestingly, Herce et al.’s (2001, p. 64) test of causality between GDP and social protection expenditure in the European Union indicates the explanatory significance of citizens’ “sense of security”.

  6. In rational conflict theory, war is regarded as part of the bargaining process to achieve peace. Accordingly, the advocates of rational conflict theory interpreted Clausewitz’s (2006/1827) ‘total’ or ‘absolute’ war as a war that never happens in reality (Sánchez-Pagés 2009). The only type of war that was assumed to be ‘rationally conceivable’ was Clausewitz’s ‘battle’ (limited confrontation) to remove misconceptions or asymmetric information between the belligerent parties. That interpretation suffers from a major shortcoming, however, namely revolutionary wars. In such wars against tyranny, the objective is the total destruction of the enemy and not in reaching a compromise. In fact, Clausewitz’s total war explicitly pertained to revolutionary wars that were effective against tyranny. He defined ‘total war’ with respect to its objectives rather than its means. For him, total war implied a war to the last, targeting the complete destruction of the enemy’s military might, its political system or even its culture. He did not describe ‘total war’ in terms of using modern industrial means requiring the mobilization of the entire society. In this paper, we are using total war in the latter sense.

  7. Although the war ended officially in February, it continued in the east of France. “The badly devised armistice led to the destruction of the second largest French army. Immediately after the cessation of hostilities, the elections of 8 February were organized on a purely war or peace platform” (Taithe 2001, p. 178). The Third Republic established in September 1870 lasted until 1940, when France's defeat by Nazi Germany in World War II led to the formation of the Vichy government.

  8. It should be remembered that the expression ‘welfare state’ does not exist in French. Its French translation is ‘Etat providence’, a controversial term, referring to the provision of social protection by a central state that acts as divine intervenor.

  9. In fact, Thomas Marshall (1965, p. 82) claimed that “the experience of total war is … bound to have an effect on both the principles of social policy and the methods of social administration. But the nature of this effect will depend to a considerable extent on the fortunes of war—on whether a country is invaded or not, on whether it is victorious or defeated, and on the amount of physical destruction and social disorganization it suffers.”

  10. See Boris (1963) for understanding the influence of the Beveridge plan on the French resistance in exile.

  11. Bloody week refers to the week during which the Republic crushed the Paris Commune in March 1871.

  12. For data on the evolution of the state’s expenditure in France, see also André and Delorme (1983) and Fontvieille (1976).

  13. For example, the Lemire Law (June 21, 1907) reduced the marriage age to 21 without parental consent and defrayed marriage legal costs.

  14. See Viet (2016a) for the case of tuberculosis.

  15. In the French administrative system, local authorities or administrations include communes and counties.

  16. The tax was adopted in 1914 and was first levied in 1915.

  17. See the next section for an elaboration of the re-appropriation effect through state control of citizen welfare.

  18. We intentionally cite an old reference from the early 1950s to show that in the aftermath of the war everyone was convinced that the state as well as the business, financial and bureaucratic elites were discredited because of their collaboration. The same point also has been underlined in Wieviorka (2013) more recently.

  19. In April 1946, the CGT claimed 5.5 million members (Lorwin 1952, p. 526).

  20. Social security was not an outcome of nationalization. The post-war nationalization program was a response to the wartime collaborationist attitude of many private employers. The state took control of certain companies whose owners were so discredited (Kuisel 1981). This initiative was in line with the establishment of ‘économie dirigée’ (planned economy) as a prolongation of war socialism. The problem of social security was entirely different, since workers and trade unions such as CGT had not been tainted by collaboration. Interestingly, “the CGT withdrew from the planning apparatus in 1947.… Similarly, unions lost control of the government boards of the nationalized firms in the 1950s” (Kuisel 1981, p. 259).

