Skip to main content
Log in

A Measure of Trade Induced Adjustment in Volume and Quality Space

  • RESEARCH ARTICLE
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we contribute to the literature on the measurement of international trade flows. Specifically, we combine changes in the volume and quality in matched trade changes to present a simple new index together with a geometric framework that can be used to visualise changes in quality and volume simultaneously. We illustrate the usefulness of our simple extension with data for trade between Malaysia and China between 1994 and 2004.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Theoretically, Falvey (1981), Falvey and Kierzkowski (1985) and Flam and Helpman (1987) show that, even without increasing returns to scale, large numbers of firms will produce varieties of different quality. More recently, an empirical literature has developed to quantify the importance of product variety (see e.g. Hummels and Klenow 2005; Schott 2004; Broda and Weinstein 2006).

  2. The precise meaning of the SAH remains subject to differing interpretation although an excellent clarification of the three key components of the SAH, which are trade as an exogenous variable, adjustment costs and IIT, can be found in Brulhart et al. (2006). There is insufficient space to go into detail although simply put, “trade induced” adjustment refers to changes in the domestic market that can be traced back to changes in prices or volume relative to the rest of the world. See also Davidson and Matusz (2001, 2004) and Bacchetta and Jansen (2003) for recent assessments of trade-induced adjustment costs.

  3. Eicher (1996) discusses the relationship between human capital and technological change with higher technological innovation (improvements in quality) being associated with more skilled labour (skill-biased labour demand) and an increase in the relative wage of skilled to unskilled labour.

  4. Azhar et al. (2008) follow the three stage approach and investigate the robustness and sensitivity of the existing approaches to measuring VIIT and HIIT (Greenaway et al. 1999; Fontagné and Freudenberg 1997; Azhar and Elliott 2006) using data on the nature of trade flows between China and its East Asian neighbours.

  5. The premise for using UVs is that goods of a higher quality should demand a higher price (Stiglitz 1987). Thus, price can be considered an imperfect indicator of quality. Greenaway et al. (1994) and Aiginger (1997) provide discussion. Such comparisons however ignore the fact that that prices may also differ due to comparative advantage (Hallak and Schott 2005). Schott (2004) demonstrates that exporter skill and capital abundance are positively related to the within-product variation in export unit values. Unit values as a surrogate for price indices has also been criticised for being liable to measurement bias due to poor data quality and the mix of heterogenous items within product groupings (Silver 2007).

  6. Rodrik (2006) and Azhar et al. (2008) use UVs to compare the quality of Chinese exports with those from other East Asian countries while Schott (2006) compares Chinese export UVs within different product categories to the prices received by other US trading partners. See Hummels and Klenow (2005) for a general study looking at the relationship between the variety and quality of a nation’s exports and Funke and Ralf (2001) for an East Asian study of export variety and export performance.

  7. The choice of the 85% cut-off point is arbitrary but the choice is no different to the 15% or 25% cut-off used in previous measures. See Azhar and Elliott (2006) for a longer debate on this issue.

References

  • Aiginger K (1997) The use of unit values to discriminate between price and quality competition. Camb J Econ 21(5):571–592

    Google Scholar 

  • Abd-el-Rahman KS (1991) “Firms” Competitive and National Comparative Advantages as Joint Determinants of Trade Competition. Weltwirtsch Arch 127(1):83–97

    Google Scholar 

  • Azhar AKM, Elliott RJR (2003) On the measurement of trade induced adjustment. Weltwirtsch Arch 139:419–439

    Google Scholar 

  • Azhar AKM, Elliott RJR (2006) On the measurement of product quality in intra-industry trade. Weltwirtsch Arch 142(3):476–495

    Google Scholar 

  • Azhar AKM, Elliott RJR (2008) On the measurement of changes in product quality in marginal intra-industry trade. Weltwirtsch Arch 144(2):225–247

    Google Scholar 

  • Azhar AKM, Elliott RJR, Liu J (2008) On the measurement of product quality in intra-industry trade: an empirical test for China. China Econ Rev 19(2):336–344

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bacchetta M, Jansen M (2003) Adjusting to trade liberalisation: the role of policy, institutions and WTO disciplines, WTO Special Studies, No. 7. WTO, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • Balassa B (1966) Tariff reduction and trade in manufactures among industrial countries. Am Econ Rev 56(2):466–473

    Google Scholar 

  • Broda C, Weinstein D (2006) Globalization and the gains from variety. Q J Econ 121(2):541–585

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brülhart M (1994) Marginal intra-industry trade: measurement and relevance for the pattern of industrial adjustment. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 130:600–613

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brülhart M (2000) Dynamics of intra-industry trade and labour adjustment. Rev Int Econ 8(3):420–435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brülhart M, Elliott RJR (2002) Labour market effects of intra-industry trade: evidence for the United Kingdom. Weltwirtsch Arch 138(2):207–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brülhart M, Elliott RJR, Lindley JK (2006) Intra-industry trade and labour market adjustment: a reassessment using data on individual workers. Weltwirtsch Arch 142(3):521–545

    Google Scholar 

  • Cabral M, Silva J (2006) Intra-industry trade expansion and employment reallocation between sectors and occupations. Weltwirtsch Arch 146(3):496–520

    Google Scholar 

  • Cabral M, Falvey RE, Milner CR (2006) The skill content of inter- and intra-industry trade: evidence for the United Kingdom. Weltwirtsch Arch 142(3):546–566

    Google Scholar 

  • Cadot O, Faini R, de Melo J (1995) Early trade patterns under the europe agreements: France, Germany and Italy. Eur Econ Rev (Papers and Proceedings) 39:601–610

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davidson C, Matusz S (2001) On adjustment costs, GEP Research Paper 2001/24, University of Nottingham

  • Davidson C, Matusz S (2004) Should policy makers be concerned about adjustment costs? In: Mitra D, Panagariya A (eds) The political economy of trade, aid and foreign investment policies, Elsevier.

  • Dixon P, Menon J (1997) Intra-industry trade verses inter-industry trade: relevance for adjustment costs. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 133(1):146–169

    Google Scholar 

  • Egger H, Egger P, Greenaway D (2007) Intra-industry trade with multinational firms. Eur Econ Rev 51:1959–1984

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eicher TS (1996) Interaction between endogenous human capital and technological change. Rev Econ Stud 63:127–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elliott RJR, Lindley JK (2006) Trade, skills and adjustment costs: a study of intra-sectoral mobility. Rev Dev Econ 10(1):20–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elliott RJR, Greenaway DA, Hine RC (2000) Tests for factor homogeneity and industry classification. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 136(2):355–371

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erlat G, Erlat H (2003) Measuring intra-industry and marginal intra-industry trade: the case for Turkey. Emerg Market Finance Trade 39(6):5–38

    Google Scholar 

  • Falvey R (1981) Commercial policies and intra-industry trade. J Int Econ 11:495–511

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falvey R, Kierzkowski H (1985) Product quality, intra-industry trade and (Im)perfect competition. In: Kierzkowski H (ed) Protection and Competition in International Trade. Oxford, Blackwell

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferto I (2005) Vertically differentiated trade and differences in factor endowment: the case of agri-food products between Hungary and the EU. J Agric Econ 56(1):117–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferto I (2008) Dynamics of intra-industry trade and adjustment costs. The case of Hungarian food industry. Appl Econ Lett 15(5):379–384

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flam H, Helpman E (1987) Vertical product differentiation and north-south trade. Am Econ Rev 77:810–822

    Google Scholar 

  • Fontagné L, Freudenberg M (1997) Intra-industry trade: methodological issues reconsidered, CEPII working paper 97/02

  • Funke M, Ralf R (2001) Export variety and export performance: evidence from East Asia. J Asian Econ 12(4):493–505

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenaway D, Hine RC, Milner CR, Elliott RJR (1994) Adjustment and the measurement of marginal intra-industry trade. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 130:418–427

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenaway D, Hine RC, Milner CR (1995) Vertical and Horizontal Intra-Industry Trade: A Cross Industry Analysis for the United Kingdom. Econ J 105:1505–1519

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenaway D, Milner C, Elliott RJR (1999) UK Intra-Industry Trade with EU North and South. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 61:365–384

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenaway D, Haynes M, Milner C (2002) Adjustment, employment characteristics and intra-industry trade. Weltwirtsch Arch 138(2):254–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grubel H, Lloyd PJ (1975) Intra-industry Trade. London. Macmillan

  • Hallak JC, Schott P (2005) Estimating cross-country differences in product quality, mimeo, Yale University

  • Hamilton C, Kniest P (1991) Trade liberalisation, structural adjustment and intra-industry trade: a note. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 127:356–367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haynes M, Upward R, Wright P (2002) Estimating the wage costs of inter- and intra-sectoral adjustment. Weltwirtsch Arch 138(2):229–253

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hummels D, Klenow P (2005) The variety and quality of a nation’s exports. Am Econ Rev 95:704–723

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1981) Intraindustry specialization and the gains from trade. J Polit Econ 89:959–973

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menon J, Dixon P (1997) Intra-Industry Trade verses Inter-Industry Trade: Relevance for Adjustment Costs. Weltwirtsch Arch 133(1):146–169

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D (2006) What’s so special about China’s exports?, NBER Working Paper 11947, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Schott PK (2004) Across-product versus within-product specialization in international trade. Q J Econ 119(2):647–678

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schott PK (2006) The relative sophistication of Chinese exports, NBER Working paper 12173, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Silver M (2007) Do unit values export, import and terms of trade indices represent or misrepresent price indices, IMF Working Paper WP/07/21, International Monetary Fund

  • Stiglitz JE (1987) The causes and consequences of the dependence of quality on price. J Econ Lit 25:1–48

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

A.K.M. Azhar is grateful to the Malaysian Ministry of Science, Technology and Innovation for funding grant number 54322. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert James Ross Elliott.

Appendix

Appendix

In the appendix we briefly describe a possible weighting procedure. For example, if one believed that volume based adjustment costs are two or three times more severe that quality induced adjustment then appropriate weights could be applied. However, the chosen weights would be arbitrarily. One solution would be to weight the VQ index by estimating the following equation;

$$ \Delta em{p_{it}} = \alpha {S_{it}} + \beta M{Q_{it}} + \gamma {X_{it}} + {\varepsilon_{it}} $$

Where, Δempit is labour turnover in country i at the t, S it and MQ it are S and MQ indices respectively, X it is a vector of control variables, and ε it is the error term. The estimates of α and β would then tell us the effect of changes in volume and changes in quality based IIT on employment, which we can then use as the weights when calculating the VQ index. Dependent variables that have been considered include labour turnover (Brülhart 2000), occupational or sectoral labour movement (Greenaway et al. 2002; Brülhart et al. 2006) and sectoral movement (Elliott and Lindley 2006; Cabral and Silva 2006).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Azhar, A.K.M., Elliott, R.J.R. A Measure of Trade Induced Adjustment in Volume and Quality Space. Open Econ Rev 22, 955–968 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-010-9186-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-010-9186-9

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation