Skip to main content
Log in

Optimal Currency Area: A twentieth Century Idea for the twenty-first Century?

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We take stock of the history of the European Monetary Union and pegged exchange-rate regimes in recent decades. The post-Bretton Woods greater financial integration and under-regulated financial intermediation have increased the cost of sustaining a currency area and other forms of fixed exchange-rate regimes. Financial crises illustrated that fast-moving asymmetric financial shocks interacting with real distortions pose a grave threat to the stability of currency areas and fixed exchange-rate regimes. Members of a currency union with closer financial links may accumulate asymmetric balance-sheet exposure over time, becoming more susceptible to sudden-stop crises. In a phase of deepening financial ties, countries may end up with more correlated business cycles. Down the road, debtor countries that rely on financial inflows to fund structural imbalances may be exposed to devastating sudden-stop crises, subsequently reducing the correlation of business cycles between currency area’s members, possibly ceasing the gains from membership in a currency union. A currency union of developing countries anchored to a leading global currency stabilizes inflation at a cost of inhibiting the use of monetary policy to deal with real and financial shocks. Currency unions with low financial depth and low financial integration of its members may be more stable at a cost of inhibiting the growth of sectors depending on bank funding.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Glick and Rose (2002) also supported this argument, finding a large impact on the growth of trade of a currency union among its members. Revisiting this issue, Glick and Rose (2015) found a more modest impact of the EMU on trade among its members and noted that switches and reversals across methodologies do not make allowances for any bold statements. Rose (2017) provides an update of the empirical evidence.

  2. Aizenmanet al. (2010) quantified the three-trilemma indexes for more than 170 countries during recent decades. The monetary independence index depends negatively on the correlation of a country’s interest rates with the base country’s interest rate, the exchange rate stability index depends negatively on exchange rate volatility, and the degree of financial integration is the Chinn-Ito capital controls index. For further details, see http://web.pdx.edu/~ito/trilemma_indexes.htm.

  3. Note that this argument holds only if the central bank of the country in question is credible and the sovereign issues debt that is denominated in the local currency. Clearly, these conditions would not hold for many countries, including those that experienced crises in the Eurozone.

  4. Among the fundamental factors of each of the individual crisis countries in the Eurozone was the build-up of external and internal debts -- whether public debt, or private debt. In these circumstances, the straight-jacket imposed by the Eurozone membership precludes country specific depreciations, magnifying recessionary forces during the adjustment.

  5. The GDP/capital growth rate decline during the GFC [2006 to 2008] was about 4% in Poland, which was half of the decline experienced by Germany and Spain. Remarkably, the public debt/GDP of Poland increased mildly from 45% in 2007 to 57% in 2013, while that of Spain almost tripled during that period, rising from 37% to 94%. The Zloty/Euro rate depreciated by 44% during the GFC [rising from 3.21 zloty/euro in 6/30/2008 to 4.64 zloty/euro in 2/1/2009], thus mitigating the recessionary impact of the crisis. These considerations are reflected in the attitude of Beata Szydlo, the new Polish Premier elected in 2015, who described the euro as a bad idea that would make Poland a “second Greece.” [Financial Times, “ECB alarmed at UK push to rebrand Union” 12/5/2015].

  6. The U.K.’s expansionary monetary policy induced the depreciation of the British pound by a third of its value (from 2.1 dollar/lb in Nov. 7, 2007, to 1.38 dollar/lb in January 22, 2009), thus facilitating a faster recovery. In contrast, Spain stagnated. The sharp increase in the sovereign spread of Spain in 2010 and 2011 and its stagnating growth implied that, despite entering the crisis with lower public debt/GDP than the U.K., Spain resumed anemic growth in 2014 with a sizably larger public debt/GDP than the U.K.

  7. Kazakhstan’s fixed exchange rate regime was one of the latest victims of the declining commodity prices, moving to a floating exchange rate in August 2015. Plummeting oil prices and devaluations by Russia and China increased exponentially the cost of defending the currency against the dollar. Azerbaijan followed Kazakhstan in moving to a floating currency in December 2015, after a devaluation of about 25% in February 2015. In both cases, growing exchange market pressure and declining international reserves induced exchange rate regime changes.

References

  • Aizenman J, Chinn MD, Ito H (2010) The emerging global financial architecture: Tracing and evaluating new patterns of the trilemma configuration. J Int Money Financ 29(4):615–641

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aizenman J, Chinn MD, Ito H (2011) Surfing the waves of globalization: Asia and financial globalization in the context of the trilemma. J Jap Int Econ 25.33:290–320 September

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aizenman J, Pinto B (2013) Managing Financial Integration and Capital Mobility—Policy lessons from the past two decades. Rev Int Econ 21(4):636–653

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aizenman J (2015) The Eurocrisis: Muddling through, or on the Way to a More Perfect Euro Union. Comp Econ Stud 57:205–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buiter W (1999) The EMU and the NAMU: What is the Case for North American Monetary Union? Can Publ Policy 25:285–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, Guillermo A., and Carmen M. Reinhart. "When capital inflows come to a sudden stop: consequences and policy options." (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  • De Grauwe, Paul, " The Governance of a Fragile Eurozone ," (2011), CEPS Working Documents, May

  • Frankel JA, Rose AK (1997) Is EMU more justifiable ex post than ex ante? Eur Econ Rev 41(3):753–760

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel JA, Rose AK (1998) The endogenity of the optimum currency area criteria. Econ J 108(449):1009–1025

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibson HD, Palivos T, Tavlas GS (2014) The crisis in the Euro area: an analytic overview. J Macroecon 39:233–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glick, Reuven and Andrew K. Rose. “Currency Unions and Trade: A Post-EMU Mea Culpa”, (2015), CEPR Discussion Paper 10615

  • Glick R, Rose AK (2002) Does a currency union affect trade? The time-series evidence. Eur Econ Rev 46(6):1125–1151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jonung, Lars, and Eoin Drea. "It can’t happen, it’s a bad idea, it won’t last: US economists on the EMU and the Euro, 1989–2002." Econ Journal Watch7.1 (2010): 4–52

  • Kenen P (1969) The Theory of Optimum Currency Areas: An Eclectic View. In: Mundell R, Swoboda A (eds) Monetary Problems in the International Economy. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (2012) Revenge of the optimum currency area. NBER Macroecon Annu 27(1):439–448

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mckinnon R (1963) Optimum Currency Areas. Am Econ Rev 53:717–725

    Google Scholar 

  • Mundell R (1961) A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas. Am Econ Rev 51:657–675

    Google Scholar 

  • Pisani-Ferry J (2013) The known unknowns and unknown unknowns of European Monetary Union. J Int Money Financ 34:6–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose AK (2017) Why do Estimates of the EMU Effect on Trade Vary so Much? Open Econ Rev 28(1, (2017)):1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I gratefully acknowledge the discussion and comments at the March 8-9 2016 ATI-IMF seminar on “The Future of Monetary Integration,” Mauritius, and the insightful comments of George Tavlas.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Joshua Aizenman.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Aizenman, J. Optimal Currency Area: A twentieth Century Idea for the twenty-first Century?. Open Econ Rev 29, 373–382 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-017-9455-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-017-9455-y

Keywords

Navigation