Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The Law of One Food Price

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Are food prices more or less equalised across countries? In view of various barriers to trade (both naturally occurring and of a man-made nature) and currency gyrations, the answer would seem to be an unambiguous “No”, but we show this question is worthy of further investigation. In order for the law of one price (LOP) to hold, domestic prices must respond one-for-one to changes in world prices and exchange rates, but this is usually prevented by variations in mark-ups and/or trade barriers. We use data on producer prices from the Food and Agriculture Organization to test for the LOP. The results give surprising support to the LOP: Market wedges appear to be insufficiently important to prevent food prices equalising over the longer term. The law of one food price seems to hold, at least as a first approximation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Data Availability

The datasets generated and analysed during the current study are available from the authors on reasonable request.

Notes

  1. Relatedly, Frankel et al. (2012) document a rapid downward trend in the degree of exchange-rate pass-through and speed of adjustment (towards PPP) across both developed and developing countries since the 1990s. Interestingly, Rabe and Waddle (2020) estimate that the half-life of deviations from PPP fell from 3 to 2 years over the last five decades, and suggest that the PPP puzzle may be slightly abating over time due to the increasingly tradable nature of the composition of the consumer price index. This estimate of the half-life is also in broad agreement with that of Kunkler and MacDonald (2015), among others.

  2. Two other possible explanations for the lower food prices should be mentioned. First, because of their superior endowment of agricultural land and favourable climate, rich countries may simply have a comparative advantage in producing food at lower prices. A second explanation is Engel’s law: Higher income is likely to lead to growth in the consumption of most goods, but because of the Engel effect, food consumption grows slower than average. If on the supply side all sectors (food and non-food) expand at approximately the same rate, at constant relative prices there will be an excess supply of food. The combined effects lead to lower relative food prices in rich countries. A possible complication to this explanation is the food price elasticity may differ across countries. Because low-income countries devote a larger share of spending to food, food demand is likely to be more price elastic in these countries. The reverse is true in rich countries, with a smaller food share and a lower price elasticity is likely. As the production of food expands, the lower price elasticity means the incipient excess supply leads to a larger fall in the relative price. This effect would reinforce the above argument of cheap food in rich countries.

  3. The data source, the International Comparison Program (World Bank 2013, unpublished), does not reveal the actual brand name of the whiskey.

  4. The Economist’s approach of adjusting Big Mac prices for differences in country income can also be interpreted as a type of adjustment for differing nontraded components (The Economist (ongoing)). The income-adjusted prices are closer to parity.

  5. Many of these studies also establish that slow PPP convergence is driven primarily by nominal exchange-rate movements, a finding at odds with the conventional emphasis on slow price adjustments (as in the nominal rigidity literature, for example). In the short run, nominal-exchange-rate movements are seemingly disconnected from price movements, leading to the observation that exchange rates appear to disrupt PPP convergence. This idea is reinforced by the market for currencies being much larger than that for commodities: Total global merchandise and service trade value was US$25 trillion in 2018 (WTO 2019)—a mere 1% of total foreign-exchange trade in the same year (BIS 2019). Although the contrast between trade and financial flows is suggestive, the magnitude of the difference needs qualification. There are substantial measurement errors in both types of flows due to (i) double counting of trade volumes (as both exports from the source country and imports into the destination) and (ii) multi-counting of financial flows as a result of the notorious “churn” associated with high daily turnover in foreign-exchange markets.

  6. Additionally, there is some evidence that in the 1980s, the price response was asymmetric: Japanese exporters and importers exploited the temporary decrease in the value of the dollar to extract quota rents by further increasing yen prices, giving rise to a low pass-through coefficient. But when the dollar appreciates, the pass-through coefficient is not significantly different from 1. This is possibly because exporters do not have much incentive for changing prices in the presence of an inelastic destination demand and when the risk of loss of market share is small. From Japanese importers’ point of view, monopolistic power allows them to absorb favourable exchange-rate changes into margins. This type of incomplete and asymmetric pass-through behaviour is typical of food and agriculture markets, as in the recent cases of Japanese meat (Miljkovic and Zhuang 2011), US beer (Hellerstein 2008) and US cocoa bean (Luckstead 2018), for example. Forbes et al. (2018) find that exchange rate pass-through is low in response to domestic demand shocks and high in response to domestic monetary policy shocks. Another reason for a less-than-unitary pass-through is the tendency of exchange rates to “overshoot” economic fundamentals in the short-run (see, e.g., Bjørnland 2009; Dornbusch 1980; Frankel 2008; and Hatzenbuehler 2016).

