Skip to main content
Log in

Parliamentary procedure: principal forms and political effects

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Legislative agendas depend on parliamentary procedure, of which there are two main versions and a noteworthy variant: Anglo-American, Euro-Latin, and Mex-Italian. Theorems proved here identify the output of each procedure under strategic and sincere voting. Surprises abound: Strategic voting makes Anglo-American procedure more restrictive than Euro-Latin, and either sort of voting makes Anglo-American procedure more conservative, or stabilizing. Although sincere voting makes Mex-Italian procedure equivalent to the similar-looking Euro-Latin, strategic voting makes it equivalent rather to Anglo-American. Also strategic voting reduces the effects of agenda manipulation only under Mex-Italian procedure. These findings raise new research questions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Alemán, E., & Schwartz, T. (2006). Presidential vetoes in Latin American constitutions. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 18, 98–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banks, J. S. (1985). Sophisticated voting outcomes and agenda control. Social Choice and Welfare, 1, 295–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. (1958). The theory of committees and elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (2005). Setting the agenda. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutta, B. (1988). Covering sets and a new Condorcet choice correspondence. Journal of Economic Theory, 44, 63–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farquharson, R. (1969). Theory of voting. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P. C. (1977). Condorcet social choice functions. SIAM Journal of Applied Mathematics, 33, 469–489.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammond, T., & Miller, G. (1987). The core of the Constitution. American Political Science Review, 81, 1155–1174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Linz, J. J. (1990). The perils of presidentialism. Journal of Democracy, 1, 51–69.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mainwaring, S. (1993). Presidentialism, multipartism and democracy: The difficult combination. Comparative Political Studies, 26, 198–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R. D., & Niemi, R. (1978). A multistage game representation of sophisticated voting for binary procedures. Journal of Economic Theory, 18, 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, N. R. (1980). A new solution set for tournaments and majority voting. American Journal of Political Science, 24, 69–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, N. R. (1995). Committees, agendas, and voting. Chur: Harwood Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Montesquieu, C.-L. (1977). In D. W. Carrithers (Ed.), The spirit of laws. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moulin, H. (1979). Dominance-solvable voting schemes. Econometrica, 47, 13347–13351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ordeshook, P., & Schwartz, T. (1987). Agendas and the control of political outcomes. American Political Science Review, 81, 179–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plott, C., & Levine, M. (1976). A model of agenda influence on committee decisions. American Economic Review, 68, 146–160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rasch, B. E. (2000). Parliamentary floor voting procedures and agenda setting in Europe. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 25, 3–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. H. (1958). The paradox of voting and congressional rules for voting on amendments. American Political Science Review, 52, 349–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W. H. (1982). Liberalism against populism. San Francisco: Freeman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rohde, D. W. (1991). Parties and leaders in the postreform house. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1978). Political resource allocation, controlled agendas, and the status quo. Public Choice, 33, 27–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. A., & Weingast, B. R. (1984). Uncovered sets and sophisticated voting outcomes with implications for agenda control. American Journal of Political Science, 28, 49–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, T. (1990). Cyclic tournaments and cooperative majority voting: A solution. Social Choice and Welfare, 7, 19–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, T. (2005). Vetoes overridable by simple majorities. Constitutional Political Economy, 15, 383–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sullivan, T. (1984). Procedural structure. New York: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas Schwartz.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Schwartz, T. Parliamentary procedure: principal forms and political effects. Public Choice 136, 353–377 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-008-9300-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-008-9300-3

Keywords

Navigation