  21. Ordonnances” in French.

  22. Alain Juppé was the French prime minister in 1996.

  23. The ministry was in charge of managing the social security.

  24. This is an image constantly referred to in the French media pertaining to the social security deficit.

  25. In French, CSG stands for contribution sociale géneralisée (Generalized Social Contribution).

  26. The equivalent of NICE (National Institute for Health and Care Excellence) in the United Kingdom. The HAS dispenses reliable information about quality-certification and accreditation criteria. It draws up lists of drugs of low actual clinical benefit that are subject to de-reimbursement.

References

  • Aghion, P., Persson, T., & Rouzet, D. (2012). Education and military rivalry. Working paper 18049. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Alesina, A., & Reich, B. (2013). Nation building. Working paper 18839. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Alesina, A., & Reich, B., & Riboni, A. (2017). Nation-building, nationalism and wars. Working paper 18839. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • André, C., & Delorme, R. (1991). Deux siècles de finances publiques: de l’Etat circonscrit à l’Etat inséré (pp. 51–64). Hors-série: Revue d’économie financière.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreassen, B. A. (1992). Article 22. In A. Eide, et al. (Eds.), The universal declaration of human rights—A commentary. Oslo: Oslo University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, P. (1990). The politics of social solidarity. Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barbier, J.-C. (2013). The road to social Europe, A contemporary approach to political cultures and diversity in Europe. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Batifoulier, P., Da Silva, N., & Duchesne, V. (2019). The dynamics of critique: the case of the French Social Security System. Historical Social Research/Historische Sozialforschung, GESIS – Leibniz-Institut für Sozialwissenschaften 44(1), 258–284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becchia, A. (1986). Les milieux parlementaires et la dépopulation de 1900 à 1914. Communication,44, 201–246.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S., & Mulligan, C. B. (2003). Deadweight costs and the size of government. Journal of Law and Economics,46(2), 293–340.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beito, D. (2000). From mutual aid to the welfare state, fraternal societies and social services, 1890–1967. London: The University of North Carolina Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bette, P. (2016). Des œuvres de guerre aux offices nationaux: l’évolution de la prise en charge des veuves de guerre (France, 1914–1924). Comité d’histoire de la sécurité sociale,9(1), 68–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonoli, G., & Palier, B. (2007). When past reforms open new opportunities: Comparing old-age insurance reforms in Bismarckian welfare systems. Social Policy & Administration,41(6), 555–573.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boris, G. (1963). Servir la République: Textes et témoignages. Présentation de Pierre Mendès France. Paris: R. Julliard Évreux.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (1980). The power to tax: Analytical foundations of a fiscal constitution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Lomasky, L. (1993). Democracy and decision: The pure theory of electoral preference. Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Briggs, A. (1961). The welfare state in historical perspective. European Journal of Sociology,2(2), 221–258.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, M., & Seaton, S. (1984). Christmas truce: The western front December 1914. New York: Hippocrene Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Browning, E. K. (1975). Why the social insurance budget is too large in a democracy. Economic Inquiry,13(3), 373–388.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cahen, F. (2014). Le gouvernement des grosses en France (1920–1970). Comité d’histoire de la sécurité sociale,1(7), 34–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caprettini, B., Schmidt-Fischbach, F., & Voth, H. J. (2018). From welfare to warfare: New deal spending and patriotism during World War II. CEPR Discussion paper series, economic history, DP 12807, 22 March.

  • Castel, R. (1995). Les métamorphoses de la question sociale: une chronique du salariat. Paris: Fayard.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chaineaud, C. (2009). L’amélioration de la protection sociale des veuves dans l’entre-deux-guerres ou la veuve bénéficiaire directe des mesures législatives. Revue d’histoire de la protection sociale,1(2), 66–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clausewitz, C. (2006/1827). On war. Translated by Michael Howard and Peter Paret. New York: Oxford University Press, electronic resource.

  • CNR. (1944). Les jours heureux, http://museedelaresistanceenligne.org/media6651-Les-jours-heureux-par-le-CNR.

  • Congleton, R. D., Kim, Y., & Marsella A. (2019). Some evidence of the long-run stability of political processes in the United States: Post-sample forecasts and refinements of the Congleton–Shughart models of social security benefits, Department of Economics, West Virginia University (Manuscript).

