Skip to main content
Log in

Leontief was not right after all

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We use recent international data on cost shares by industry to conduct the first robust test of Leontief’s hypothesis of factor-specific productivity differences. We strongly reject this hypothesis. Hence tests of the Heckscher–Ohlin–Vanek paradigm cannot be based upon simple modifications that define factors in efficiency units. We also discuss a theory of productivity differences that describes the factor content of trade well.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. These parameters depend upon Country c and Country 0, but that dependence is suppressed for notational convenience.

  2. Some data were available that might have undercut one’s belief in Leontief’s conjecture. Exploiting cross-country data on a wide sample of industries, Arrow et al. (1961) estimated elasticities of substitution that were typically quite different from unity. Since factor prices are not equalized, it could be inferred that an industry’s factor cost shares differed across countries. Also, scholars such as Rosefielde (1974) had long studied input-output matrices from other countries.

  3. See OECD (2015). The URL http://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/industry-and-services/data/stan-input-output/input-output-database_data-00650-en?isPartOf=/content/datacollection/stan-in-out-data-en was retrieved on 12 October 2015.

  4. Our definition has a slight drawback. Factor shares always sum to unity, but there are a few subsidized industries where payments to social capital are negative. The most striking case is “Motor Vehicles, Trailers, and Semi-trailers” in Indonesia. Capital’s share is 1.6, labor’s is 0.8, and social capital’s is \(-\)1.4. Some might consider it an advantage to identify rare cases of highly subsidized industries. These cases give the data fat tails.

  5. We drop “Steam and Hot Water Supply” since that industry is not active in the United States.

  6. See Everitt (1998, pp. 182–83) for a discussion of this distribution.

  7. The binomial distribution is discrete. Each marginal significance level is the two-sided probability of a more extreme value than that observed in the data.

  8. A standard graduate textbook (Feenstra 2004, p. 61) assigns an exercise that illustrates Gabaix’s algebra. It is unfortunate that Gabaix (1997) was never published and is not readily available. In essence, Gabaix shows that Trefler’s calculations are not identified. When the measured factor content of trade in labor services is zero, then Trefler (1993) computed either labor productivity parameters or GDP per capita.

  9. Trefler’s (1993) productivity parameters are the solution to an invertible system of linear equations. Its kernel has the property that each country’s factor-specific productivity is simply national income per unit of that factor. For example, the productivity parameters for labor are just output per worker, and those for capital are the inverses of the capital-output ratios. Since any invertible linear mapping is continuous, the imputed productivity parameters are quite near output per factor when the system’s image is in a neighborhood of zero.

  10. Let \(Y_c\) be the output of Country c. In steady state, investment is \(I_c = \delta K_c\) where the variables have their usual meanings. The data report \(\kappa _c = I_c/Y_c\), the share of investment in GDP. Hence \(Y_c/K_c = \delta /\kappa _c\), and the depreciation rate is common across all countries. Thus the productivity parameters for capital should be correlated with the inverses of the investment shares of GDP.

  11. Schott (2003) contends that the rubrics in these data are too broad. He argues that countries produce highly disaggregated goods in different diversification cones, depending upon their level of economic development. We must be agnostic about this claim, but we note that there are very few zeros in each country’s vector of imports and exports at this level of aggregation.

  12. Let \(Ax=b\) be a system of n equations in f unknowns x. Then the set of all solutions is \(x=A^+b+(I-A^+A) z,\) where z is an arbitrary \(f \times 1\) vector. If the rank of A is at least f, then \(I-A^+A=0\). In fact, the Moore–Penrose inverse gives a solution to an inconsistent system of equations \(Ax \approx b\), a fact that will be useful below.

  13. We are using the symmetry property of the Moore Penrose inverse: \((A^\prime )^+=(A^+)^\prime .\)

  14. Brecher and Choudhri (1982) give a nice diagrammatic exposition of an economy with more goods than factors.

  15. Again, for notational convenience, we will henceforth omit the dependence of \(\Theta _c(\cdot )\) on local factor prices.

  16. When a sector is not active, every element in that row is zero. Then the pseudo-inverse has a corresponding column that also has every element equal to zero.

  17. Thus the rates of tchnological progress lie in the column space of \(\Theta _0(w_0)\).

  18. Because unit input requirements minimize costs, the envelope theorem implies that \(\Theta _0(w_0)\) is unaffected for small changes \(\hat{w}_0\). Given fixed factor supplies, higher factor returns are equivalent to more productive factors.

  19. These data are presented in Table 1 of Fisher (2015). We have assumed here that the work year consists of 2000 h.

  20. We constructed the dollar values of endowments from those in local currencies in the OECD data using purchasing power parity exchange rates from the World Bank’s International Comparison Program.

  21. Note that \(\Theta _i^+\Theta _j \ne \Theta _j^+\Theta _i\), just as a regression of Y on X is different from a regression of X on Y. Also, \(\Theta _i^+\Theta _i = I_f\), so there are only 1056 such matrices in these data that are not trivial. Again, we will make all these data available to any interested researcher.

References

  • Arrow KJ, Chenery HB, Minhas BS, Solow RM (1961) Capital subsitution and economic efficiency. Rev Econ Stat 43:225–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brecher RA, Choudhri EU (1982) The factor content of international trade without factor-price equalization. J Int Econ 12:277–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis DR, Weinstein DE (2001) An account of global factor trade. Am Econ Rev 91:1423–1453

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Everitt BS (1998) The Cambridge dictionary of statistics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra RC (2004) Advanced international trade: theory and evidence. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra RC, Taylor AM (2012) Int Econ, 2nd edn. Worth Publishers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher EON (2011) Heckscher–Ohlin theory when countries have different technologies. Int Rev Econ Financ 20:202–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher EO’N (2015) Factor cost shares and local technologies. http://www.calpoly.edu/efisher/factorcostshares

  • Fisher EON, Marshall KG (2011) The structure of the American economy. Rev Int Econ 19:15–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher EO’N, Marshall KG (2015) Testing the Heckscher–Ohlin–Vanek paradigm in a world with cheap foreign labor. http://www.calpoly.edu/efisher/TestingtheHOV2015.pdf

  • Gabaix Xavier (1997) The Factor content of trade: a rejection of the Heckscher–Ohlin Leontief hypothesis. Unpublished manuscript, Harvard University

  • Heckscher EF (1919) Utrikeshandelns verkan på inkomstfördelningen. några teoretiska grundlinjer. Ekonomisk tidskrift 21:1–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones RW (2008) Heckscher–Ohlin trade flows: a re-appraisal. Trade Dev Rev 1:1–6

    Google Scholar 

  • Leontief W (1953) Domestic production and foreign trade: the American capital position re-examined. Proc Am Philos Soc 97:332–349

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall KG (2012) International productivity and factor price comparisons. J Int Econ 87:386–390

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2015) STAN input–output: input output database. STAN, OECD Structural Analysis Statistics (database)

  • Rosefielde S (1974) Factor proportions and economic rationality in soviet international trade 1955–1968. Am Econ Rev 64:670–681

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson PA (1953) Prices of factors and goods in general equilibrium. Rev Econ Stud 21:1–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schott PK (2003) One size fits all? Heckscher–Ohlin specialization in global production. Am Econ Rev 93:686–708

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1957) Technical change and the aggregate production function. Rev Econ Stat 39:312–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ten Raa T (2008) Professor Jones’ re-appraisal of Heckscher–Ohlin trade flows. Trade Dev Rev 1:144–147

    Google Scholar 

  • ten Raa T, Mohnen P (2001) The location of comparative advantages on the basis of fundamentals only. Econ Syst Res 13:93–108

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trefler D (1993) International factor price differences: Leontief was right!. J Polit Econ 101:961–987

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vanek J (1968) The factor proportions theory: the n-factor case. Kyklos 21:749–756

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank two anonymous referees, an associate editor, Daniel Trefler, Xavier Gabaix, John Cochrane, and Matt Cole for helpful comments on earlier drafts. All the data and programs are available upon request.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Eric O’N. Fisher.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fisher, E.O., Marshall, K.G. Leontief was not right after all. J Prod Anal 46, 15–24 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-016-0466-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-016-0466-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation