Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Optimal Debt? On the Insurance Value of International Debt Flows to Developing Countries

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

According to reputation models of sovereign debt, the incentives to repay are proportional to the income insurance benefits provided by the access to international markets. This paper, however, documents that private net lending to developing countries exhibits a procyclical or acyclical pattern, contradicting this premise. By contrast, official debt net flows exhibit a countercyclical patter. In addition, the paper shows that (both current and past) defaults are associated with lower net debt flows. The findings suggest that, while reputation models may explain the preferred creditor status enjoyed by official lenders, they cannot account for the presence of sovereign debt markets in developing countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Both the historical record on the workings of creditor clubs, and the evidence that defaulters are excluded from international capital markets tend to support this view.

  2. A related argument is made by Cole and Kehoe (1996), where the cost of default is due to negative externalities (e.g., the reputation costs on other relationships that cannot be readily insured). Guido…makes a similar argument, where these externalities are associated with the real impact of higher borrowing costs by private corporations as a result of the sovereign’s default.

  3. In this context, it is easy to see the distinction between willingness and ability to pay, since defaults are, by assumption, positively correlated with the latter. The more frequent case of a default during a recession calls for a more nuanced definition of those terms. We come back to this below.

  4. Trivially, the insurance view would entail a positive transfer in this case. As will be seen, due to the preferred creditor status of multilateral financial institutions, transfers are often negative even under default.

  5. In fact, borrowing costs may work in the context of a standard debt contract as a potential channel to distribute consumption between states, by borrowing more costly in bad times at the expense of a taller bill in good times.

  6. The Fund, built as an insurance mechanism against temporary balance of payment imbalances, should behave countercyclically.

  7. See Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996), chapter 6, for a discussion along these lines. Other characteristic of the original model, the fact that the supply of loans is bounded and upward sloping as the probability of default increases monotonically with debt service, is typically verified in practice.

  8. Official flows comprise four sub-categories: IMF lending, non-IMF multilateral lending (concessional and non-concessional), and bilateral lending. The last three sub-categories behave in line with aggregate non-IMF official flows and, for the sake of brevity, are not reported in the tables (the results are available from the author on request).

  9. Variable definitions and sources are detailed in Appendix.

  10. Results using the HP-filtered gap are reported in Levy Yeyati (2006). While results are not significantly altered when zero-flow countries are not excluded, failing to do so may introduce an important bias in the coefficients when a large fraction of countries do not have access to a specific flow type, as is the case for bonded debt.

  11. It needs to be noted, however, that bonded debt ratios within this group are highly diverse, with very small numbers but for a few emerging economies that have only recently gained access to international capital markets. I come back to this point in the robustness section below.

  12. Possible explanations include the incidence of consessional loans as last resort lending in low income economies, and the growing participation of multilateral agencies in IMF-led rescue packages.

  13. As the timing of defaults and their financial effects is sometimes controversial, I prefer to use last year as the cutoff date between what is considered past and current defaults to avoid associating immediate effects to reputation aspects. However, tests controlling using the current year as cutoff date yield similar results.

  14. See Lindert and Morton (1989), Ozler (1993), and Flandreau and Zumer (2004) for earlier defaults, and Ades et al. (2000) and Dell’Ariccia et al. (2002) for the emerging market experience.

  15. See, among others, Calvo et al. (2003) and Edwards (2005) for evidence on the link between capital account reversals and economic performance, and Gavin and Perotti (1997) for an early account on the asymmetric behavior of capital flows, where sudden reversal are sharper and more procyclical than inflows.

  16. For all the tests reported in the paper, similar results are obtained when the cycle is computed based on the HP-filtered trend. These results, omitted here for brevity, are available on request.

  17. By contrast, private bank flows in the 90s played a minor relative to bonded debt (for emerging economies) and official lending (for non-emerging economies).

