Skip to main content
Log in

Openness and Real Exchange Rate Volatility: In Search of an Explanation

  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The puzzle that real exchange rates are less volatile in open economies is an important challenge to exchange rate theory. Adjustment of domestic prices to nominal exchange rate movements can account for only a small proportion of this effect. Real and nominal shocks display no obvious correlation with openness. It is shown here that real effective exchange rates are more strongly mean-reverting in more open economies, even after controlling for exchange rate regime effects. This is predicted by the theory of current account sustainability, because of its emphasis on ratios to GDP rather than to trade flows.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Greece and Portugal are omitted for this reason.

  2. This is a crude measure, but business cycle models routinely predict that the amplitude of cycles will increase with the magnitude of shocks.

References

  • Bénassy-Quéré A, Duran-Vigneron P, Lahrèche-Révil A, Mignon V (2004) Burden sharing and misalignments within the group of twenty. In: Bergsten CF, Williamson J (eds) Dollar adjustment: how far? Against what? Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergsten CF, Williamson J (eds) (2004) Dollar adjustment: how far? Against what? Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Bleaney M (1992) Comparing real exchange rate volatility across exchange rate systems. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 54:557–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheung Y-W, Lai KS, Bergman M (2004) Dissecting the PPP puzzle: the unconventional roles of nominal exchange rate and price adjustments. J Int Econ 64:135–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cline W (2005) The United States as a debtor nation. Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Devereux MB, Lane P (2003) Understanding bilateral exchange rate volatility. J Int Econ 60:109–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel C, West KD (2005) Exchange rates and fundamentals. J Pol Econ 113:485–517

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel J, Froot K (1986a) The dollar as a speculative bubble: a tale of fundamentalists and chartists. Working paper no. 1854. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA

  • Frankel J, Froot K (1986b) Understanding the US dollar in the eighties: the expectations of fundamentalists and chartists. Econ Rec December:24–38

  • Hau H (2002) Real exchange rate volatility and economic openness: theory and evidence. J Money Credit Bank 34:611–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann R, Panizza U, Rigobon R (2004) The long-run volatility puzzle of the real exchange rate. Working paper no. 10751. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA

  • Jeanne O, Rose A (2002) Noise trading and exchange rate regimes. Q J Econ 117:537–570

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kubelec C (2004) Intervention when exchange rate misalignments are large. In: Bergsten CF, Williamson J (eds) Dollar adjustment: how far? Against what? Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Mann C (1999) Is the U.S. trade deficit sustainable? Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • McKinnon R (1961) Optimum currency areas. Am Econ Rev 51:657–665

    Google Scholar 

  • Mussa M (2004) Exchange rate adjustments needed to reduce global payments imbalances. In: Bergsten CF, Williamson J (eds) Dollar adjustment: how far? Against what? Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Wren-Lewis S, Driver R (1998) Real exchange rates for the year 2000. Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

The author wishes to thank Liliana Castilleja Vargas for excellent research assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael Bleaney.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A theoretical model

In this Appendix, we explore the idea that volatility is related to the strength of signals of misalignment at a given deviation from equilibrium, based on the model of Frankel and Froot (1986a, b).

In Frankel and Froot’s model, the foreign exchange market is populated by “fundamentalists” and “chartists”, who supply exchange-rate forecasts to portfolio managers (see Jeanne and Rose 2002, and Kubelec 2004, for similar models). The log of the exchange rate (foreign currency units per unit of domestic currency) at time t is denoted s t. Portfolio managers are the only agents active in the foreign exchange market, and generate their own forecasts as a weighted average of the two groups of forecasters. Chartists believe that exchange rates are non-stationary and use some ARIMA (p, 1, q) model to generate forecasts. Fundamentalists believe that exchange rates will revert to equilibrium at some predetermined rate, but it is realistic to assume that they are not certain what the equilibrium is, since even estimates by economists have quite wide confidence intervals (Bénassy-Quéré et al. 2004; Wren-Lewis and Driver 1998). Suppose that fundamentalist j believes at time t that the equilibrium is \(\overline{s} _{{jt}} ,\) and let the mean of these beliefs across all fundamentalists be \( \overline{s} _{t} \) (it is at this point that the model diverges from that of Frankel and Froot (1986a, b), who assume that \( \overline{s} \) is known but that w varies according to the past forecasting performance of the two groups). The log of the exchange rate as forecast at time t by the chartists, fundamentalists and portfolio managers are respectively \(s^{c}_{{t + 1}} ,\) \( s^{f}_{{t + 1}} \) and \(s^{m}_{{t + 1}} .\) Then we have

$$ s^{m}_{{t + 1}} = ws^{f}_{{t + 1}} + {\left( {1 - w} \right)}s^{c}_{{t + 1}} $$
(2)
$$ s^{f}_{{t + 1}} = s_{t} + \mu {\int\limits_{j = 0}^1 {{\left( {\overline{s} _{{jt}} - s_{t} } \right)}} }\,dj = \mu \overline{s} _{t} + {\left( {1 - \mu } \right)}s_{t} $$
(3)

Equation 2 expresses portfolio managers’ forecasts as a weighted average of those of fundamentalists and chartists, and Eq. 3 represents fundamentalists’ average forecast as a constant rate of mean reversion to the average of their beliefs about the equilibrium rate. As in Frankel and Froot (1986a) and Engel and West (2005), the actual exchange rate is determined in a generic way consistent with a wide range of models, as the sum of the fundamentals (z) and a term based on the expected level of the exchange rate:

$$ s_{t} = as^{m}_{{t + 1}} + z_{t} $$
(4)

Substituting from Eqs. 2 and 3 and rearranging yields:

$$ s_{t} = \frac{{a{\left( {1 - w} \right)}s^{c}_{{t + 1}} + aw\mu \overline{s} _{t} + z_{t} }} {{1 - aw{\left( {1 - \mu } \right)}}} $$
(5)

Equation 5 says that the exchange rate is a linear combination of (a) the fundamentals, (b) chartists’ forecasts, and (c) fundamentalists’ beliefs about the equilibrium. Note that, if fundamentalists believe the rate of mean-reversion to be faster (μ is larger), the exchange rate will be closer to its equilibrium value.

If we assume that chartists’ forecasts are uncorrelated with the fundamentals or with fundamentalists’ estimates of the equilibrium, then

$$ \operatorname{var} {\left( s \right)} = \frac{{{\left( {a{\left( {1 - w} \right)}} \right)}^{2} \operatorname{var} {\left( {s^{c} } \right)} + {\left( {aw\mu } \right)}^{2} \operatorname{var} {\left( {\overline{s} } \right)} + 2aw\mu \operatorname{cov} {\left( {\overline{s} ,z} \right)} + \operatorname{var} {\left( z \right)}}} {{{\left( {1 - aw{\left( {1 - \mu } \right)}} \right)}^{2} }} $$
(6)

Both the numerator and the denominator of Eq. 6 are increasing in μ. Because chartists’ forecasts are not tied down by the fundamentals, it is likely that var\({\left( {\overline{s} } \right)}\) and var(z) are small compared with var(s c). In that case, provided that w is not too close to one (i.e. chartists matter), var(s) will be decreasing in μ. In other words if fundamentalists believe that mean-reversion is stronger, the real exchange rate will be less volatile.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bleaney, M. Openness and Real Exchange Rate Volatility: In Search of an Explanation. Open Econ Rev 19, 135–146 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-007-9054-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-007-9054-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation