Skip to main content
Log in

International Saving, Investment and Trade

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Feldstein and Horioka (Econ J 90:314–329, 1980) observed that saving and investment move closely together in the major OECD countries. This finding is a puzzle if national economies are characterized by one sector neoclassical production functions—with diminishing returns to capital, a high level of savings in a country should create an incentive to export capital. In this paper, we show that this incentive disappears in the presence of multiple sectors with differing capital intensities. In a high saving country, national capital can be absorbed domestically without a decline in its marginal product through a shift in the sectoral composition of national production towards capital intensive sectors. This is nothing but the well-known Rybczynski effect. We present a modified version of the standard Heckscher–Ohlin (HO) Model to show that very small barriers to capital mobility are enough to force national savings to stay within the country of origin. We also argue that, while the assumptions of this model may appear special, they are not unrealistic for the developed countries in the Feldstein Horioka study. Some historical economic trends are also consistent with the picture presented in this paper. Finally, the paper shows that the conventional insights from the one sector neoclassical model can be completely overturned in a multi-sector setting when technological differences are introduced.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Well-known surveys of the literature are Tesar (1993), Mussa and Goldstein (1993) and Obstfeld (1986,1994). A more recent, good survey is Hericourt and Maurel (2005).

  2. This paper addresses the FH puzzle only, and does not focus on the separate puzzles of ‘consumption correlation’ or ‘portfolio home bias’ that Obstfeld and Rogoff (2000) consider. The lack of portfolio diversification and consumption correlation are puzzles because they conflict with the desire to diversify risk. The FH observation is primarily a puzzle because it conflicts with the diminishing returns to capital associated with a neoclassical production function.

  3. At the heart of Feldstein and Horioka’s analysis is a simple cross-country regression of the following form:

    $$\left( {{I \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {I Y}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} Y}} \right)_{\text{i}} = \alpha + \beta \left( {{S \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {S Y}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} Y}} \right)_i + \varepsilon _i ,\left( {{I \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {I Y}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} Y}} \right)_{\text{i}} = \alpha + \beta \left( {{S \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {S Y}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} Y}} \right)_i + \varepsilon _i ,$$

    where S/Y is the gross domestic savings rate, and I/Y the gross domestic investment rate. The slope coefficient was estimated 0.887 (S.E. 0.07).

  4. The explanation provided here does not address the question posed by Lucas (1990) why capital was not flowing from rich to poor countries. As a matter of fact, as Debaere and Demiroglu (2003) shows, the sectoral variation in factor intensities is not large enough to absorb the huge differences in factor endowments between developed and developing countries. Therefore, see also Sections 2 and 3, developed and developing countries cannot produce the same set of goods (there is complete specialization of production) and we are back to the analysis of one-sector production functions mentioned above and hence back to Lucas’ original question: Why is it that with much more labor per unit of capital that developing countries do not attract more capital flows?

  5. For example, a possible explanation for a changing D could be a change in the perceived exchange rate risk, or even a changing balance between trade restrictions and those on factor movements.

  6. As we know from the Stolper–Samuelson Theorem, factor prices are determined by goods prices. If the country under consideration is large, the shift in the country’s production towards capital intensive sectors may change the world relative prices of goods. Consequently, the factor prices may change worldwide as a result of the capital accumulation in that single country. However, the changes in goods prices will prevail across the world because of trade. As a result, the factor prices implied by these goods prices will be the same in all the countries also. In the two-by-two model, if, for instance, there is a decline in the price of the capital intensive good, the rental rate of capital declines everywhere in the world. The FPE Theorem assures that the returns to capital will still be identical across countries and there will be no incentive for capital flows as before.

  7. In a footnote Obstfeld (1986) refers to Kotlikoff (1984) who briefly mentions a conversation in which the possible relevance of the FPE result to the FH puzzle is brought up. The explanation is not pursued by either of the authors, possibly because it is thought of as an intellectual curiosity, rather than an issue that may have actual pertinence to reality. Ventura (1997) who develops a dynamic Heckscher–Ohlin model also mentions FPE as a possible explanation for the FH puzzle in a footnote.

  8. In case the endowments are so different that they do not lie inside the diversification cone, the two countries cannot produce the same set of goods and FPE will not materialize.

  9. Alternatively, good 1 could also be chosen as the investment good, and that would not make any difference in the model.

  10. This may seem a short-sighted criterion for foreign investment as the capital gains or losses that may accrue due to the change in the price of the capital good should also play a role in the decision process. But, in this model, the capital good is good 1, and its price is the same in both countries due to free trade. Hence, capital gains or losses are the same in both countries.

  11. As mentioned in the introduction, D prevents indeterminacy. Without D, any allocation of world investment across countries is an equilibrium. With any positive D, no matter how small, S = I and S* = I* are the unique equilibrium outcome whenever FPE holds.

  12. See also Schott (2003).

  13. These existing capital flows may reflect aid or funds from the IMF and the World Bank rather than private capital looking for higher gains. Nevertheless, they are consistent with the analysis of the endowments mentioned above. Another point one can raise is that the existence of net capital inflows to LDCs implies that there should be corresponding net capital outflows from developed countries. However, the size of LDC economies is small compared to output of developed economies. Thus, capital flows that are significant for the LDC economies are relatively insignificant for the developed countries.

  14. Even if we assumed identical-homothetic preferences, the HOV prediction would not likely be true in the model of Section 2. Our high saving country has a higher investment rate and thus absorbs more of the capital intensive good. As such, the capital abundant country may well be a net importer of capital.

  15. The identical technology assumption is only needed for FPE and not for the Rybczynski and Stolper–Samuelson Theorems. The latter two theorems are still operational in this section.

  16. In our model, capital is mobile with no essential barriers to its movements (the required premium D is assumed to be arbitrarily small). Thus, r = r* is a reasonable starting point, as previous capital movements would have eliminated the return differentials if they existed. In this section we try to obtain the equality in the future period\(\left( {r_ + = r_ + ^ * } \right)\) without resorting to any further capital movements.

  17. The rental price of capital and the goods prices the producers face are the same in both countries, but foreign firms have inferior technology. This disadvantage for the foreign firms is offset by lower wages.

  18. One might argue that capital movements will yield the initial equality of returns to capital in the 2 × 2 × 2 case with technological differences, yet that they are also likely to lead to specialization in the production of one good in one of the countries. This specialization would make the comovements of the returns to capital impossible. On the other hand, with many goods, complete specialization is less likely. That is why we consider the case of diversification in our 2 × 2 × 2 analysis. (As for the comovements of factor returns, the correlation version of the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem (Deardorff and Stern 1995) is applicable to the case of multiple goods.)

References

  • Blanchard O, Giavazzi F (2002) Current account deficits in the Euro Area: the end of the Feldstein–Horioka puzzle? Brookings Pap Econ Act 2:147–209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deardorff AV (1994) The possibility of factor price equalization, revisited. J Int Econ 36:167–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deardorff AV, Stern RM (1995) The Stolper Samuelson theorem: a golden jubilee. The University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Debaere P, Demiroglu U (2003) On the similarity of country endowments. J Int Econ 59:101–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dooley M, Frankel J, Mathieson D (1987) International capital mobility: what do saving-investment correlations tell us? IMF staff papers, September

  • Ethier W (1984) Higher dimensional issues in trade theory. In: Jones R, Kenen P (eds) Handbook of international economics, international trade, Vol. I. Elsevier, New York, pp 131–184

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein H, Horioka C (1980) Domestic saving and international capital flows. Econ J 90:314–329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hericourt J, Maurel M (2005) The Feldstein–Horioka revisited: an “European Regional” Perspective, Working paper.

  • Kotlikoff LJ (1984) Taxation and savings: a neoclassical perspective. J Econ Lit 22:1576–1629

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1993) What do we need to know about the international monetary system? Essays in International Finance, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Leamer E, Levinsohn J (1995) International trade theory: the evidence. In: Grossman G, Rogoff K (eds) Handbook of international economics, III. Elsevier, New York, pp 1339–1394

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas R (1990) Why doesn’t capital flow from rich to poor countries? Am Econ Rev 80:92–96

    Google Scholar 

  • Montiel PJ (1994) Capital mobility in developing countries: some measurement issues and empirical estimates. World Bank Econ Rev 8:311–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mundell RA (1957) International trade and factor mobility. Am Econ Rev 47:321–335