  18. See Rodrik (1995) and Morris and Shin (2006).

  19. See, among others, Cowan et al. (2006).

  20. See Hausmann and Fernández Arias (2000).

  21. This simply confirms results reported by Borensztein et al. (2007).

References

  • Ades A, Kaune F, Leme P, Masih R, Tenengauzer D (2000) Introducing GS-ESS: a new framework for assessing fair value in emerging markets hard-currency debt. Goldman Sachs Global Economics Website.

  • Amador M (2003) A Political Model of Sovereign Debt Repayment. Stanford University, mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton P, Freixas X (2000) Equity, bonds and bank debt: capital structure and financial market equilibrium under asymmetric information. J Polit Econ 2(108):324–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borensztein E, Levy Yeyati E, Panizza U (2007) Living with Debt: How to Limit the Risks of Sovereign Finance, Harvard University Press.

  • Bulow J, Shoven J (1978) The Bankruptcy decision. Bell Journal of Economics 437–456

  • Bulow J, Rogoff K (1989) A constant recontracting model of sovereign debt. J Polit Econ 97(1):155–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo G, Izquierdo A, Talvi E (2003) Sudden stops, the real exchange rate, and fiscal sustainability: Argentina’s lessons. NBER Working Papers 9828

  • Cole H, Kehoe T (1996) A self-fulfilling model of Mexico’s 1994–1995 debt crisis. J Int Econ 41(3–4):309–330

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowan K, Levy Yeyati E, Panizza U, Sturzenegger F (2006) Public debt in the Americas: new data and stylized facts. IADB Working Paper No. 577

  • Dell’Ariccia G, Schnabel I, Zettelmeyer J (2002) Moral hazard and international crisis lending: a test. IMF Working Paper No 02/181

  • Eaton J, Gersovitz M (1981) Debt with potential repudiation: theoretical and empirical analysis. Review of Economic Studies, Blackwell Publishing 48(2):289–309

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards S (2005) Capital controls, sudden stops and current account reversals. NBER Working Papers 11170

  • Flandreau M, Zumer F (2004) The making of global finance 1880–1913. OECD, Development Center, Paris, p 144

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gavin M, Perotti R (1997) Fiscal policy in Latin America. NBER macroeconomics annual 1997.

  • GDF (2006) Global Development Finance. The World Bank.

  • Hausmann R, Fernandez-Arias E (2000) Foreign direct investment: good cholesterol? IADB, Research Department Working Paper No. 417

  • Kletzer K, Wright B (2000) Sovereign debt as intertemporal barter. Am Econ Rev 90(3):621–639

    Google Scholar 

  • Levy Yeyati E (2006) Optimal debt? On the insurance value of international debt flows to developing countries. Inter-American Development Bank Working Paper No. 574

  • Lindert P, Morton P (1989) How sovereign debt has worked. In: Sachs, Jerey D. (eds) Developing country debt and economic performance, vol 1. The international financial system. National Bureau of Economic Research Project Report series Chicago and London, University of Chicago Press, pp 39–106

  • Morris S, Shin, HS (2006) Catalytic finance: When does it work? Elsevier. J Int Econ 70(1):161–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld M, Rogoff K (1996) Foundations of International Economics. MIT Press.

  • Ozler S (1993) Have commercial banks ignored history? Am Econ Rev, American Economic Association 83(3):608–620

    Google Scholar 

  • Rochet JC (2006) Sovereign debt: Why do countries borrow so much? IDEI-Université Toulouse I, mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D (1995) Why is there Multilateral Lending? NBER Working Papers 5160, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

  • WEO (2006) World Economic Outlook. International Monetary Fund

  • Wright M (2001) Reputations and sovereign debt. MIT, Cambridge, Massachusetts

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author wishes to thank Jorge Morgenstern for excellent research assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Eduardo Levy Yeyati.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 11 Variable definition and sources
Table 12 List of countries

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Levy Yeyati, E. Optimal Debt? On the Insurance Value of International Debt Flows to Developing Countries. Open Econ Rev 20, 489–507 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-008-9086-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-008-9086-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation