Skip to main content
Log in

Seniority and anti-competitive restrictions on the legislative common pool: tenure’s impact on the overall production of legislation and the concentration of political benefits

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

It is well established that geographic areas benefit, in terms of the share of government spending they capture, from having a legislator with longer tenure, holding constant the tenure of other legislators. However, the implications of this literature for how the total production of legislation changes if all members gained seniority is less clear. Increased levels and dispersion of seniority within Congress generate a cartel-like effect, whereby legislators restrict the quantity of legislation enacted and increase the average price of each passed bill. The analysis provides a natural experiment to gauge the impacts of the emergence of the congressional committee system.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Crain, W. M. (1977). On the structure and stability of political markets. Journal of Political Economy, 85, 829–842.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W. M. (1979). Cost and output in the legislative firm. The Journal of Legal Studies, 8, 607–621.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W. M., & Tollison, R. D. (1980). The sizes of majorities. Southern Economic Journal, 46, 726–734.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A. T., & Munger, M. C. (1986). Legislators and interest groups: how unorganized interests get represented. The American Political Science Review, 80, 89–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gini, C. (1912). Variabilita’e mutabilita’ studi economicogiuridici universita’ di’ cagliari. III, 2a, Bologna.

  • Holcombe, R. G. (1999). Veterans interests and the transition to government growth: 1870–1915. Public Choice, 99, 311–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G., & Parker, G. R. (1991). Committees in legislatures: a property rights perspective. Public Choice, 70, 11–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leibowitz, A., & Tollison, R. D. (1980). A theory of legislative organization: making the most of your majority. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94, 261–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S. D., & Poterba, J. M. (1999). Congressional distributive politics and state economic performance. Public Choice, 99, 185–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lorenz, M. (1905). Methods of measuring the concentration of wealth. Publications of ASA, 70, 209–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luce, R. (1935). Legislative problems: development, status, and trend of the treatment and exercise of lawmaking powers. Boston: Houghton-Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCormick, R. E., & Tollison, R. D. (1978). Legislatures as unions. Journal of Political Economy, 86, 63–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCormick, R. E., & Tollison, R. D. (1981). Politics, legislation, and the economy: an inquiry into the interest-group theory of government. Boston: Martinus Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moore, S., & Steelman, A. (1994). Term limits: an antidote to federal red ink? Briefing Paper #21. Cato Institute.

  • Nordhaus, W. D. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies, 42, 169–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker, G. R. (1992). The distribution of honoraria income in the U.S. Congress: who gets rents in legislatures and why? Public Choice, 73, 167–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Payne, J. L. (1990). The Congressional brainwashing machine. Public Interest, 100, 3–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Payne, J. L. (1991). The culture of spending: why Congress lives beyond our means. San Francisco: ICS Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1978). Political resource allocation, controlled agendas, and the status quo. Public Choice, 33, 27–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ryan, M.E. (2008). Legislative tenure, federal spending, and state economic performance: 1981–2004. Mimeo.

  • Ryan, M. E. (2009). The evolution of legislative tenure in the United States Congress: 1789–2004. Mimeo.

  • Shughart, W. F., & Tollison, R. D. (1985). Legislation and political business cycles. Kyklos, 38, 43–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shughart, W. F., & Tollison, R. D. (1986). On the growth of government and the political economy of legislation. In Richard O. Zerbe Jr. (Ed.), Research in law and economics (pp. 111–127). Greenwich: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1976). The sizes of legislatures. The Journal of Legal Studies, 5, 17–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R., & Marshall, W. J. (1988). The industrial organization of Congress; or, why legislatures, like firms, are not organized as markets. Journal of Political Economy, 96, 132–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R., Shepsle, K. A., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: a neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 642–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Russell S. Sobel.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Sobel, R.S., Ryan, M.E. Seniority and anti-competitive restrictions on the legislative common pool: tenure’s impact on the overall production of legislation and the concentration of political benefits. Public Choice 153, 171–190 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9780-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9780-4

Keywords

Navigation