Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Explaining International Business Cycle Synchronization: Recursive Preferences and the Terms of Trade Channel

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The business cycles of advanced economies are synchronized. Standard macro models fail to explain that fact. This paper presents a simple model of a two-country, two-traded-good, complete-financial-markets world in which country-specific productivity shocks generate business cycles that are highly correlated internationally. The model assumes recursive intertemporal preferences (Epstein-Zin-Weil), and a muted response of labor hours to household wealth changes (due to Greenwood-Hercowitz-Huffman period utility and demand-determined employment under rigid wages). Recursive intertemporal preferences magnify the terms of trade response to country-specific shocks. Hence, a productivity (and GDP) increase in a given country triggers a strong improvement of the foreign country’s terms of trade, which raises foreign labor demand. With a muted labor wealth effect, foreign labor and GDP rise, i.e. domestic and foreign real activity comove positively.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Other related International RBC models include Dellas (1986), Cantor and Mark (1988), Crucini (1989), Devereux et al. (1992), Kollmann (1991, 1996), Schmitt-Grohé (1998) and Heathcote and Perri (2002).

  2. CRA > 1/IES implies a preference for the early resolution of uncertainty over future consumption (Weil 1990).

  3. In response to the Home productivity increase, Foreign life-time utility rises too, but less than Home life-time utility (due i.a. to the local spending bias); thus, the relative Home/Foreign IMRS falls.

  4. Benigno et al. (2012), Mumtaz and Theodoridis (2015) and Backus et al. (2016) study the effect of volatility shocks. Kollmann (2010) and Tretvoll (2016) analyze determinants of real exchange rate variability, while Colacito et al. (2014) explore differential effects of permanent and transitory productivity shocks on international capital flows. Only the latter three papers report model-predicted international correlations – those papers fail to capture the simultaneous high empirical cross-country correlations of output, labor and investment.

  5. In the numerical simulations, b is set at a very small value, which implies that the term βi,tΨi,t + 1/Ψi,t in (4) makes a negligible contribution to high-frequency fluctuations of ρi,t + 1.

  6. Concavity of the KPR period utility function requires ζ´´ < (2 − 1/σ)(ζ´)2/ζ.

  7. Under GHH utility, the disutility of labor is scaled by Xi,t to permit balanced growth, and to ensure that equilibrium hours worked are stationary; the Xi,t term can be rationalized by assuming that there is household home production (e.g., Rudebusch and Swanson (2012)). KPR period utility is consistent with balanced growth and stationary hours when the disutility of work is not scaled by productivity.

  8. Holding consumption constant, a rise in the wage rate w induces an increase in desired labor supply, as -ζ’/ ζ is increasing in hours worked; for a given wage rate w, a rise in consumption lowers desired hours worked (negative wealth effect), under KPR period utility.

  9. Rigid-wage models usually assume that hours are demand-determined (e.g., Blanchard and Gali 2007; Kollmann et al. 2016).

  10. The small value of b implies that short term model dynamics are similar to those generated by a (non-stationary) model variant with a constant subjective discount factor (b = 0).

  11. Under KPR period utility, the Frisch labor supply elasticity (LSE), evaluated at the steady state, is LSE=1/(1/η+ω/sC), where η is the curvature of labor disutility (see (7)) and sC is the steady state consumption/GDP ratio. sC depends solely on ω,δ and \( \overline{\beta} \). Under GHH utility, LSE = η.

  12. The 13 ROW countries are: Australia, Austria, Canada, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Korea, Norway, Sweden, UK. The Ohanian-Raffo quarterly labor hours data (available until 2013) are estimated from time series on employment and hours worked per employee (ILO, OECD).

  13. In the model, the share of GDP going to labor equals ω; the sample average of the labor share (compensation of employees/(GDP net of indirect taxes)) is 0.64 (0.66) in the US (ROW).

  14. I construct empirical log productivity (labor augmenting) for country i as ln(θi, t) = ( ln(GDPi, t) − ωi ln(Li, t) − (1 − ωi) ln(Ki, t))/ωi, where ωi is the sample average of i’s labor share. The labor input measure is total hours worked; quarterly capital series are cubic spline interpolates of annual capital stocks from the Penn World Table. A Törnqvist index is used to construct aggregate ROW productivity, θROW,t: \( \varDelta \kern0em \ln \kern0em {\theta}_{ROW,t}={\sum}_{j=1}^{13}{s}_{j,t}\varDelta \kern0em \ln {\theta}_{j,t} \) where sj,is the weight of country j at date t, with ∑sj,t = 1. The weights are countries’ smoothed nominal GDP shares in aggregate ROW nominal US$ GDP, at current exchange rates (to reduce the effect of nominal exchange rate volatility, exponential time trends are fitted to raw GDP shares, and fitted trend shares are used as weights).

  15. ROW aggregates for GDP, C, I and L (hours worked) are Törnqvist indices (GDP-weighted) of individual countries’ series. The ROW NX/GDP series is a GDP-weighted average of individual countries’ NX/GDP.

  16. Based on returns data from Ken French’s data base. The Sharpe ratio of an asset is the ratio of the mean of its excess return (relative to a risk-free asset) divided by its standard deviation.

  17. Consumption is countercyclical in model variants with KPR period utility and recursive intertemporal preferences (see discussion below).

  18. With recursive preferences and KPR period utility, Home consumption actually falls on impact. This explains why consumption is countercyclical, in that model configuration, as mentioned above.

  19. The stronger initial rise in Home GDP, under a predetermined consumption wage rate, explains why the predicted standard deviation of output (about 1.4%) is higher than in a flex-wage structure. Also, the predicted relative standard deviation of hours worked is now larger than the empirical relative standard deviation. By contrast, the flex-wage model variants yield a relative volatility of hours worked that is below empirical relative hours volatility.

References

  • Adjemian S, Bastani H, Karamé F, Juillard M, Maih J, Mihoubi F, Perendia G, Pfeifer J, Ratto M, Villemot S (2014) Dynare: reference manual, version 4.4.3. CEPREMAP, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Backus D, Smith G (1993) Consumption and real exchange rates in dynamic economies with non-traded goods. J Int Econ 35:297–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Backus D, Kehoe P, Kydland F (1992) International real business cycles. J Polit Econ 100:745–775

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Backus D, Kehoe P, Kydland F (1994) Dynamics of the trade balance and the terms of trade: the J-curve? Am Econ Rev 84:84–103

    Google Scholar 

  • Backus D, Coleman C, Ferriere A, Lyon S (2016) Risk and risk-sharing in two-country models. J Econ Dyn Control 72

  • Benigno G, Benigno P, Nisticò S (2012) Risk, monetary policy, and the exchange rate. NBER Macroecon Annu 26:247–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Gali J (2007) Real wage rigidities and the new Keynesian model. J Money Credit Bank 39(S1):35–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cantor R, Mark N (1988) The international transmission of real business cycles. Int Econ Rev 29:493–507

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caporale GM, Donadelli M, Varani A (2014) International capital markets structure, preferences and puzzles: The US-China case. CESifo Working Paper 4669

  • Colacito R, Croce M (2011) Risks for the long run and the real exchange rate. J Polit Econ 119:153–182

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colacito R, Croce M (2013) International asset pricing with recursive preferences. J Financ 68:2651–2686

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colacito R, Croce M, Ho S, Howard P (2014) BKK the EZ way. Working Paper, University of North Carolina

  • Correia I, Rebelo S (1995) Business cycles in small open economies. Eur Econ Rev 39:1089–1113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti G, Dedola L, Viani F (2012) The international risk sharing puzzle is at business cycle and lower frequency. Can J Econ 45:448–471

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crucini M (1989) A two-country real business cycle model. University of Rochester, Working Paper

    Google Scholar 

  • Dellas H (1986) A real model of the world business cycle. J Int Money Financ 5:381–294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Devereux MB, Gregory A, Smith G (1992) Realistic cross-country consumption correlations in a two-country, equilibrium, business cycle model. J Int Money Financ 11:3–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dou W, Verdelhan A (2015) The volatility of international capital flows and foreign assets. Working Paper, MIT

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein L, Zin S (1989) Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: a theoretical framework. Econometrica 57:937–969

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gourio F, Siemer M, Verdelhan A (2013) International risk cycles. J Int Econ 89:471–484

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood J, Hercowitz Z, Huffman G (1988) Investment, capacity utilization and the real business cycle. Am Econ Rev 27:402–417

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen LP, Jagannathan R (1991) Implications of security market data for models of dynamic economies. J Polit Econ 99:225–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heathcote J, Perri F (2002) Financial globalization and real regionalization. J Econ Theory 119:207–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaimovich N, Rebelo S (2008) News and business cycles in open economies. J Money Credit Bank 40:1699–1711

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King R, Plosser C, Rebelo S (1988) Production, growth and business cycles: I the basic neoclassical model. J Monet Econ 21:195–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kollmann R (1991) Essays on international business cycles. PhD dissertation, Economics Department, University of Chicago

  • Kollmann R (1995) Consumption, real exchange rates and the structure of international asset markets. J Int Money Financ 14:191–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kollmann R (1996) Incomplete asset markets and the cross-country consumption correlation puzzle. J Econ Dyn Control 20:945–962

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kollmann R (2009) EZW in a world economy. ECARES, Université Libre de Bruxelles, Working Paper

    Google Scholar 

  • Kollmann R (2010) International real business cycles with Epstein-Zin-Weil preferences. ECARES, Université Libre de Bruxelles, Working Paper

  • Kollmann R (2015) Exchange rate dynamics with long-run risk and recursive preferences. Open Econ Rev 26:175–196

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kollmann R (2016) International business cycles and risk sharing with uncertainty shocks and recursive preferences. J Econ Dyn Control 72:115–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kollmann R, Pataracchia B, Raciborski R, Ratto M, Roeger W, Vogel L (2016) The post-crisis slump in the euro area and the US: evidence from an estimated three-region DSGE model. Eur Econ Rev 88:21–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Küçük H (2011) Essays on international portfolio allocation and risk sharing. PhD Dissertation, Economics Department, London School of Economics

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis K, Liu E (2015) Evaluating international consumption risk sharing gains: an asset return view. J Monet Econ 71:84–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lustig H, Verdelhan A (2015) Does incomplete spanning in international financial markets help to explain exchange rates? Working paper. In: MIT

    Google Scholar 

  • Mumtaz H, Theodoridis K (2015) Common and country specific economic uncertainty. In: Working paper 752. Queen Mary College, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohanian L, Raffo A (2012) Aggregate hours worked in OECD countries: new measurement and implications for business cycles. J Monet Econ 59:40–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ohanian L, Raffo A (2014) Updated dataset (1960-2013) on aggregate hours worked in OECD countries (posted on A. Raffo’s web page)

  • Raffo A (2010) Technology shocks: novel implications for international business cycles. Federal Reserve Board, International Finance Discussion Paper 992

  • Rudebusch G, Swanson E (2012) The bond premium in a DSGE model with long-run real and nominal risks. Am Econ J Macroecon 4:105–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sauzet M (2015) Great retrenchment, financial contagion and international risk-sharing. In: Working paper. Sciences Po, Paris

  • Schmitt-Grohé S (1998) The international transmission of economic fluctuations: effects of U.S. business cycles on the Canadian economy. J Int Econ 44:257–287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swanson E (2014) A macroeconomic model of equities and real, nominal, and defaultable debt. Working Paper, UC Irvine

  • Tretvoll H (2016) Real exchange rate variability in a two-country business cycle model. Working paper. In: BI Norwegian Business School

    Google Scholar 

  • Weil P (1989) The equity premium puzzle and the risk-free rate puzzle. J Monet Econ 24:401–421

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weil P (1990) Nonexpected utility in macroeconomics. Q J Econ 105:29–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I thank Giancarlo Corsetti, Nelson Mark, Kemal Özhan, Vincenzo Quadrini, Werner Roeger, Gauthier Vermandel, Roland Winkler and workshop participants at Fed Board of Governors, Dallas Fed, IMAC3, Korea University, MACFINROBODS, SED, Swiss National Bank and Bank or England for useful comments and discussions. The research leading to these results has received funding from the European Community’s Seventh Framework Programme (FP7) under grant agreement no. 612796, Project MACFINROBODS (‘Integrated Macro-Financial Modelling for Robust Policy Design’).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert Kollmann.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kollmann, R. Explaining International Business Cycle Synchronization: Recursive Preferences and the Terms of Trade Channel. Open Econ Rev 30, 65–85 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-018-9515-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-018-9515-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation