Skip to main content
Log in

Effects of Tariffication: Tariffs and Quotas under Monopolistic Competition

  • Research article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Recent rounds of GATT and later WTO have advocated widespread tariffication, meaning that existing non-tariff barriers be converted into import equivalent tariffs. From an economic point of view, the effects of such tariffication are not entirely clear. The paper presents a trade model with monopolistic competition to examine the welfare effects of tariffication. The ranking of pre- and post-tariffication welfare crucially depends on the nature of the initial trade barrier and the tariff tool applied. Tariffication using a specific (ad valorem) tariff results in the same (reduced) welfare level compared to an initial sold quota, whereas welfare is increased (the same) compared to an initial shared quota.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The allocation schemes of quantitative restrictions are important parameters of trade policy, see e.g. Dinopoulos and Kreinin (1992), Krishna (1993), Konishi (1999) and Gervais and Surprenant (2000). The present classification into sold versus shared quotas is discussed below.

  2. Article 4, Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture. The footnote to this article explains: ‘These measures include quantitative import restrictions, variable import levies, minimum import prices, discretionary import licensing, non-tariff measures maintained through state-trading enterprises, voluntary export restraints, ...’. Note, that even though tariffication is explicitly evoked only in the Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture, it is a universal concept that is implicit at the foundation of various regional or global trade liberalization and economic integration efforts.

  3. This reflects the underlying idea of the tariffication process in the Uruguay Round where ’... for each tariff line the whole range of protective measures (including the existing tariff) is replaced by a single new tariff that is estimated to provide substantially the same level of protection as the existing measures’ (see WTO 2003, section on Tariffication)

  4. After the conclusions of the Uruguay Round, Ingco (1995, p. 2) states that ’Most countries, particular in OECD, converted their NTBs into specific tariffs, preventing an easy assessment of protection rates.’

  5. The role of the allocation schemes of quantitative restrictions has been receiving increasing attention, see e.g. Dinopoulos and Kreinin (1992), Krishna (1993), Gervais and Surprenant (2000). The present contrast between sold and shared quotas can be related to Konishi (1999), who examines welfare differences between tariffs and quotas, while maintaining a separation into constraint and free entry. Similarly, constraint and free entry are the prime drivers of our present distinction between sold and shared quotas. However, in Konishi (1999) – apart from being placed in a very different model, namely a Cournot oligopoly with strategic investment—the entry/exit effect is confined to the home market, while we focus on the entry/exit effect embedded in the quota scheme and occurring in the foreign country, i.e. the restricted country.

  6. A new branch of international trade literature with additional export costs and firm heterogeneity with respect to marginal costs or export costs has recently emerged (see Melitz 2003 or Schmitt and Yu 2001). The present paper does not take this issue into account as we assume that fixed and variable costs are identical across variants.

  7. Due to symmetry it is in effect inessential which country does administer the quota and where the quota rent occurs. What is important, however, is that the property rights to the quota ensure that the quota can and will be sold.

  8. This is a finding in line with Gros (1987).

  9. This is in line with findings that e.g. Lockwood and Wong (2000) and Kowalczyk and Skeath (1994) have made in settings of monopoly and oligopoly; on this see also Schröder (2004) and Jørgensen and Schröder (2005).

References

  • Anderson J (1988) The relative inefficiency of quotas. MIT, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati J (1965) On the equivalence of tariffs and quotas. In: Baldwin R et al (eds) Trade, growth and the balance of payments. Rand McNally, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Collie DR, Su Y (1998) Trade policy and product variety: when is a VER superior to a tariff? J Dev Econ 55:249–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Das S, Donnenfeld S (1987) Trade policy and its impact on quality of imports: a welfare analysis. J Int Econ 23:77–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delipalla S, Keen M (1992) The comparison between ad valorem and specific taxation under imperfect competition. J Public Econ 49(3):351–367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dinopoulos E, Kreinin ME (1992) Alternative quota and ver allocation schemes—a welfare comparison. Economica 59:337–349

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gervais JP, Surprenant D (2000) An economic investigation of the import licensing methods and TRQs in agriculture. Can J Agric Econ 48(4):397–410

    Google Scholar 

  • Gros D (1987) Protectionism in a framework with intra-industry trade: tariffs, quotas, retaliation, and welfare losses. IMF Staff Pap 34(1):86–114

    Google Scholar 

  • Helpman E, Krugman P (1989) Trade policy and market structure. MIT, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Ingco M (1995) Agricultural trade liberalization in the Uruguay round—one step forward, one step back? The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 1500

  • Ingco M (1996) Tariffication in the uruguay round: how much liberalisation? World Econ 19(4):425–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jørgensen JG, Schröder PJH (2005) Welfare ranking ad valorem and specific tariffs under monopolistic competition. Can J Econ 38(1):228–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaempfer W, Marks S (1994) The possibility of inefficient liberalisation through tariffication. Rev Int Econ 2(2):123–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konishi H (1999) Tariffs versus quotas with strategic investment. Can J Econ 32(1):71–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kowalczyk C, Skeath SE (1994) Pareto ranking optimal tariffs under foreign monopoly. Econ Lett 45:355–359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishna K (1993) Theoretical implications of imperfect competition on quota license prices and auctions. World Bank Econ Rev 7(1):113–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1980) Scale economies, product differentiation, and the pattern of trade. Am Econ Rev 70(5):950–959

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1981) Intraindustry specialisation and the gains from trade. J Polit Econ 89(5):959–973

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lawrence R (1989) Protection: is there a better way? Am Econ Rev 79(2):118–126

    Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood B, Wong K-Y (2000) Specific and ad valorem tariffs are not equivalent in trade wars. J Int Econ 52:183–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCorrison S, Sheldon IM (1991) Intra-industry trade and specialization in processed agricultural products: the case of the US and the EC. Rev Agric Econ 13(2):173–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz Marc J (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6):1695–1725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nguyen T, Perroni C, Wigle R (1993) An evaluation of the draft final act of the Uruguay round. Econ J 103:1540–1549

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (1996) Indicators of tariff and non-tariff trade barriers. Paris

  • OECD (1999) OECD economic outlook No.65. Paris

  • OECD (2001) The Uruguay round agreement on agriculture—an evaluation of its implementation in OECD countries. Paris

  • Romer P (1994) New goods, old theory, and the welfare costs of trade restrictions. J Dev Econ 43:5–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitt N, Yu Z (2001) Economics of scale and the volume of intra-industry trade. Econ Lett 74:127–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schröder PJH (2004) Real versus tariff liberalization: a welfare comparison under monopolistic competition. Open Econ Rev 15(4):403–418

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suits DB, Musgrave RA (1953) Ad valorem and unit taxes compared. Q J Econ 67:598–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Berkum S, van Meijl H (2000) The application of trade and growth theories to agriculture: a survey. The Aust J Agric Resour Econ 44(4):505–542

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • WTO (1998) Annual report 1998. World Trade Organization, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • WTO (2003) Market access for agricultural goods, the Uruguay round: a quantitative assessment, WTO web-document, accessed at [http://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/whatis_e/eol/e/wto01/wto1_45.htm] on April 23rd 2006

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors wish to thank the editors and an anonymous referee for valuable comments. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Philipp J. H. Schröder.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A.1 Impact on the non-traded industry

Both labour and spending power (including redistributed funds from quota rents and tariff revenue), stemming from the constrained export industry will move to the non-traded industry. Formally, the labour supply for the non-traded industries, \(\ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{L}^{s} \), can be written as:

$$\ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{L}^{s} = \frac{1}{2}L + \Delta L^{s} \,\,\,\,\,\,s = q,v,\tau ,t$$
(18)

The increase in available labour does not influence the equilibrium output and price of the individual firm in the non-traded industry and hence output and price is equal to \({\ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{p}}\) and \({\ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{x}}\) given implicitly in Eqs. 4a and 4b. This reallocation of labour is identical to an increase in market size, and thus only influences the equilibrium number of variants, and hence also total industry output. The equilibrium number of variants, \(\ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{n}^{s} \), is found by using the labour market clearing condition for the non-traded industry given by:

$$\ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{L}^{s} = {\left( {\alpha + \beta \ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{x}} \right)}\ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{n}^{s} \,\,\,\,\,\,s = q,v,\tau ,t$$
(19)

Combining Eqs. 18 and 19 and inserting ΔL s found in Eqs. 8, 10 and 14, we find the equilibrium number of variants in the non-traded industry under the different trade policies:

$$\ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{n}^{q} = \ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{n}^{\tau } = \frac{{2 - \theta \gamma }}{{2 - \theta }}n$$
(20)
$$\ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{n}^{v} = \ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{n}^{t} = {\left( {2 - \gamma } \right)}n$$
(21)

From Eqs. 20 and 21 it immediately follows that \(\ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{n}^{q} ,\ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{n}^{v} ,\ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{n}^{t} ,\ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{n}^{\tau } > n\) and \(\ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{n}^{q} = \ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{n}^{\tau } < \ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{n}^{v} = \ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{n}^{t} \).

1.2 A.2 Proof that U q, U v, U τ, U t < U

Consumer utility under trade protection, but with full reallocation of tariff revenues and quota rents, is less than utility under free trade. Recall from Proposition 1 that U τ = U q and U t = U v.

Proof

Ut < U. From Eq. 17c it follows that Ut = U + ln(2 − γ) + ln γ. Hence, one has to show that:

$$K^{t} = \ln {\left( {2 - \gamma } \right)} + \ln \gamma < 0.$$
(22)

It follows from Eq. 22 that limγ→0Kt = −∞ and limγ→1Kt = 0. Since \(\frac{{\partial K^{t} }}{{\partial \gamma }} = \frac{{2 - 2\gamma }}{{{\left( {2 - \gamma } \right)}\gamma }} > 0,\,K^{t} \) is monotone increasing in γ for all 0 < γ < 1, Eq. 22 is fulfilled.□

Proof

Uτ < U. From Eq. 17d it follows that \(U^{\tau } = U + {\left( {2 - \theta } \right)}\ln {\left( {\frac{{2 - \theta \gamma }}{{2 - \theta }}} \right)} + \theta \ln \gamma \). Hence, one has to show that:

$$K^{\tau } = {\left( {2 - \theta } \right)}\ln {\left( {\frac{{2 - \theta \gamma }}{{2 - \theta }}} \right)} + \theta \ln \gamma < 0$$
(23)

It follows from Eq. 23 that limγ→0Kτ = −∞and limγ→1Kτ = 0. Since \(\frac{{\partial K^{\tau } }}{{\partial \gamma }} = \theta \frac{{2{\left( {1 - \gamma } \right)}}}{{{\left( {2 - \theta \gamma } \right)}\gamma }} > 0,\,\,K^{\tau } \) is monotone increasing in γ for all 0 < γ < 1, Eq. 23 is fulfilled.□

1.3 A.3 Proof that U τ > U t

Tariffication with a specific tariff and complete reallocation of all tariff revenues gives higher consumer utility than tariffication with an ad valorem tariff.

Proof

Uτ > Ut. FromEqs. 17c and 17d it follows that:

$$U^{\tau } > U^{t} \Leftrightarrow {\left( {2 - \theta } \right)}\ln {\left( {\frac{{2 - \theta \gamma }}{{2 - \theta }}} \right)} + \theta \ln \gamma > \ln {\left( {2 - \gamma } \right)} + \ln \gamma $$
(24)

Define the function:

$$F{\left( z \right)} = {\left( {2 - z} \right)}\ln {\left( {\frac{{2 - z\gamma }}{{2 - z}}} \right)} + z\ln \gamma $$
(25)

If F(z) is monotone decreasing in z, then b > a implies F(a) > F(b), and hence Eq. 24 is fulfilled as 1 > θ. From Eq. 25 it follows that

$$\frac{{\partial F}}{{\partial z}} = \ln {\left( {\frac{{{\left( {2 - z} \right)}\gamma }}{{2 - z\gamma }}} \right)} + \frac{{2{\left( {1 - \gamma } \right)}}}{{2 - z\gamma }}$$
(26)

One has to show that for a given z Eq. 26 is negative for all γ, 0 < γ < 1. It follows from Eq. 26 that

$${\mathop {\lim }\limits_{\gamma \to 0} }\frac{{\partial F}}{{\partial z}} = - \infty \,\,\,{\text{and}}\,\,\,{\mathop {\lim }\limits_{\gamma \to 1} }\frac{{\partial F}}{{\partial z}} = 0$$
(27)

and since

$$\frac{{\partial \frac{{\partial F}}{{\partial z}}}}{{\partial \gamma }} = \frac{{4\left( {1 - \gamma } \right)}}{{\gamma \left( {2 - z\gamma } \right)^2 }} > 0$$
(28)

Eq. 26 is monotone increasing in γ for all z and thus negative in the relevant parameter intervals, such that Eq. 25 is monotone decreasing and hence Uτ > Ut holds.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Jørgensen, J.G., Schröder, P.J.H. Effects of Tariffication: Tariffs and Quotas under Monopolistic Competition. Open Econ Rev 18, 479–498 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-007-9025-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-007-9025-9

Keywords

JEL

Navigation