Skip to main content
Log in

The Revival of Target Zone Modeling

  • Review Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Krugman's ‘honeymoon’ seminal paper showed in 1991 the stabilizing properties of the adoption of fluctuation bands and gave rise to the literature on target zones. Subsequent contributions, however, showed that, in the absence of adequate reserves, a destabilizing ‘divorce’ would lead to speculative attacks.

The euro area public debt crisis revived that literature, producing a second generation of target zone modeling, based on the idea that the sustainability of public debt implies the adoption of an interest rate target. Its lack of credibility (if the central bank or the government does not guarantee repayment of the debt) explains the non-linearity of the relationship between interest rates and public debt that was observed during the euro area crisis. The model also makes it possible to understand why some non-euro area countries have not been subject to speculative attacks despite the fact that their public debt-to-GDP ratios were as high as those of countries in crisis, but guaranteed by the 'virtual' reserves of their national central banks. Finally, a third generation of target zone modeling is represented by its application to the current crisis of economic globalization and has been extended to merge it with heterogeneous agents modeling.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Krugman and Miller (1992) contains a first set of important contributions. Kempa and Nelles (1999) provide an accurate theoretical and empirical overview of the large body of literature that developed approximately during the first decade of life of the exchange rate target zone literature. Duarte et al. (2013), instead, reviewed, together with the basic setup of the model, also the subsequent theoretical developments, until about 10 years ago. No significant contributions or applications have appeared after then. This is why I have used the term ‘revival’ in my paper.

  2. One can think of the state of economic fundamentals as represented, for example, by money supply in a standard monetary model of exchange rate determination.

  3. Duarte et al. (2013) already introduce the distinction between a ‘first’ and a ‘second generation’ of target zone modelling. In their terminology, the former is the one relative to the full-credibility ‘honeymoon’ case, while with the latter they refer to the imperfect-credibility case of ‘divorce’.

  4. Among the many papers that have been devoted to the study of exchange rate target zones, one can refer to Farina and Tamborini (2004), Hughes Hallet and Minford (1990) and Tirelli (1991).

  5. Krugman’s model assumes instead the exchange rate equation: \({s}_{t}={m}_{t}+\beta \frac{E(d{s}_{t})}{dt}\).

  6. The ‘fundamentals-driven’ risk premium may well depend on the difference between the absolute size of the public debt-to-GDP ratio \({b}_{t}\) an expected maximum ‘safe’ value like, for example, the 60% public debt-to-GDP ratio reported in the Maastricht Treaty. Alcidi and Gros (2018), IMF (2011) and European Commission (2014), for example, consider the risk premium as determined by such a difference. It should be stressed, however, that such a value is far from objective and univocally determined but results instead from institutional and possibly also contingent choices. The value assigned to α is 0.03 in the case of developed countries (Alcidi and Gros 2018) and 0.04 in the case of developing countries (IMF 2011).

  7. “Economists usually like to model people as calculating optimally their investment decisions based on expectations of future price changes and estimates of the risk in alternative investments” (Shiller 2000, p. 55).

  8. See Della Posta (2019) for further details on the government debt stability condition. The dynamics of public debt might have had a more complex specification, for example in the case in which some foreign resources were available (IMF, Next Generation EU, and the like). In the present setup of the model, I do not consider those possibilities, that could be simply thought, however, as determining a larger value for \(\widetilde {m}\).

  9. See Tamborini (2015) for further details on the conditions that have to hold for public debt sustainability.

  10. Equation (53) also suggests that it would be possible to use as a dependent variable of the target zone model also either \(m_t\)  or \(s_t\).

  11. Normally, an anti-inflationary and independent central bank will avoid printing money when that may cause inflation, but it is difficult to imagine that a monetary authority which is caught between the need to avoid inflation and the need to avoid the bankruptcy of her own country will prefer the second option.

  12. The equation above captures quite intuitively the fact that the costs of globalization resented by the population are both real and perceived. The role played by self-fulfilling expectations in driving human behavior is well-known, the placebo effect being probably the most famous example of it.

  13. In what follows, also in line with the previous applications of target zone modeling, any lower target for the costs is also ignored, since we are focusing on the possible destabilizing effects resulting from an increase in the level of globalization.

References

  • Alcidi C, Gros D (2018) Debt Sustainability Assessments: The state of the art. European Parliament

  • Ayres J, Navarro G, Nicolini JP, Teles P (2018) Sovereign default: The role of expectations. J Econ Theory 175:803–812

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertola G, Caballero R (1992) Target Zones and Realignments. Am Econ Rev 82(3):520–536. Retrieved from http://www.jstor.org/stable/2117319

  • Corsetti G, Kuester K, Meier A, Müller GJ (2014) Sovereign risk and belief-driven fluctuations in the euro area. J Monetary Econ 61: 53–73

  • De Grauwe P (2012) The Governance of a Fragile Eurozone. Australian Econ Rev 45(3):255–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe P, Ji Y (2013a) Self-fulfilling crises in the Eurozone: An empirical test. J Internatl Money Finance - European Sovereign Debt Crisis: Background & Perspective 34–36

  • De Grauwe P, Ji Y (2013a) From panic-driven austerity to symmetric macroeconomic policies in the Eurozone. J Common Market Stud 51 Annual Rev 31–41

  • Della Posta P (2018) Central bank intervention, public debt and interest rate target zones. J Macroecon 56:311–323, June. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmacro.2018.04.001

  • Della Posta P (2019) Interest rate targets and speculative attacks on public debt. Macroecon Dynamics 23(7):2698–2716. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1365100517000931. Published online: 16 March 2018

  • Della Posta P (2020a) The economic and social costs of globalization: a target zones analysis. The World Econ First published, 17 July 2020. https://doi.org/10.1111/twec.13008

  • Della Posta P (2020b) An analysis of the current backlash of economic globalization in a model with heterogeneous agents. Metroeconomica, First published: 02 September 2020, 1–20, 2020. https://doi.org/10.1111/meca.12312

  • Della Posta P (2021) Government size and speculative attacks on public debt. Int Rev Econ Finance 72:79–89. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.iref.2020.11.004. Accepted 15 Nov 2020

  • Duarte AP, Andrade J, Duarte A (2013) Exchange Rate Target Zones: A Survey of the Literature. J Econ Surveys 27(2):247–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2014) Assessing Public Debt Sustainability in EU Member States: A Guide, European Economy, Occasional Papers 200 | September 2014

  • Farina F, Tamborini R (2004) “Set a Sufficiently Ambitious Budget Target and Let the Automatic Stabilizers Work”. Will it Really Work in the European Monetary Union? Open Econ Rev 15:143–168. https://doi.org/10.1023/B:OPEN.0000012300.71559.9a

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flood RP, Garber PM (1984) Collapsing exchange-rate regimes. J Int Econ 17(1–2):1–13. https://doi.org/10.1016/0022-1996(84)90002-3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hughes-Hallett A, Minford P (1990) Target zones and exchange rate management: A stability analysis of the European Monetary System. Open Econ Rev 1:175–200. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01886164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2011) Modernizing the Framework for Fiscal Policy and Public Debt Sustainability Analysis. Prepared by the Fiscal Affairs Department and the Strategy, Policy, and Review Department. August 5

  • Kempa B, Nelles M (1999) The Theory of Exchange Rate Target Zones. Journal of Economic Surveys 13:173–210. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-6419.00081

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1991) Target Zones and Exchange Rate Dynamics. Quarter J Econ 106 (3):669–682

  • Krugman P, Rotemberg J (1992) Speculative Attacks on Target Zones. In: Krugman P, Miller M (eds) Exchange Rate Targets and Currency Bands. Cambridge University Press, pp 117–132

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P, Miller N (eds) (1992) Exchange Rate Targets and Currency Bands. Cambridge University Press

  • Obstfeld M (1986) Rational and Self-fulfilling Balance-of-Payments Crises. Am Econ Rev 76(1):72–81

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller RC (2000) Irrational exuberance. Phil Pub Pol Quart 20(1):18–23

    Google Scholar 

  • Tamborini R (2015) Heterogeneous Market Beliefs, Fundamentals and the Sovereign Debt Crisis in the Eurozone. Economica 82(s1):1153–1176. https://doi.org/10.1111/ecca.12155

  • Tirelli P (1991) Target zones and wealth effects: Current account implications of alternative policy assignments. Open Econ Rev 2:65–82. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01886135

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pompeo Della Posta.

Additional information

I would like to thank three anonymous referees for their precious comments and suggestions. They have allowed me to improve significantly my article. Needless to say, none of them can be held responsible for any remaining mistake.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Della Posta, P. The Revival of Target Zone Modeling. Open Econ Rev 33, 775–805 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-021-09642-6

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-021-09642-6

Keywords

JEL

Navigation