  • Congleton, R. D., & Shughart, W. F., II. (1990). The growth of social security: Electoral push or political pull? Economic Inquiry,28(1), 109–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corwin, E. S. (1970). Total war and the constitution. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Da Silva, N. (2017). Le mythe du “trou de la Sécu” à l’aune des débats parlementaires de 1949. In C. Brunet, T. Darcillon, & G. Rieucau (Eds.), Economie sociale et économie politique. Regards croisés sur l’histoire et sur les enjeux contemporains. Louvain: Presses universitaires de Louvain.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Luca Barrusse, V. (2009). La revanche des familles nombreuses: les premiers jalons d’une politique familiale (1896–1939). Comité d’histoire de la sécurité sociale,2(1), 47–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Swaan, A. (1988). In care of the state: Health care, education, and welfare in Europe and the USA in the modern era. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Delorme, R., & André, C. (1983). L’Etat et l’Economie. Paris: Seuil.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. A., & Mirrlees, J. A. (1971). Optimal taxation and public production: I and II. American Economic Review,81, 261–278.

    Google Scholar 

  • Domin, J. P. (2008a). Une histoire économique de l’hôpital (XIXe-XXe siècles). Une analyse rétrospective du développement hospitalier. Paris: Comité d’histoire de la sécurité sociale.

  • Domin, J. P. (2018). Socialization of healthcare demand and development of the French health system (1890–1938). Business History. https://doi.org/10.1080/00076791.2018.1454433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dryzek, J., & Goodin, R. (1986). Risk-sharing and social justice: The motivational foundations of the post-war welfare state. British Journal of Political Science,16(1), 1–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duchesne, V. (2018). L’agence, le contrat, l’incitation. Les Agences régionales de santé fer-de-lance administratif de la politique de santé. Journal de gestion et d’économie médicale,36(4), 159–180.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eisner, M. A. (2000). From warfare state to welfare state: World War I, compensatory state-building, and the limits of the modern order. Pennsylvania: The Pennsylvania State University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Falls, C. (1941). The nature of modern warfare. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fontvieille, L. (1976). Évolution et croissance de l’État français de 1815 à 1969. Économies et sociétés série AF,13, 1655–2144.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friot, B. (2012). Puissances du salariat. Paris: La Dispute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gal, J. (2007). The puzzling warfare-welfare Nexus. War & Society,26, 99–118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galbraith, J. (2009). The predator state. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guillaume, M. (1994). La sécurité sociale. Son histoire à travers les textes. Tome 1—1780–1870. Paris: Comité d’histoire de la sécurité sociale.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gustiaux, R. (2016). L’empreinte de la grande guerre sur le logement social en France (1912–1928). Comité d’histoire de la sécurité sociale,9(1), 88–109.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hatzfeld, H. (1971). Du paupérisme à la sécurité sociale (1850–1945). Paris: Armand Colin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herce, J., Sasvilla-Rivero, S., & De Lucis, J. (2001). Growth and the welfare state in the European Union: A causality analysis. Public Choice,109(1/2), 55–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Higgs, R. (1987). Crisis and leviathan: Critical episodes in the growth of American Government. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Higgs, R. (1991). Eighteen problematic propositions in the analysis of the growth of government. Review of Austrian Economics,5(1), 3–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (1989). The median voter model in public choice theory. Public Choice,61(2), 115–125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (1993). Are there ratchets in the growth of federal government spending? Public Finance Quarterly,21(1), 33–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (1996). The growth of the federal government in the 1920s. Cato Journal,16(2), 175–199.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (2002). From liberty to democracy: The transformation of American Government. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (2005). Government growth in the twenty-first century. Public Choice,124(1/2), 95–114.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. (2019). Progressive democracy: The ideology of the modern predatory state. Public Choice. https://link.springer.com/article/10.1007/s11127-019-00637-z. January.

  • Holcombe, R. G., & Mills, J. A. (1995). Politics and deficit finance. Public Finance Quarterly,23(4), 448–466.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horne, J. (1989). “L’impôt du sang”. Republican Rhetoric and Industrial Warfare in France 1914–1918. Social History,14(2), 201–223.

    Google Scholar 

  • Imbert, J. (1947). Les hôpitaux en droit canonique. Paris: Vrin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Imbert, J. (1988). Les hôpitaux en France. Paris: PUF.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaunait, A. (2005). Comment pense l’institution médicale? Une analyse des codes français de déontologie médicale. Paris: Dalloz.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jay, W. (1986). The great war and the British people. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jay, W., & Robert, J.-L. (2007). Capital cities at war: Paris, London, Berlin 1914–1919. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, N., & Koyama, M. (2017). States and economic growth: Capacity and constraints. Explorations in Economic History,64, 1–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • JORF. (1949). n°74 A.N. Débats parlementaires. 11 juillet.

  • JORF. (1967). n°85 A. N. Compte-rendu intégral des débats. 26 octobre.

  • Kerr, C., Harbison, F., Dunlop, J. T., & Myers, C. A. (1960). Industrialism and industrial man. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuisel, R. (1981). Capitalism and the state in modern France. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lacroix-Riz, A. (2007). Industriels et banquiers français sous l’Occupation: la collaboration économique avec le Reich et Vichy. Paris: Armand Colin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lacroix-Riz, A. (2009). Le choix de la défaite: les élites françaises dans les années 1930. Paris: Armand Colin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lanthier, M. (2003). War widows and the expansion of the French welfare state. In Proceedings western society for French history. University Press of Colorado.

  • Leeson, P. (2012). Ordeals. Journal of Law and Economics,55(3), 691–714.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeson, P. (2013). “God Damn”: The law and economics of monastic malediction. Journal of Law Economics and Organization,30(1), 193–216.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lorwin, V. R. (1952). French trade unions since liberation, 1944–1951. Industrial and Labor Relations Review,5(4), 524–539.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lott, J. R., & Kenny, L. W. (1999). Did women’s suffrage change the size and scope of government? Journal of Political Economy,107(6/1), 1163–1198.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ly, P. E. (2007). The charitable activities of terrorist organizations. Public Choice,131(1/2), 177–195.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mann, K. (2009). Remembering and rethinking the social divisions of welfare: 50 years on. Journal of Social Policy,38(1), 1–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, T. (1965). Class, citizen and social development. New York: Anchor Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy,89(5), 914–927.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mirrlees, J. A. (1971). An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation. Review of Economic Studies,38(2), 175–208.

    Google Scholar 

  • Monneraud, L. (2009). The dominant economic(s) prism in health reforms: From economic constraint to economic paradigm. Central European Journal of Public Policy,3(2), 22–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (1989). Public choice II. Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nay, O., Béjean, S., Benamouzig, D., Bergeron, H., Castel, P., & Ventelou, B. (2016). Achieving universal health coverage in France: Policy reforms and the challenge of inequalities. Lancet,387, 2236–2249.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago: Aldine-Atherton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nord, P. (2016). Le new deal Français. Paris: Perrin.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York: W.W. Norton and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Obinger, H., & Petersen, K. (2015). Mass welfare and the welfare state, causal mechanisms and effects. British Journal of Political Science,47, 203–227.

    Google Scholar 

  • Offer, J. (1999). Idealist thought, social policy and the rediscovery of informal care. British Journal of Sociology,50(3), 467–488.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M., Jr. (1982). The rise and decline of nations. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Overbye, E. (1995). Explaining welfare spending. Public Choice,83(3/4), 313–335.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palier, B. (2010). The dualizations of the French welfare system. In B. Palier (Ed.), A long goodbye to bismarck (Vol. 3). Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pauwels, J. (2016). 1914–1918: La Grande guerre des classes. Paris: Delga.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paxton, R. (1972). Vichy France: old guard and new order, 1940–1944. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peacock, A. T., & Wiseman, J. (1961). The growth of government expenditures in the United Kingdom. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1980). The growth of government. Journal of Law and Economics,23(2), 209–287.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pick, D. (1993). War machine: The rationalization of slaughter in the modern age. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T. (2018). Top incomes in France in the twentieth century: Inequality and redistribution, 1901–1998. Harvard: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter, B. D. (1994). War and the rise of the state: The military foundations of modern politics. New York: The Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rasmussen, A. (2008). A corps défendant: vacciner les troupes contre la typhoïde pendant la grande guerre. Corps,2(5), 41–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rasmussen, A. (2016a). Introduction. Protéger la société de la guerre: de l’assistance aux ‘droits sur la nation’. Revue d’histoire de la protection sociale,9(1), 9–24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rasmussen, A. (2016b). Expérimenter la santé des grands nombres: les hygiénistes militaires et l’armée française, 1850–1914. Le mouvement social,257(4), 71–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rassler, K. A., & Thompson, W. R. (1985). War making and state making: Government expenditures, tax revenues, and global wars. American Political Science Review,79(2), 491–507.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rivière, A. (2016). De l’abandon au placement temporaire: la révolution de l’assistance à l’enfance (Paris, 1870–1920). Revue d’histoire de la protection sociale,1(9), 26–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1978). Political resource allocation, controlled agendas, and the status quo. Public Choice,33(4), 27–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sánchez-Pagés, S. (2009). Conflict as a part of the bargaining process. The Economic Journal,119, 1189–1207.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sauvy, A. (1965). Histoire économique et sociale de la France entre les deux guerres, Tome 1. Paris: Fayard.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinfield, A. (1978). Analyses in the social division of welfare. Journal of Social Policy,7, 129–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skocpol, T. (1992). Protecting soldiers and mothers. The origins of social policy in the US. Cambridge: The Belknap Press and Harvard University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, T. (2003). Creating the welfare state in France, 1880–1940. London: McGill-Queen’s University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • The Economist. (2018). Reforming the welfare state, back to basic liberalism. July 14th–20th (pp. 12–13).

  • Taithe, B. (1999). Defeated flesh, medicine, welfare, and warfare in the making of modern France. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taithe, B. (2001). Citizenship and wars, France in turmoil 1870–1871. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilly, C. (1985). War making and state making as organized crime. In P. Evans, D. Rueschemeyer, & T. Skocpol (Eds.), Bringing the state back in (pp. 169–191). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Toynbee, A. J. (1950). War and civilization. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Titmuss, R. M. (1958). Essays on the welfare state. London: George Allen and Unwin LTD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1983). Economics of income redistribution. Boston: Kluwer Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Usher, D. (1992). The welfare economics of markets, voting, and predation. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2004). The political economy of destructive power. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2016a). The political economy of predation: Manhunting and the economics of escape. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vahabi, M. (2016b). A positive theory of the predatory state. Public Choice,168(3–4), 153–175.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viet, V. (2016). La grande guerre et la lutte antituberculeuse en France. Revue d’histoire de la protection sociale,1(9), 52–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1922/1968). Economy and society: An outline of interpretive sociology (Vol. 1). New York, NY: Benminster Press.

  • Wieviorka, O. (2013). Histoire de la résistance, 1940–1945. Paris: Perrin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilensky, H. (1975). The welfare state and equality. Berkeley: University of California.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilensky, H., & Lebeaux, C. (1965). Industrial society and social welfare. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We wholeheartedly thank our two anonymous referees, the associate editor Peter Leeson, and the editor in chief, William Shughart II of the Public Choice journal, for their excellent and constructive comments. We would also like to present our gratitude to Bernard Chavance, Bertrand Crettez, Jean-Paul Domin, Victor Duchesne, Sylvie Lupton, and Mandana Vahabi, for their inspiring and insightful remarks on earlier versions of this paper. Obviously, all the remaining errors are ours.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mehrdad Vahabi.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Vahabi, M., Batifoulier, P. & Da Silva, N. A theory of predatory welfare state and citizen welfare: the French case. Public Choice 182, 243–271 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00660-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00660-0

Keywords

Navigation