Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The Organization of Factions: Interest Mobilization and the Group Theory of Politics

  • Published:
Public Organization Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Theories of interest group mobilization are central to political science but current research on interest organizations has not proven useful for scholars in related fields. I argue that, by adapting organizational theory to account for the particular function of interest organizations, scholars can build a widely applied theoretical framework. The key step is an analysis of the role that organizations play in the mobilization of influence: they are intermediaries, reliant on their constituents and their lobbying targets. Reviewing research on ethnic politics and political economy, I demonstrate that this intermediary view of interest organizations encourages theoretical ideas to travel between subfields.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Lasswell (1958) outlines these broad theoretical goals. Truman (1951) presents an early interest group theory of politics.

  2. For a discussion of context effects, see Bledsoe et al. (1995). For a review of identity and participation, see Shingles (1981).

  3. Some scholars (e.g., Esping-Andersen and Korpi, 1984) argue that economic class structure generates policy outcomes and these policies in turn create class alignments. Neoliberal scholars (e.g., Friedman and Friedman, 1962) argue that economic competition and global markets generate domestic constituencies that affect policy but also argue that government intervention can create additional constituencies. Other scholars, following the work of Polanyi (1944), argue that politics is constitutive of the economy: the political process determines the groups than then compete for policy influence.

  4. Tsebelis (1999) uses this concept to argue that scholars should pay attention to all groups or individuals in the political system that can block legislation.

  5. Wolin (1993) reviews the similarities and differences between traditional pluralism and its more recent counterparts.

  6. For further examples, see studies of social movements (e.g., McAdam et al., 2001), international non-governmental organizations (e.g., Brechin, 1997), corporatist systems (e.g., Lehmbruch, 1984), and public policy (e.g., Fernandez and Gould, 1994).

  7. Recent analyses of American interest groups combine organizational research with traditional group theories of politics (e.g., Truman, 1951). Gray and Lowery (2004) label this research agenda the “neopluralist perspective.” Andrew McFarland (2004) also suggests a reformulation of interest group theory under the moniker “neopluralism.”

  8. For an example, see Salisbury (1992). For an overview, see Moe (1984).

  9. See Denhardt (1981); Bozeman (1987); Waldo (1987); Gortner et al. (1997).

  10. For an early review of this literature, see Polsby (1963).

  11. The collective action framework became prominent in many areas of social science despite its widespread failure to explain the behavior of American interest groups, the empirical terrain from which it was originally inducted. For a review of the empirical results in contradiction with the theoretical work, see Baumgartner and Leech (1998).

  12. Selznick (1957) identifies many of the mechanisms that were later instantiated in the institutional theory of organizations. The classic theoretical statement is from Meyer and Rowan (1977).

  13. For an articulation of this goal, see Lehmbruch (1984).

  14. Brechin (1997), for example, has begun to outline how forestry organizations are dependent on their ability to adapt for successful social mobilization and inter-governmental relations.

  15. For an account based on normative goals, see Esping-Andersen (1990). For a class-based account, see Chaudhry (1993). These perspectives are welcome, as are evaluations of current economic‐political systems. This work could benefit, however, from empirical theory on how groups attempt to affect policy outcomes.

  16. For an example of a case study of economic policy that is not sufficiently addressed by common theories in political economy, see Johnson (1982).

  17. One example is the coalitions proposed in the insider‐outsider theory of unemployment by Lindbeck and Snower (1988). Based on presumed interests, these scholars imagine two large policy advocacy coalitions.

References

  • Alvarez, M.R., Garrett, G., & Lange, P. 1991. Government partisanship, labor organization, and macroeconomic performance. American Political Science Review, 85: 539–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, D. 1990. The logic of congressional action. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bauer, R.A., de Sola Pool, I., & Dexter, L.A. 1972. American business and public policy: The politics of foreign trade, 2d ed. Chicago: Aldine Artherton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumgartner, F.R., & Leech, B.L. 1998. Basic interests: The importance of groups in politics and political science. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry, J.M. 1989. The interest group society, 2d ed. New York: Harper Collins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bledsoe, T. et al. 1995. Residential context and racial solidarity among African Americans. American Journal of Political0 Science, 39: 434–458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bozeman, B. 1987. All organizations are public: Bridging public and private organizational theories. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brechin, S. 1997. Planting trees in the developing world: A sociology of international organizations. Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bueno de Mesguita, B. et al. 2002. Political institutions, policy choice, and the survival of leaders. British Journal of Political Science, 32: 559–590.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, A. 2003. How policies make citizens: Senior political activism and the American welfare state. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carmines, E., & Stimson, J. 1989. Issue evolution: Race and the transformation of American politics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cerny, P.G. 1994. The dynamics of financial globalization: Technology, market structure, and policy response. Policy Sciences, 27: 319–342.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cigle,r A.J. 1991. Interest Groups: A subfield in search of an identity. In: Crotty, W.J. (ed), Political science: Looking to the future: American institutions. Evanston, Illinois: Northwestern University Press, pp 99–135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cigler, A.J. 1994. Research gaps in the study of interest group representation. In: Crotty, W.J., Schwartz, M.A., & Green, J.C. (eds), Representing interests and interest group representation. Lanham, Maryland: University Press of America, pp 29–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chaudhry, K. 1993. The myths of the market and the common history of late developers. Politics & Society, 21: 5–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denhardt, R.B. 1981. In the shadow of organization. Lawrence: University of Kansas.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P., & Powell, W.W. 1983. The iron cage re-visited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48: 147–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Anderson, G. 1990. The three worlds of welfare capitalism. London: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Anderson, G., & Korpi, W. 1984. Social policy as class politics in post-war capitalism: Scandinavia, Austria, and Germany. In: Goldthorpe, J. (ed), Order and conflict in contemporary societies. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp 179–208.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez, R.M., & Gould, R.V. 1994. A dilemma of state power: Brokerage and influence in the national health policy domain. American Journal of Sociology 99:1455–1491

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M., & Friedman, R. 1962. Capitalism and freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frymer, P. 1999. Uneasy alliances: Race and party competition in America. Princeton: Princeton University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Gortner, H.F., Mahler, J., & Nicholson, J.B. 1997. Organization theory: A public perspective. Fort Worth, Texas: Harcourt Brace College Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gray, V., & Lowery, D. 1996. The population ecology of interest representation: Lobbying communities in the American States. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gray, V., & Lowery, D. 2004. A neopluralist perspective on research on organized interests. Political Research Quarterly, 57: 163–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hannan, M.T., & Freeman, J.H. 1977. The population ecology of organizations. American Journal of Sociology, 82: 929–964.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heinz, J.P. et al. 1993. The hollow core: Private interests in national policy making. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Immergut, E.M. 1992. The rules of the game: The logic of health policy-making in France, Switzerland and Sweden. In: Steinmo, S., Thelen, K., & Longstreth, F. (eds), Structuring politics: Historical institutionalism in comparative analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp 57–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, C.A. 1982. MITI and the japanese miracle: The growth of industrial policy, 1925–1975. Palo Alto: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, R.O., Milner, H.V., & Lange, P. (eds) 1996. Internationalization and domestic politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Key, V.O. 1964. Politics, parties pressure groups, 5th ed. New York: Crowell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kitschelt, H. 1994. The transformation of european social democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, T. 2002. Mobilizing public opinion: Black insurgency and racial attitudes in the civil rights era. Chicago: University of Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehmbruch, G. 1984. Concentration and the structure of corporatist networks. In: Goldthotpe, J. (ed) Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp 60–80.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lasswell, H. 1958. Politics: Who gets what, when, how. New York: World Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laumann, E.O., & Knoke, D. 1987. The organizational state: Social choice in national policy domains. Madison: University of Wisconsin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck, A., & Snower, D.J. 1988. The insider–outsider theory of unemployment. Cambridge: M.I.T.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lowi, T. 1979. The end of liberalism: The second republic of the United States. New York: W. W. Norton and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • McAdam, D., Tarrow, S., & Tilly, C. 2001. Dynamics of contention. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McFarland, A.S. 2004. Neopluralism: The evolution of political process theory. Lawrence: University of Kansas.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, J.W., & Rowan, B. 1977. Institutional organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. American Journal of Sociology, 83: 340–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moe, T.M. 1984. The new economics of organization. American Journal of Political Science, 28: 739–777.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oliver, J.E., & Wong, J. 2003 .Inter-group prejudice in multi-ethnic settings. American Journal of Political Science, 47: 567–582.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perry, J.L., & Rainey, H.G. 1988. The public–private distinction in organization theory: A critique and research strategy. Academy of Management Review, 13: 182–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polanyi, K. 1944. The great transformation: The political and economic origins of our time. New York: Rinehart & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Polsby, N.W. 1963. Community power and political theory. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rhodes, M. 2001. The political economy of social pacts: ‘Competitive corporatism’ and European welfare reform. In: Pierson, P. (ed), The new politics of the welfare state. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp 165–194.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Salisbury, R.H. 1984. Interest representation: The dominance of institutions. American Political Science Review, 78: 64–76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salisbury, R.H. 1992. Interests and institutions: Substance and structure in American politics. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanders, E. 1999. Roots of reform: Farmers, workers the American State, 1877–1917. Chicago: University of Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selznick, P. 1957. Leadership in administration: A sociological interpretation. Evanston, Illinois: Row & Peterson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shingles, R.D. 1981. Black consciousness and political participation: The missing link. American Political Science Review, 75: 76–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Truman, D.B. 1951. The governmental process: Political interests and public opinion. New York: Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. 1999. Veto players and law production in parliamentary democracies: An empirical analysis. American Political Science Review, 93: 591–608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waldo, D. 1987. Politics and administration: On thinking about a complex relationship. In: Chandler, R. C. (ed), A centennial history of the American Administrative State. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walker, J.L. 1991. Mobilizing interest groups in America: Patrons, professions social movements. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J.Q. 1995. Political organizations. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wolin, S. 1993. Democracy, difference re-cognition. Political Theory, 21: 464–483.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright, J. 1996. Interest groups and congress: Lobbying, contributions influence. Boston: Allyn and Bacon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zucker, L. 1983. Organizations as institutions. In: Bacharach, S.B. (ed), Research in the Sociology of Organizations. Greenwich, CO: JAI, pp 1–47.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Matt Grossmann.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Grossmann, M. The Organization of Factions: Interest Mobilization and the Group Theory of Politics. Public Organiz Rev 6, 107–124 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11115-006-0002-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11115-006-0002-3

Keywords

Navigation