  7. Other sources of deviations include the costs of distribution, trade policy interventions, insulating price policies, price stickiness and international oil price shocks (Jabara and Schwartz 1987).

  8. These are prices “received by farmers…as collected at the point of initial sale (prices paid at the farm-gate)” (FAO, online).

  9. For details, see Appendix A2.

  10. From the last two columns of panel C, 99 percent of the truncated observations \(\left(=\frac{\mathrm{96,769}}{\mathrm{97,274}}\right)\) are in the range \([ - 3, \, 3]\) while only 32 percent \(\left(\frac{\mathrm{30,752}}{\mathrm{97,274}}\right)\) are in the range \([ - 0.3, \, 0.3]\).

  11. In Appendix A4, we show that these observations persist when compressing the sample using country and commodity averages.

  12. Even when the individual test statistic of each cross-section has a non-standard distribution, under cross-sectional independence, the pooled test statistic (Z) converges to the standard Gaussian distribution and inference can be made on the basis of well-defined critical values obtained from simulations (Choi 2001). A more detailed discussion of this approach is provided in Appendix A5.

  13. The speed of adjustment may depend on the magnitude of the deviations, giving rise to a “no-arbitrage band” of the type investigated by Vo (2018).

  14. See, among others, Bahmani-Oskooee and Wu (2018), Breitung and Candelon (2005), Pesaran (2007), and Westerlund and Blomquist (2013).

  15. As wheat exports are a small fraction of Australia’s GDP, can they plausibly affect the value of the currency? Prominent Australian exports are agricultural commodities, minerals and energy. Some important mineral and energy exports tend to operate under long-term pricing arrangements with limited flexibility (such as iron ore and LNG), while agricultural commodities usually have more flexible transaction-level prices. According to ABARES, wheat represents more than 20% of Australia’s agricultural exports (https://daff.ent.sirsidynix.net.au/client/en_AU/xls (https://live.com). Flexible wheat prices can be taken as indicative of the state of the world market for agricultural commodities in general. As the Australian dollar is widely regarded as a “commodity currency”, it can be seen how variations in wheat prices might affect the exchange rate.

  16. As there is neither trending nor drifting behaviour, we do not include deterministic terms. The lag length is determined to be 4 by the Akaike information criterion. For an examination of generalisations of the VAR model, see Appendix A7.

  17. Appendix A7 provides details on the construction of the GIRFs.

  18. An example of such a sustained disequilibrium of exchange rates is the “dollar effect”, which refers to the persistent misalignment of some currencies against the USD.

References

  • Abbott PC (2010) Exchange Rates and Agricultural Commodity Prices. AEA Annual Meeting. Denver, CO. July 25–27

  • Anderson JE, van Wincoop E (2004) Trade Costs. Journal of Economic Literature 42:691–751

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baffes J (1991) Some Further Evidence on the Law of One Price: The Law of One Price Still Holds. Am J Agric Econ 73:1264–1273

  • Bahmani-Oskooee M, Wu TP (2018) PPP In the 34 OECD Countries: Evidence from Quantile-based Unit Root Tests with both Smooth and Sharp Breaks. Appl Econ 50:2622–2634

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balassa B (1964) The Purchasing Power Parity Doctrine: A Reappraisal. J Polit Econ 72:584–596

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bank for International Settlements (2019) Triennial Central Bank Survey of Foreign Exchange and Over-the-counter (OTC) Derivatives Markets. Online database. Available at: https://www.bis.org/statistics/rpfx19.htm

  • Bergin PR, Glick R, J. L., Wu, (2017) Conditional PPP and Real Exchange Rate Convergence in the Euro Area. J Int Money Financ 73:78–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjørnland HC (2009) Monetary Policy and Exchange Rate Overshooting: Dornbusch Was Right After All. J Int Econ 79:64–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breitung J, Candelon B (2005) Purchasing Power Parity During Currency Crises: A Panel Unit Root Test Under Structural Breaks. Rev World Econ 141:124–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burstein A, Gopinath G (2014) International Prices and Exchange Rates. In: Gopinath G, Helpman E, Rogoff K (eds) Handbook of International Economics, vol 4. Elsevier, The Netherlands, pp 391–451

    Google Scholar 

  • Cavallo A, Diewert WE, Feenstra RC, Inklaar R, Timmer MP (2018) Using Online Prices for Measuring Real Consumption Across Countries. AEA Papers and Proceedings 108:483–487

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cavallo A, Neiman B, Rigobon R (2014) Currency Unions, Product Introductions, and the Real Exchange Rate. Quart J Econ 129:529–595

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cavallo A, Rigobon R (2016) The Billion Prices Project: Using Online Prices for Measurement and Research. Journal of Economic Perspectives 30:151–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ca’Zorzi, M., J. Muck and M. Rubaszek. (2017) Real Exchange Rate Forecasting And PPP: This Time The Random Walk Loses. Open Econ Rev 27(3):585–609

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen YC, Rogoff K (2003) Commodity Currencies. J Int Econ 60:133–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen YC, Rogoff K, Rossi B (2010) Can Exchange Rates Forecast Commodity Prices? Quart J Econ 125:1145–1194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheung YW, Lai KS, Bergman M (2004) Dissecting the PPP Puzzle: The Unconventional Roles of Nominal Exchange Rate and Price Adjustments. J Int Econ 64:135–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi I (2001) Unit Root Tests for Panel Data. J Int Money Financ 20:249–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chou YH (2017) Dissecting Exchange Rates and Fundamentals in the Modern Floating Era: The Role of Permanent and Transitory Shocks. Rev Int Econ 25:165–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clements KW, Fry R (2008) Commodity Currencies and Currency Commodities. Resour Policy 33:55–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crucini MJ, Shintani M (2008) Persistence in Law of One Price Deviations: Evidence from Micro-Data. J Monet Econ 55:629–644

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DellaVigna S, Gentzkow M (2019) Uniform Pricing in US Retail Chains. Quart J Econ 134:2011–2084

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diakosavvas D (2001) The Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture in Practice: How Open Are OECD Markets? World Bank Conference “Leveraging Trade, Global Market Integration, and the New WTO Negotiations for Development”. Washington D.C., 23-24 July 2001

  • Dornbusch R (1980) Open Economy Macroeconomics. Basic Books, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Dornbusch, R. (1988). “Purchasing Power Parity.” In The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. New York: Stockton Press

  • Eichenbaum M, Johannsen BK, Rebelo S (2020) Monetary Policy and the Predictability of Nominal Exchange Rates. Rev Econ Stud. Forthcoming

  • Enders W (2015) Applied Econometric Time Series. Wiley, Canada

    Google Scholar 

  • Engel C, Rogers JH (1996) How Wide Is The Border? Am Econ Rev 86:1112–1125

    Google Scholar 

  • Fackler PL, Goodwin BK (2001) Spatial Price Analysis. Handbook of Agricultural Economics, vol 1. Elsevier, The Netherlands, pp 971–1024

  • Food and Agriculture Organization (2018) Statistical Data. Available at: http://www.fao.org/faostat/en/#data/

  • Feenstra C, Kendall JD (1997) Pass-Through of Exchange Rates and Purchasing Power Parity. J Int Econ 43:237–261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forbes K, Hjortsoe I, Nenova T (2018) The Shocks Matter: Improving Our Estimates of Exchange Rate Pass-Through. J Int Econ 114:255–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • FRED (2018) Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Available at: https://research.stlouisfed.org/

  • Frankel J (2008) The Effect of Monetary Policy on Real Commodity Prices. In: Campbell JY (ed) Asset Prices and Monetary Policy. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 291–334

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel J, Parsley D, Wei SJ (2012) Slow Pass-Through around the World: A New Import for Developing Countries? Open Econ Rev 23:213–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frenkel JA (1978) Purchasing Power Parity: Doctrinal Perspective and Evidence from the 1920s. J Int Econ 8:169–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Froot KA, Rogoff K (1995) Perspectives on PPP and Long-Run Real Exchange Rates. In: Grossman G, Rogoff K (eds) Handbook of International Economics, vol 3. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 1647–1688

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldberg PK, Knetter MM (1997) Goods Prices and Exchange Rates: What Have We Learned? J Econ Lit 35:1243–1272

    Google Scholar 

  • Hartung J (1999) A Note on Combining Dependent Tests of Significance. Biom J 41:849–855

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hatzenbuehler PL, Abbott PC, Foster KA (2016) Agricultural Commodity Prices and Exchange Rates under Structural Change. J Agric Resour Econ 41:204–224

    Google Scholar 

  • Hellerstein R (2008) Who Bears the Cost of a Change in the Exchange Rate? Pass-Through Accounting for the Case of Beer. J Int Econ 76:14–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imbs J, Mumtaz H, Ravn MO, Rey H (2005) PPP Strikes Back: Aggregation and The Real Exchange Rate. Quart J Econ 120:1–43

    Google Scholar 

  • Iregui AM, Otero J (2017) Testing for Spatial Market Integration: Evidence for Colombia Using a Pairwise Approach. Agric Econ 48:743–753

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jabara CL, Schwartz NE (1987) Flexible Exchange Rates and Commodity Price Changes: The Case of Japan. Am J Agr Econ 69:580–590

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacks DS, O’Rourke KH, Williamson JG (2011) Commodity Price Volatility and World Market Integration since 1700. Rev Econ Stat 93:800–813

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kao C (1999) Spurious Regression and Residual-Based Tests for Cointegration in Panel Data. J Economet 90:1–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kituyi M (2020) Trade Wars Are Huge Threats to Food Security”. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. Available at: https://unctad.org/news/trade-wars-are-huge-threats-food-security

  • Kunkler M, MacDonald R (2015) Half-Lives of Currencies and Aggregation Bias. Econ Lett 135:58–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li J, Li Z, Sun P (2018) Does the Razor’s Edge Exist? New Evidence of the Law of One Price in China (1997–2012). World Econ 41:3442–3466

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loayza NV, Ranciere R, Servén L, Ventura J (2007) Macroeconomic Volatility and Welfare in Developing Countries: An Introduction. World Bank Econ Rev 21:343–357

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lothian JR (2016) Purchasing Power Parity and the Behavior of Prices and Nominal Exchange Rates across Exchange-rate Regimes. J Int Money Financ 69:5–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lothian JR, Taylor MP (1996) Real Exchange Rate Behavior: The Recent Float from the Perspective of the Past Two Centuries. J Polit Econ 104:488–509

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lothian JR, Taylor MP (2008) Real Exchange Rates over the Past Two Centuries: How Important is the Harrod-Balassa-Samuelson Effect? Econ J 118:1742–1763

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luckstead J (2018) Asymmetric Exchange Rate Pass-Through in US Imports of Cocoa. J Agric Appl Econ 50:369–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lütkepohl H (2005) New Introduction to Multiple Time Series Analysis. Springer-Verlag, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Manzur M (2008) Purchasing Power Parity. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing

  • Mark NC, Choi DY (1997) Real Exchange-Rate Prediction over Long Horizons. J Int Econ 43:29–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marsh IW, Passari E, Sarno L (2012) Purchasing Power Parity in Tradable Goods. In: James J, Marsh IW, Sarno L (eds) Handbook of Exchange Rates. Wiley, pp 189–220

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Mundlak Y, Larson DF (1992) On the Transmission of World Agricultural Prices. World Bank Econ Rev 6:399–422

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miljkovic D, Zhuang R (2011) The Exchange Rate Pass-Through into Import Prices: The Case of Japanese Meat Imports. Appl Econ 43:3745–3754

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Connell PG (1998) The Overvaluation of Purchasing Power Parity. J Int Econ 44:1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2001) The Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture: An Evaluation of Its Implementation in OECD Countries. OECD Publishing, Paris. https://doi.org/10.1787/9789264192188-en

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Officer LH (1982) Purchasing Power Parity and Exchange Rates: Theory, Evidence and Relevance. JAI Press, Greenwich, CT

    Google Scholar 

  • Papell D, Prodan R (2020) Long-Run Purchasing Power Parity Redux. J Int Money Financ 109:102260

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parsley DC, Wei S-J (2001) Explaining the Border Effect: The Role of Exchange Rate Variability, Shipping Costs, and Geography. J Int Econ 55:87–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pedroni P (2004) Panel Cointegration: Asymptotic and Finite Sample Properties of Pooled Time Series Tests with an Application to the PPP Hypothesis. Economet Theor 20:597–625

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran MH (2007) A Simple Panel Unit Root Test in the Presence of Cross-section Dependence. J Appl Economet 22:265–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran MH, Shin Y (1996) Cointegration and Speed of Convergence to Equilibrium. Journal of Econometrics 71:117–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran MH, Shin Y (1998) Generalized Impulse Response Analysis in Linear Multivariate Models. Econ Lett 58:17–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rabe C, Waddle A (2020) The Evolution of Purchasing Power Parity. J Int Money Financ 109:102237

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogoff K (1996) The Purchasing Power Parity Puzzle. J Econ Lit 34:647–668

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson PA (1964) Theoretical Problems on Trade Problems. Rev Econ Stat 46:145–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Senay O, Sutherland A (2015) Local Currency Pricing, Foreign Monetary Shocks and Exchange Rate Policy. Open Econ Rev 26(4):633–661

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simonovska I (2015) Income Differences and Prices of Tradables: Insights from an Online Retailer. Rev Econ Stud 82:1612–1656

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor AM, Taylor MP (2004) The Purchasing Power Parity Debate. J Econ Perspect 18:135–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • The Economist (ongoing). “The Big Mac Index”. Available at: http://www.economist.com/content/big-mac-index

  • USDA (2020) United States Department of Agriculture. “Wheat Data.” Available at: https://www.ers.usda.gov/data-products/wheat-data/

  • Vo LH (2018) “Why Don’t Agricultural Prices Always Adjust Towards Parity?” Discussion Paper 18.09. Economics Department, Business School, The University of Western Australia

  • Westerlund J (2007) Testing for Error Correction in Panel Data. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 69:709–748

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Westerlund J, Blomquist J (2013) A Modified LLC Panel Unit Root Test of the PPP Hypothesis. Empirical Economics 44:833–860

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2013) International Comparison Program Data for Researchers. Washington, DC: World Bank

  • World Trade Organization (2019) “Highlights of World Trade”. In World Trade Statistical Review, Chapter 2, pp 6–15. WTO: Geneva

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper benefited from helpful suggestions and comments made by two anonymous referees, the Editor of this journal, Yihui Lan, James Lothian, Ranjan Ray, Jeffrey Sheen and participants at the 1st Australasian Commodity Markets Conference, the 64th Annual Conference of the Australasian Agricultural and Resource Economics Society, the 5th Vietnam’s Conference on Business, Economics and Resources, and various internal seminars at the University of Western Australia (UWA). Long Hai Vo gratefully acknowledges financial support from an Australian Government Research Training Program Scholarship. For provision of unpublished data, the authors thank the International Comparison Program administrators at the World Bank. All errors remain with the authors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hai Long Vo.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of Interest

The authors have no competing interests to declare that are relevant to the content of this article.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file1 (DOCX 2228 KB)

Supplementary file2 (DOCX 45 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Clements, K.W., Si, J. & Vo, H.L. The Law of One Food Price. Open Econ Rev 34, 195–216 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-022-09671-9

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-022-09671-9

Keywords

JEL

Navigation