    Google Scholar 

  • Mussa M, Goldstein M (1993) The integration of world capital markets. In: Changing capital markets: implications for monetary policy, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, pp 245–313

  • Obstfeld M (1986) Capital mobility in the world economy: theory and measurement. Carnegie–Rochester Conf Ser Public Policy 24:55–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld M (1994) International capital mobility in the 1990s. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, International Discussion Paper, 472

  • Obstfeld M, Rogoff K (1996) Foundations of international macroeconomics. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld M, Rogoff K (2000) The six major puzzles in international macroeconoics: is there a common cause? In: Bernanke B, Rogoff K (eds) NBER macroeconomics annual. NBER, Massachusetts

    Google Scholar 

  • Schott P (2003) One size fits all? Heckscher–Ohlin specialization in global production. Am Econ Rev 93(2):686–708

    Google Scholar 

  • Tesar L (1993) Savings, investment and international capital flows. J Int Econ 31:55–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trefler D (1995) The case of missing trade and other mysteries. Am Econ Rev 85:1029–1046

    Google Scholar 

  • Ventura J (1997) Growth and interdependence. Q J Econ 112(1):57–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Peter Debaere.

Additional information

Peter Debaere is at the Darden School of Business, University of Virginia, DebaereP@darden.virginia.edu, Ufuk Demiroglu is at the Congressional Budget Office in Washington DC, UfukD@cbo.gov. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and should not be interpreted as being those of the Congressional Budget Office. The first version of this paper appeared as RSIE working paper 406. We thank Casper de Vries and a referee for helpful suggestions. All remaining errors are ours.

Appendix

Appendix

The following proposition states that, starting from a situation with identical returns to capital in the two countries, the change in r is the same in response to a change in prices in the case of Cobb–Douglas production functions with multiplicative technological differences.

Proposition

Suppose that r=r*, and the production functions in each sector of the home and foreign country are, respectively,

$$ F_{{i\,}} {\left( {K_{i} ,L_{i} } \right)} = A_{i} K^{{\alpha _{1} }}_{i} L^{{1 - \alpha _{1} }}_{i} \;{\text{and}}\;F^{*}_{i} {\left( {K_{i} ,L_{i} } \right)} = A^{*}_{i} K^{{\alpha _{1} }}_{i} L^{{1 - \alpha _{1} }}_{i} $$
(4)

where i=1, 2 is the index for the sectors. Then \( {\vartheta r} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\vartheta r} {\vartheta p_{2} = {\vartheta r^{ * } } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\vartheta r^{ * } } {\vartheta p_{2} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\vartheta p_{2} }}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\vartheta p_{2} = {\vartheta r^{ * } } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\vartheta r^{ * } } {\vartheta p_{2} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\vartheta p_{2} }} \).

Proof

For a given price p i and factor prices w and r, the revenue function is \( p_{i} A_{i} K^{{\alpha _{i} }}_{i} L^{{1 - \alpha _{i} }}_{i} \) and the profit function in sector i can be written as \( \pi _{i} {\left( {K_{i} ,L_{i} } \right)} = p_{i} A_{i} K^{{\alpha _{i} }}_{i} L^{{1 - \alpha _{i} }}_{i} - wL_{i} - rK_{i} \). Maximization of π i (K i , L i ) with respect to K i and L i yields

$$ K_{i} = \frac{{\alpha _{i} }} {{1 - \alpha _{i} }}\frac{w} {r}L_{i} . $$
(5)

With perfect competition and constant returns to scale production functions, profits will be zero in the equilibrium, i.e., π i (K i , L i )=0. Substituting Eq. 5 in π i (K i , L i )=0 and solving for w, we obtain

$$ w = {\left( {1 - \alpha _{i} } \right)}\alpha ^{{\frac{{\alpha _{i} }} {{1 - \alpha _{i} }}}}_{i} {\left(\kern1.5pt {p_{i} A_{i} } \right)}^{{\frac{{1}} {{1 - \alpha _{i} }}}} r^{{ \kern1pt- \kern1pt\frac{{\alpha _{i} }} {{1 - \alpha _{i} }}}} . $$
(6)

Equation 6 will hold for both of the sectors, i=1, 2, with the same w and r:

$$ w = {\left( {1 - \alpha _{1} } \right)}\alpha _{1} ^{{\frac{{\alpha _{1} }} {{1 - \alpha _{1} }}}} {\left(\kern1.5pt {p_{1} A_{1} } \right)}^{{\frac{{1 }} {{1 - \alpha _{1} }}}} r^{{ \kern1pt-\kern1pt \frac{{\alpha _{1} }} {{1 - \alpha _{1} }}}} ,\;{\text{and}}\;w = {\left( {1 - \alpha _{2} } \right)}\alpha _{2} ^{{\frac{{\alpha _{1} }} {{1 - \alpha _{2} }}}} {\left(\kern1.5pt {p_{2} A_{2} } \right)}^{{\frac{{1 }} {{1 - \alpha _{2} }}}} r^{{ \kern1pt-\kern1pt \frac{{\alpha _{2} }} {{1 - \alpha _{2} }}}} . $$
(7)

Using the pair of Eq. 6, one can solve for r as

$$r = {c{\left( {p_{2} A_{2} } \right)}^{{\beta _{2} }} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{c{\left( {p_{2} A_{2} } \right)}^{{\beta _{2} }} } {{\left( {p_{1} A_{1} } \right)}}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {{\left( {p_{1} A_{1} } \right)}}^{{\beta _{1} }} ,$$
(8)

where \({\left( {{\text{letting}}\,\,\gamma = {\left( {\frac{{\alpha _{2} }}{{1 - \alpha _{2} }} - \frac{{\alpha _{1} }}{{1 - \alpha _{1} }}} \right)}} \right)}\) \( \beta _{i} = {\left[ {\gamma {\left( {1 - \alpha _{i} } \right)}} \right]}^{{ - 1}} \), i=1, 2, and \( c = \frac{{\alpha ^{{\alpha _{2} \beta _{2} }}_{2} }} {{\alpha ^{{\alpha _{1} \beta _{1} }}_{1} }}{\left( {\frac{{1 - \alpha _{2} }} {{1 - \alpha _{1} }}} \right)}^{{\frac{1} {\gamma }}} \). Without loss of generality, consider a change in p 2, From Eq. 8, the partial response of r is

$$ \frac{{\partial r}} {{\partial p_{2} }} = c\frac{{\beta _{2} p_{2} ^{{\beta _{2} - 1}} A_{2} ^{{\beta _{2} }} }} {{p^{{\beta _{1} }}_{1} A^{{\beta _{1} }}_{1} }} $$
(9)

Similarly, for the foreign country, we have

$$ r^* = {c{\left(\kern1.5pt {p_{2} A^{*}_{2} } \right)}^{{\beta _{2} }} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{c{\left( {p_{2} A^{*}_{2} } \right)}^{{\beta _{2} }} } {{\left( {p_{1} A^{*}_{1} } \right)}^{{\beta _{1} }} }}} \right. } {{\left(\kern1.5pt {p_{1} A^{*}_{1} } \right)}^{{\beta _{1} }} }, $$
(10)

and

$$ \frac{{\partial r^*}} {{\partial p_{2} }} = c\frac{{\beta _{2} p_{2} ^{{\beta _{2} - 1}} A^{{*\beta _{2} }}_{2} }} {{p^{{\beta _{1} }}_{1} A^{{*\beta _{1} }}_{1} }}. $$
(11)

Since r=r* initially, we equate the right hand sides of Eqs. 8 and 10. That yields

$$ \frac{{A^{{\beta _{2} }}_{2} }} {{A^{{\beta _{1} }}_{1} }} = \frac{{A^{{*\beta _{2} }}_{2} }} {{A^{{*\beta _{1} }}_{1} }}. $$
(12)

Finally, Eqs. 9, 11 and 12 imply that \( {\partial r} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\vartheta r} {\vartheta p_{2} = {\vartheta r^{ * } } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\vartheta r^{ * } } {\vartheta p_{2} }}} \right. } {\vartheta p_{2} }}}} \right. } {\partial p_{2} = {\partial r^{ * } } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\vartheta r^{ * } } {\vartheta p_{2} }}} \right. } {\partial p_{2} }} \). □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Debaere, P., Demiroglu, U. International Saving, Investment and Trade. Open Econ Rev 19, 613–627 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-007-9072-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-007-9072-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation