Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Youth bulges, insurrections and labor-market restrictions

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyzes the link between large youth cohorts and violent conflicts when labor-market restrictions are present. Such restrictions are expected to limit the youth cohort’s access to income opportunities in the formal economy, and thus lower the youth-specific opportunity cost of insurrection activities. We develop a theoretical model of insurrection markets and integrate the youth cohort’s relative size. In equilibrium, a binding labor-market constraint interacts with the youth bulge in determining the level of insurrection activities within the society. We test the implications of our model on a sample of 135 non-OECD countries in the post-Cold War period and find the effect of the youth cohort’s relative size on conflict onsets to be moderated by changes in the labor-market conditions as measured by unemployment rates. Generally, the results provide evidence that the underlying institutional setting shapes the conflict potential inherent in a given demographic structure.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. These effects already have been mentioned by Goldstone (1991, p. 139): “If real wages are above average, then ...a youthful population can be stabilizing. However, if there is a precipitous drop in real wages, then ...the youthfulness of the population can increase the mobilization potential of the population”.

  2. There is by now a vast amount of literature following Acemoglu and Robinson (2000, 2001, 2006) that is based on the notion of collectively sustained revolution constraints (see, e.g., Dorsch and Maarek 2015; Cervellati et al. 2014). However, this literature suffers from a number of drawbacks. In general, the literature on revolutions suppresses the micro-structure of collective action, so that it provides an ex-post rationalization rather than a causal explanation of insurrection activities (Apolte 2012).

  3. Acemoglu (2006) and Dorsch and Maarek (2015) consider the scope of tax instruments and deadweight-losses from such intervention into the economy. Since they are not critical for the point raised in this paper, we abstract from these losses.

  4. A detailed formal analysis of the following is provided in the “Appendix”.

  5. See the “Appendix” for the formal details.

  6. We rule out possible situations with no labor-market restriction and, at the same time, utility from insurrection activities is less than the net effective wage rate even with full employment, so that insurrection activities are never worthwhile.

  7. See the “Appendix” for the formal details.

  8. In the following, we use the terms “insurrection” and “conflict” interchangeably as our (empirical) conflict measure closely resembles what we modeled as “insurrections” in the theoretical section.

  9. We refrain from relating the youth cohort size to the total population as such a measure might seriously underestimate the extent of a youth bulge in the presence of continued high fertility rates (Urdal 2004, 2006).

  10. Technically, we use the size of the cohort of the 0-to-9-year-old males at time t-15 [which becomes the youth cohort (aged 15–24) in t]. In the denominator, we include the size of the population aged zero to 54 in t-15 [which becomes the total working population (aged 15–69) in t].

  11. Similar approaches are applied in studies of the relationship between youth cohorts and labor-market outcomes (Korenman and Neumark 1997) and in the literature on demography and economic growth (see, for example, Bloom and Williamson 1998).

  12. See Angrist and Krueger (1999) for a technical discussion of this condition.

  13. We provide an online appendix that contains additional information on the definitions and sources of all variables included in our analysis.

  14. One concern with the included controls is that they might be endogenous to insurrections and tend to be correlated with each other (Burke et al. 2014). Therefore, we treat these controls with caution and also present results without them. Nevertheless, our results do not depend on the chosen number and definition of the control variables. Additional regression results are available from the authors.

  15. For a country with RYCS (at birth) at the sample mean (= 0.149), the standardized value of this variable is zero. Thus, the overall effect of a one-unit increase in UE (= unemployment changes) at RYCS (at birth) = 0.149 is simply \(\hat{\gamma _2}\). For a country with RYCS (at birth) = 0.177, the standardized value is 0.848. The overall effect of a one-unit increase in UE at RYCS (at birth) = 0.177 is therefore \(\hat{\gamma _2} + \hat{\gamma _3}*0.848\). The differential effect of a one-unit increase in UE is the difference in both effects, or \(\hat{\gamma _3}*0.848 = 0.00727*0.848 = 0.00616\) (i.e., 0.616 percentage points).

  16. One could question the extent to which the absence of regulatory constraints actually reflects functioning labor markets. While this might be true for many (though not all) developed countries, in less developed countries the absence of labor regulations could simply reflect the failure of the state to establish a regulatory framework needed for functioning markets in the first place. That is one more reason why we refrain from using these indices as our main labor-market indicators.

  17. Since the indicator variable does not vary over time and the relative youth cohort size exhibits only little within-country variation, we refrain from including country fixed effects in our model, but instead enter regional and region-year fixed effects.

  18. In models (3)–(6) of Table 3, we separately include dummy variables for the political system, levels of education and resource rents. For ease of exposition, we summarize the coefficients on the main effects of these variables in one line, and we do the same for the interaction with RYCS (at birth) and the three-way interaction effect, using as a placeholder the term “indicator variable”.

  19. The results are qualitatively similar if we use the PolityIV definition and define as democratic all country-years with a Polity2 score of more than five.

  20. The partial effects of an increase in RYCS for a given value of UE in autocracies versus democracies are computed as follows. In autocracies (i.e., when democracy = 0), the effect of RYCS is given by \(0.0647 + 0.0224\times \overline{UE}\). When democracy = 1, the effect of RYCS is \(0.0647 - 0.0660 + (0.0224 - 0.0213)\times \overline{UE} = -\,0.0013 + 0.0011\times \overline{UE}\), which clearly is smaller than the effect in autocracies for any \(\overline{UE}>0\).

  21. The construction of the binary variables is similar to the institutional indicators in column (1) and (2) of Table 3. The only difference is that we do not construct time-invariant country averages, but use the annual observations to capture expansions in education over time. We use total years of schooling as well as years of tertiary schooling from the dataset of Barro and Lee (2013). To control for endogeneity concerns and since the data are available only for 5-year periods, we lag the variable by 5 years following Campante and Chor (2012).

  22. Excluding all observations of ongoing conflicts produces a somewhat artificial correlation between current and lagged values of the dependent variable. Therefore, in the dynamic specifications, the dependent variable is coded one for all conflict onsets, while country-years of ongoing conflicts are coded zero, following the coding procedure of Fearon and Laitin (2003). We call this variable “any conflict onset”. In the online appendix, we provide a list of included cases for all conflict definitions.

  23. We employ the first-difference GMM estimator instead of the system GMM estimator because it involves fewer internal instruments. As instruments, we use lagged levels of the dependent variable, unemployment (changes) and their interaction with the youth bulge, assuming exogeneity for RYCS (at birth). The results do not change when entering internal instruments for this variable as well.

  24. In the online appendix we provide additional robustness tests to our baseline model. In particular, we show that our results are robust to alternative definitions of the dependent variable and the youth cohort, as well as to different time structures and to the inclusion of additional demographic controls.

References

  • Acemoglu, D. (2006). A simple model of inefficient institutions. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 108(4), 515–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2000). Democratization or repression? European Economic Review, 44(4), 683–693.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). A theory of political transitions. American Economic Review, 91(4), 938–963.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2006). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ai, C., & Norton, E. C. (2003). Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Economics Letters, 80(1), 123–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angrist, J. D., & Krueger, A. B. (1999). Empirical strategies in labor economics. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics (Vol. 3, pp. 1277–1366). Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.

  • Angrist, J. D., & Pischke, J.-S. (2008). Mostly harmless econometrics: An empiricist’s companion. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Apolte, T. (2012). Why is there no revolution in North Korea? Public Choice, 150(3–4), 561–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austin, L. (2011). The politics of youth bulge: From Islamic activists to democratic reform in the Middle East and North Africa. SAIS Review of International Affairs, 31(2), 81–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banks, A. S., & Wilson, K. A. (2015). Cross-national time-series data archive. Jerusalem: Databanks International. Online database, available from http://www.cntsdata.com/. Accessed 18 Nov 2015.

  • Barakat, B. & Urdal, H. (2009). Breaking the waves? Does education mediate the relationship between youth bulges and political violence? World Bank Policy. Research Working Paper No. 5114. Online available from https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/4304.

  • Barro, R., & Lee, J.-W. (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010. Journal of Development Economics, 104, 184–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bazzi, S., & Blattman, C. (2014). Economic shocks and conflict: Evidence from commodity prices. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 6(4), 1–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berman, E., Callen, M., Felter, J. H., & Shapiro, J. N. (2011). Do working men rebel? Insurgency and unemployment in Afghanistan, Iraq, and the Philippines. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 55(4), 496–528.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhuller, M., Mogstad, M., & Salvanes, K. G. (2014). Life cycle earnings, education premiums and internal rates of return. NBER Working Paper 20250. Online available from http://www.nber.org/papers/w20250. Accessed 22 May 2016.

  • Blattman, C., & Miguel, E. (2010). Civil war. Journal of Economic Literature, 48(1), 3–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, D. E., & Williamson, J. G. (1998). Demographic transitions and economic miracles in emerging Asia. The World Bank Economic Review, 12(3), 419–455.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boix, C., & Svolik, M. W. (2013). The foundation of limited authoritarian government: Institutions, commitment, and power-sharing in dictatorships. The Journal of Politics, 75(2), 300–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruno, G. S. F. (2005). Approximating the bias of the LSDV estimator for dynamic unbalanced panel data models. Economics Letters, 87(3), 361–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burke, M., Hsiang, S. M., & Miguel, E. (2014). Climate and conflict. NBER Working Paper 20598. Online available from http://www.nber.org/papers/w20598. Accessed 7 July 2015.

  • Caldwell, C. (2007). Youth and war, a deadly duo. The Financial Times, January 6.

  • Campante, F. R., & Chor, D. (2012). Why was the Arab world poised for revolution? Schooling, economic opportunities, and the Arab spring. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26, 167–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carter, D. B., & Signorino, C. S. (2010). Back to the future: Modeling time dependence in binary data. Political Analysis, 18(3), 271–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cervellati, M., Fortunato, P., & Sunde, U. (2014). Violence during democratization and the quality of democratic institutions. European Economic Review, 66, 226–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheibub, J. A., Gandhi, J., & Vreeland, J. R. (2010). Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice, 143(1–2), 67–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P., & Hoeffler, A. (2004). Greed and grievance in civil war. Oxford Economic Papers, 56(4), 563–595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collier, P., Hoeffler, A., & Rohner, D. (2009). Beyond greed and grievance: Feasibility and civil war. Oxford Economic Papers, 61(1), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Defoe, I. N., Dubas, J. S., Figner, B., & van Aken, M. A. G. (2015). A meta-analysis on age differences in risky decision making: Adolescents versus children and adults. Psychological Bulletin, 141(1), 48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dorsch, M. T., & Maarek, P. (2015). Inefficient predation and political transitions. European Journal of Political Economy, 37, 37–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A., Minasyan, A., & Nunnenkamp, P. (2015). Government ideology in donor and recipient countries: Does ideological proximity matter for the effectiveness of aid? European Economic Review, 79, 80–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A. (1987). Birth and fortune: The impact of numbers on personal welfare. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fearon, J. D., & Laitin, D. D. (2003). Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war. American Political Science Review, 97(1), 75–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuller, G. E. (1995). The demographic backdrop to ethnic conflict: A geographic overview. In C. I. Unit (Ed.), The challenge of ethnic conflict to national and international order in the 1990s (pp. 151–154). Washington, DC: CIA.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuller, G. E. (2003). The youth factor: The new demographics of the Middle East and the implications for US Policy. Washington: Saban Center for Middle East Policy at the Brookings Institution.

    Google Scholar 

  • Furnham, A. (2015). Young people’s understanding of society. Abingdon: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gates, S. (2002). Recruitment and allegiance: The microfoundations of rebellion. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(1), 111–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gleditsch, N. P., Wallensteen, P., Eriksson, M., Sollenberg, M., & Strand, H. (2002). Armed conflict 1946–2001: A new dataset. Journal of Peace Research, 39(5), 615–637.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goemans, H. E., Gleditsch, K. S., & Chiozza, G. (2009). Introducing Archigos: A dataset of political leaders. Journal of Peace Research, 46(2), 269–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (1991). Revolution and rebellion in the early modern world. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2002). Population and security: How demographic change can lead to violent conflict. Journal of International Affairs, 56(1), 3–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, H. I. (1991). A general equilibrium model of insurrections. The American Economic Review, 81, 912–921.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, H. I. (1999). Kleptocracy and revolutions. Oxford Economic Papers, 51(2), 267–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gwartney, J., Lawson, R., & Hall, J. (2016). Economic freedom of the world: 2016 annual report. Vancouver: The Fraser Institute. Online available from https://www.fraserinstitute.org/studies/economic-freedom. Accessed 16 Nov 2016.

  • Heinsohn, G. (2007). Why Gaza is fertile ground for angry young men. Financial Times, June 14.

  • Heinsohn, G. (2009). Afghanistan’s disposable sons. The Wall Street Journal, September 17.

  • Heritage Foundation. (2016). Index of economic freedom. Washington D.C.: The Heritage Foundation. Online database, available from http://www.heritage.org/index/explore. Accessed 6 May 2017.

  • Heston, A., Summers, R., & Aten, B. (2012). Penn World Table version 7.1. Center for international comparisons of production, income and prices at the University of Pennsylvania. Online database, available from https://www.rug.nl/ggdc/productivity/pwt/pwt-releases/pwt-7.1. Accessed 19 Feb 2018.

  • Hillman, A. L. (2010). Expressive behavior in economics and politics. European Journal of Political Economy, 26(4), 403–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kiviet, J. F. (1995). On bias, inconsistency, and efficiency of various estimators in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 53–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korenman, S. & Neumark, D. (1997). Cohort crowding and youth labor market: A cross-national analysis. NBER Working Paper 6031. Online available from http://www.nber.org/papers/w6031. Accessed 22 April 2014.

  • Krieger, T., & Meierrieks, D. (2011). What causes terrorism? Public Choice, 147(1–2), 3–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A. B. (2008). What makes a terrorist: Economics and the roots of terrorism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kuran, T. (1989). Sparks and prairie fires: A theory of unanticipated political revolution. Public Choice, 61(1), 41–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2003). The paradox of rebellion (pp. 728–731). Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lichbach, M. I. (1995). The Rebel’s dilemma. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, M. G., Gurr, T. R., & Jaggers, K. (2016). Polity IV project: Political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2016, dataset users’ manual. Vienna: Center for Systemic Peace. Online available from http://www.systemicpeace.org/inscr/p4manualv2016.pdf. Accessed 10 May 2017.

  • McGrath, L. F. (2015). Estimating onsets of binary events in panel data. Political Analysis, 23(4), 534–549.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mesquida, C. G., & Wiener, N. I. (1999). Male age composition and severity of conflicts. Politics and the Life Sciences, 18(2), 181–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moller, H. (1968). Youth as a force in the modern world. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 10(03), 237–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niang, S. R. (2010). Terrorizing ages: The effects of youth densities and the relative youth cohort size in the likelihood and pervasiveness of terrorism. Paper presented at the annual meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, April 2010, Chicago.

  • Nickell, S. (1981). Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 49(6), 1417–1426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nizalova, O. Y., & Murtazashvili, I. (2016). Exogenous treatment and endogenous factors: Vanishing of omitted variable bias on the interaction term. Journal of Econometric Methods, 5(1), 71–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordås, R., & Davenport, C. (2013). Fight the youth: Youth bulges and state repression. American Journal of Political Science, 57(4), 926–940.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nunn, N., & Qian, N. (2014). US food aid and civil conflict. The American Economic Review, 104(6), 1630–1666.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965/1971). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

  • Pharo, H., Sim, C., Graham, M., Gross, J., & Hayne, H. (2011). Risky business: Executive function, personality, and reckless behavior during adolescence and emerging adulthood. Behavioral Neuroscience, 125(6), 970.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sageman, M. (2004). Understanding terror networks. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1958). An exact consumption-loan model of interest with or without the social contrivance of money. The Journal of Political Economy, 66, 467–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schomaker, R. (2013). Youth bulges, poor institutional quality and missing migration opportunities—Triggers of and potential counter-measures for terrorism in MENA. Topics in Middle Eastern and North African Economies, 15(1), 116–140.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shadmehr, M., & Haschke, P. (2016). Youth, revolution, and repression. Economic Inquiry, 54(2), 778–793.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephan, M. J., & Chenoweth, E. (2008). Why civil resistance works: The strategic logic of nonviolent conflict. International Security, 33(1), 7–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Themnér, L., & Wallensteen, P. (2013). Armed conflicts, 1946–2012. Journal of Peace Research, 50(4), 509–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1971). The paradox of revolution. Public Choice, 11(1), 89–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1974). The social dilemma: The economics of war and revolution. Blacksburg: University Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division. (2015). World population prospects: The 2015 revision, methodology of the United Nations population estimates and projections. Online available from https://esa.un.org/unpd/wpp/publications/Files/WPP2015_Methodology.pdf. Accessed 11 Oct 2016.

  • Urdal, H. (2004). The devil in the demographics: The effect of youth bulges on domestic armed conflict, 1950–2000. World Bank Social Development Papers No. 14. Online available from http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/794881468762939913/The-devil-in-the-demographics-the-effect-of-youth-bulges-on-domestic-armed-conflict-1950-2000. Accessed 25 Nov 2013.

  • Urdal, H. (2006). A clash of generations? Youth bulges and political violence. International Studies Quarterly, 50(3), 607–629.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wall, E. (2006). The terrorism labor market. Economics Department Honors Thesis, Economics, Holy Cross University Worcester, MA.

  • Whelton, C. (2007). A demographic theory of war: Population, power, and the slightly weird ideas of Gunnar Heinsohn. Weekly Standard, 6. Online available from http://www.weeklystandard.com/a-demographic-theory-of-war/article/15288. Accessed 19 Feb 2018.

  • Wintrobe, R. (2006). Extremism, suicide terror, and authoritarianism. Public Choice, 128(1–2), 169–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2016). World development indicators. Washington, DC: The World Bank Group. Online database, available from http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators. Accessed 19 May 2016.

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Roger Congleton and Randall Holcombe for helpful discussions at the 2016 Meeting of the Public Choice Society, as well as to the anonymous referees and the editor in charge of our submission, William Shughart II, for unusually constructive comments. We also thank Rahel Schomaker and Dirk Wentzel for insightful discussions at early stages of the project. Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the 2016 Meeting of the European Public Choice Society and the 2015 Meeting of the German Economic Association.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas Apolte.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

11127_2018_514_MOESM1_ESM.pdf

An online appendix of additional empirical results is available from the corresponding author's website (www.wiwi.uni-muenster.de/loep/en/people/thomas-apolte). (PDF 223 kb)

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 The revolutionary elite’s maximization problem

Considering Eq. (4) in combination with Eq. (2), the maximization problem of the revolutionary elite is:

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathfrak {I}}=t^{R} \beta I- \rho \ w_{I}I+\lambda (\tau ^{R}Y-t^{R}). \end{aligned}$$

The Kuhn–Tucker conditions are then:

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathfrak {I}}_{I}= &\;t^{R}\beta - \rho \ w_{I}\leqslant 0; \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)
$$\begin{aligned} {\mathfrak {I}}_{t^{R}}= &\;\beta I-\lambda \leqslant 0; \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)
$$\begin{aligned} {\mathfrak {I}}_{\lambda }= &\;\tau ^{R}Y-t^{R}\geqslant 0; \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)
$$\begin{aligned} I,t^{R},\lambda\geqslant & 0; \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)
$$\begin{aligned} I{\mathfrak {I}}_{I}= &\;I(t^{R}\beta - \rho \ w_{I})=0; \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)
$$\begin{aligned} t^{R}{\mathfrak {I}}_{t^{R}}= &\;t^{R}(\beta I-\lambda )=0; \end{aligned}$$
(A.6)
$$\begin{aligned} \lambda {\mathfrak {I}}_{\lambda }= &\;\lambda (\tau ^{R}Y-t^{R})=0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.7)

1.2 The citizens’ maximization problem

The citizens maximize (6) subject to their time restriction \(l+i\le 1\) and subject to the labor-market restriction \(l\le \varepsilon\). The Lagrangian is as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathfrak {I}}=(1-t^{G}A^{G})w_{L}l+\rho ((1+w_{I})^{r\mu }-1)i+\lambda _{1}(1-l-i)+\lambda _{2}(\varepsilon -l). \end{aligned}$$
(A.8)

The Kuhn–Tucker conditions of the citizens’ maximization problem are:

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathfrak {I}}_{l}= &\;(1-t^{G}A^{G})w_{L} - \lambda _{1} - \lambda _{2}\leqslant 0; \end{aligned}$$
(A.9)
$$\begin{aligned} {\mathfrak {I}}_{i}= &\;\rho ((1+w_{I})^{r\mu }-1)-\lambda _{1}\leqslant 0; \end{aligned}$$
(A.10)
$$\begin{aligned} {\mathfrak {I}}_{\lambda _{1}}= &\;1-l-i\geqslant 0; \end{aligned}$$
(A.11)
$$\begin{aligned} {\mathfrak {I}}_{\lambda _{2}}= &\;\varepsilon - l\geqslant 0; \end{aligned}$$
(A.12)
$$\begin{aligned} l> & 0;\quad i,\lambda _{1},\lambda _{2}\geqslant 0; \end{aligned}$$
(A.13)
$$\begin{aligned} l{\mathfrak {I}}_{l}= &\;l((1-t^{G}A^{G})w_{L} - \lambda _{1} - \lambda _{2})=0; \end{aligned}$$
(A.14)
$$\begin{aligned} i{\mathfrak {I}}_{i}= &\;i (\rho ((1+w_{I})^{r\mu }-1)-\lambda _{1})=0; \end{aligned}$$
(A.15)
$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _{1}{\mathfrak {I}}_{\lambda _{1}}= &\;\lambda _{1}(1-l-i)=0; \end{aligned}$$
(A.16)
$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _{2}{\mathfrak {I}}_{\lambda _{2}}= &\;\lambda _{2}(\varepsilon - l)=0;\,\,\, hence: \,\,\lambda _{2}{\mathfrak {I}}_{\lambda _{2}}=\lambda _{2}(\varepsilon N-N)=0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.17)

If both restrictions in (A.8) were non-binding, so that \(\lambda _{1}=\lambda _{2}=0\), then this would imply by Eq. (A.14) that either \(w_{L}=0\) or \(l=0\) since both are non-negative. Note, however, that \(l=0\) is ruled out by the Inada conditions for the production function, while \(w_{L}=0\) is ruled out by both the Inada conditions and by \(\delta r^{-1}>0\) in combination with the firm’s first-order maximization condition (7); this is at least true as long as the effective tax rate is not fully confiscatory, i.e., as long as \(t^{G}A^{G}<1\). A non-binding time restriction of the citizens (i.e., \(l+i<1\) and hence \(\lambda _{1}=0\)) is nevertheless possible, but that presupposes the labor-market imperfection to induce a binding constraint, so that \(\lambda _{2}>0\). Both restrictions being non-binding, however, is not possible as long as \(t^{G}A^{G}<1\).

Given \(\lambda _{2}>0\), however, a non-binding time constraint of the citizens remains possible, but this would, by Eq. (A.15), be associated with either \(i=0\), or with \(\rho ((1+w_{I})^{r \mu }-1)=0\), or both. The implication is this: Should \(\lambda _{2}>0\), so that the citizens are rationed in their labor-market supply, and should the marginal utility from insurrection activities \(\rho ((1+w_{I})^{r \mu }-1)\) be zero, then the citizens are unable to fully employ their disposable time for income generation: On the market for insurrection, they have no incentive for being active because of \(\rho ((1+w_{I})^{r \mu }-1)=0\); and on the labor market, they would want to be active to the full extent of their time devoted for income-generating activities, but they cannot do so because of the positive chance \(\varepsilon >0\) of being unemployed.

Finally, combinations of \(\lambda _{1}>0\) with \(\lambda _{2}=0\) or with \(\lambda _{2}>0\) are also possible. In the former case, the labor market clears, whereas in the latter case, all unemployed labor-market time will be supplied to the revolutionary elite.

1.3 Analyses of cases A and B

Case A: \(\lambda _{1}=0;\;\lambda _{2}>0.\)

From Eq. (A.14) and from \(\lambda _{1}=0\), we have \(l((1-t^{G} A^{G})w_{L}-\lambda _{2})=0\). Since the Inada conditions of the production function \(F(\delta r^{-1}L,A)\) rule out \(L=lN=0\), we have \((1-t^{G} A^{G})w_{L}=\lambda _{2}>0\). The non-negativity of \(\rho ((1+w_{I})^{r\mu }-1)\) in combination with Eq. (A.10) implies \(\rho ((1+w_{I})^{r\mu }-1)=0\) because of \(\lambda _{1}=0\). Substituting the compensation rates \(w_{L}\) and \(w_{I}\) by the marginal productivities from (7) and (8), and considering the labor-market restriction in (A.17) as well as the assumption of case A that \(\lambda _{2}>0\), the equilibrium in case A is:

$$\begin{aligned}&(1-t^{G} A^{G})\delta r^{-1}F'(L)-\lambda _{2}=\rho ((1+t^{R}\beta \rho ^{-1})^{r\mu }-1)=0; \nonumber \\&\quad {\text{and}} \,\, (1-t^{G} A^{G})\delta r^{-1}F'(L)=\lambda _{2}>0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.18)

Note that, because of \(\lambda _{2}>0\), employment L in equilibrium is lower than N and the wage rate in equilibrium \(w_{L}=\delta r^{-1}F'\) is higher than its market-clearing value. We define the latter as \(w_{L}^{e}=w_{L}(L=N)\).

Case B: \(\lambda _{1} >0; \;\lambda _{2} \geqslant 0.\)

Case B is characterized by:

$$\begin{aligned} (1-t^{G}A^{G})\delta r^{-1}F'(L)-\lambda _{2}=\rho ((1+t^{R}\beta \rho ^{-1})^{r\mu }-1) \end{aligned}$$
(A.19)

which, according to (A.15), is associated with \(i\ge 0\).

Fig. 5
figure 5

Unemployment rates against youth bulges in MENA countries. Note Scatter plot for 135 non-OECD countries. MENA countries are labeled by triangle markers and their country names, while all other countries are indicated by circular markers. The y-axis plots the unemployment rate in the total labor force, averaged over 1992–2012. The x-axis plots the relative youth cohort size [measured as the ratio of the male youth cohort (aged 15–24 years) relative to the economically active population (ages 15–69)], averaged over 1992–2012. The vertical and horizontal lines indicate the median values of the x- and y-axis variables

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Apolte, T., Gerling, L. Youth bulges, insurrections and labor-market restrictions. Public Choice 175, 63–93 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0514-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0514-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation