In the following, we recap a popular specification of the seminal asset-pricing model by Brock and Hommes [16] to illustrate how nonlinear interactions between heterogeneous speculators may create complex (chaotic) boom-bust asset-price dynamics. However, we extend their setup by considering a central authority seeking to stabilize such dynamics via two different countercyclical intervention strategies.
Basic model setup
Let us turn to the details of the model. Market participants can invest in a safe asset, paying the risk-free interest rate r, and in a risky asset, paying an uncertain dividend Dt. The dividend process of the risky asset is specified by
$$ D_{t} = \bar{D} + \delta_{t} , $$
(1)
where \( \delta_{t} \sim N\left( {0,\sigma_{\delta }^{2} } \right) \). While the price of the safe asset is constant, the price of the risky asset depends on the trading behavior of the market participants, comprising (heterogeneous) speculators, a central authority, long-term investors and liquidity trades. Our modeling of speculators’ demand for the risky asset follows Brock and Hommes [16].Footnote 3 Let Pt be the price of the risky asset (ex-dividend) at time t. The end-of-period wealth of speculator i can be expressed as
$$ W_{t + 1}^{i} = \left( {1 + r} \right)W_{t}^{i} + Z_{t}^{i} \left( {P_{t + 1} + D_{t + 1} - (1 + r} \right)P_{t} ), $$
(2)
where \( Z_{t}^{i} \) represents speculator i’s demand for the risky asset. Note that variables indexed with t + 1 are random. Speculators are myopic mean–variance maximizers. Their demand for the risky asset follows from
$$ \max_{{Z_{t}^{i} }} \left[ {E_{t}^{i} \left[ {W_{t + 1}^{i} } \right] - \frac{{\alpha^{i} }}{2}V_{t}^{i} \left[ {W_{t + 1}^{i} } \right]} \right], $$
(3)
where \( E_{t}^{i} \left[ {W_{t + 1}^{i} } \right] \) and \( V_{t}^{i} \left[ {W_{t + 1}^{i} } \right] \) denote speculator i’s belief about the conditional expectation and conditional variance of his wealth, and parameter \( \alpha^{i} > 0 \) stands for his risk aversion. Accordingly, speculator i’s optimal demand for the risky asset is
$$ Z_{t}^{i} = \frac{{E_{t}^{i} \left[ {P_{t + 1} } \right] + E_{t}^{i} \left[ {D_{t + 1} } \right] - \left( {1 + r} \right)P_{t} }}{{\alpha^{i} V_{t}^{i} \left[ {P_{t + 1} + D_{t + 1} } \right]}}. $$
(4)
To achieve a convenient expression of speculators’ aggregate demand for the risky asset, Brock and Hommes [16] introduce the following simplifying assumptions. There are N speculators in total, believing that \( E_{t}^{i} \left[ {D_{t + 1} } \right] = \bar{D} \). Moreover, all speculators hold the same constant variance beliefs, i.e., \( V_{t}^{i} \left[ {P_{t + 1} + D_{t + 1} } \right] = \sigma_{R}^{2} \), and possess the same degree of risk aversion, i.e., \( \alpha^{i} = \alpha > 0 \). We can therefore express speculators’ aggregate demand for the risky asset as \( Z_{t}^{S} = \sum\nolimits_{i = 1}^{N} {Z_{t}^{i} } = \frac{{\mathop \sum \nolimits_{i = 1}^{N} E_{t}^{i} \left[ {P_{t + 1} } \right] + N\bar{D} - N\left( {1 + r} \right)P_{t} }}{{\alpha \sigma_{R}^{2} }} \). Denoting speculators’ average expectation about the risky asset’s next-period price by \( E_{t} \left[ {P_{t + 1} } \right] = \frac{1}{N}\mathop \sum \nolimits_{i = 1}^{N} E_{t}^{i} \left[ {P_{t + 1} } \right] \) and normalizing the mass of speculators to N = 1 yield
$$ Z_{t}^{S} = \frac{{E_{t} \left[ {P_{t + 1} } \right] + \bar{D} - \left( {1 + r} \right)P_{t} }}{{\alpha \sigma_{R}^{2} }}. $$
(5)
Note that speculators’ demand for the risky asset increases with their price and dividend expectations and decreases with the risk-free interest rate, the current price of the risky asset, their risk aversion and variance beliefs.
Speculators may use a technical or a fundamental expectation rule to forecast the price of the risky asset. The market shares of speculators following the technical and fundamental expectation rule are labeled \( N_{t}^{C} \) and \( N_{t}^{F} = 1 - N_{t}^{C} \). Speculators’ average price expectations are defined by
$$ E_{t} [P_{t + 1} ] = N_{t}^{C} E_{t}^{C} \left[ {P_{t + 1} } \right] + N_{t}^{F} E_{t}^{F} \left[ {P_{t + 1} } \right]. $$
(6)
Speculators compute the fundamental value of the risky asset price by discounting future dividend payments, that is, \( F = \bar{D}/r \). Speculators applying the technical expectation rule, also called chartists, expect the deviation between the price of the risky asset and its fundamental value to increase. Their expectations are formalized by
$$ E_{t}^{C} \left[ {P_{t + 1} } \right] = P_{t - 1} + \chi \left( {P_{t - 1} - F} \right), $$
(7)
where \( \chi > 0 \) denotes the strength of speculators’ extrapolation behavior. Speculators using the fundamental expectation rule, also called fundamentalists, believe that the price of the risky asset will approach its fundamental value. Their expectations can be written as
$$ E_{t}^{F} \left[ {P_{t + 1} } \right] = P_{t - 1} + \phi \left( {F - P_{t - 1} } \right), $$
(8)
where \( 0 < \phi \le 1 \) indicates speculators’ expected mean reversion speed. Note that both expectation rules forecast the price of the risky asset for period t + 1 at the beginning of period t, based on information available in period t − 1.
Speculators switch between the technical and fundamental expectation rule with respect to their evolutionary fitness, measured in terms of past realized profits. Accordingly, the attractiveness of the two expectation rules is computed as
$$ A_{t}^{C} = \left( {P_{t - 1} + D_{t - 1} - \left( {1 + r} \right)P_{t - 2} } \right)Z_{t - 2}^{C}, $$
(9)
and
$$ A_{t}^{F} = \left( {P_{t - 1} + D_{t - 1} - \left( {1 + r} \right)P_{t - 2} } \right)Z_{t - 2}^{F} - \kappa , $$
(10)
where
$$ Z_{t - 2}^{C} = \frac{{E_{t - 2}^{C} \left[ {P_{t - 1} } \right] + \bar{D} - \left( {1 + r} \right)P_{t - 2} }}{{\alpha \sigma_{R}^{2} }}, $$
(11)
and
$$ Z_{t - 2}^{F} = \frac{{E_{t - 2}^{F} \left[ {P_{t - 1} } \right] + \bar{D} - \left( {1 + r} \right)P_{t - 2} }}{{\alpha \sigma_{R}^{2} }}. $$
(12)
Brock and Hommes [16] consider that the use of the fundamental expectation rule may be costly, so they subtract constant per period information costs \( \kappa \ge 0 \) from [10]. However, we may also regard parameter k as a behavioral bias in favor of the simpler technical expectation rule. See Anufriev et al. [1] for empirical evidence.
The market shares of chartists and fundamentalists are due to the discrete choice approach, i.e.,
$$ N_{t}^{C} = \frac{{\exp \left[ {\beta A_{t}^{C} } \right]}}{{\exp \left[ {\beta A_{t}^{C} } \right] + \exp \left[ {\beta A_{t}^{F} } \right]}}, $$
(13)
and
$$ N_{t}^{F} = \frac{{\exp \left[ {\beta A_{t}^{F} } \right]}}{{\exp \left[ {\beta A_{t}^{C} } \right] + \exp \left[ {\beta A_{t}^{F} } \right]}}. $$
(14)
The intensity of choice parameter \( \beta > 0 \) measures how quickly the mass of speculators switches to the more successful trading rule. The higher parameter β is, the more speculators opt for the more profitable trading rule. In the limit, as parameter β approaches infinity, all speculators opt for the trading rule that produces the highest fitness. In this sense, speculators display a boundedly rational learning behavior.
Let us now turn to the central authority seeking to offset the destabilizing behavior of speculators by following two different intervention strategies [51, 63, 85]. According to the first strategy, called the leaning against the wind strategy, the central authority acts against current price trends by buying the risky asset if its price decreases and selling the risky asset if its price increases. According to the second strategy, called the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy, the central authority seeks to guide the price of the risky asset toward its fundamental value by buying the risky asset if the market is undervalued and selling the risky asset if the market is overvalued. Here, we focus on simple linear feedback strategies and express the central authority’s demand for the risky asset as
$$ Z_{t}^{G} = - m\left( {P_{t - 1} - P_{t - 2} } \right) - d\left( {P_{t - 1} - F} \right), $$
(15)
where \( m \ge 0 \) and \( d \ge 0 \) are control parameters, capturing the central authority’s intervention strength with respect to the market’s momentum and distortion.Footnote 4 Note that the central authority computes the asset’s fundamental value in the same way as speculators do.Footnote 5
The demand for the risky asset by long-term investors, following a buy-and-hold strategy, is constant and set to
$$ Z_{t}^{I} = \bar{Z}^{I}. $$
(16)
Moreover, the demand for the risky asset by liquidity traders is random and given as follows:
$$ Z_{t}^{L} = \lambda_{t} , $$
(17)
with \( \lambda_{t} \sim N\left( {0,\sigma_{L}^{2} } \right) \). The total demand for the risky asset by all market participants is
$$ Z_{t} = Z_{t}^{S} + Z_{t}^{G} + Z_{t}^{I} + Z_{t}^{L}. $$
(18)
Market equilibrium requires that the total demand for the risky asset by all market participants equals the total supply of the risky asset, that is
$$ Z_{t} = Y_{t}. $$
(19)
The total supply of the risky asset, i.e., the number of shares offered by firms, is constant and given by
$$ Y_{t} = \bar{Y}. $$
(20)
Brock and Hommes [16] assume that there is a zero supply of outside shares. For simplicity, we therefore assume that
$$ \bar{Y} = \bar{Z}^{I}, $$
(21)
i.e., the number of shares offered by firms is identical to the number of shares requested by long-term investors.
Combining [5] with [15,16,17,18,19,21] reveals that the price of the risky asset is determined by
$$ P_{t} = \frac{{E_{t} [P_{t + 1} ] + \bar{D} + \alpha \sigma_{R}^{2} \left( {Z_{t}^{G} + Z_{t}^{L} } \right)}}{1 + r}. $$
(22)
Note that [21] implies that Pt increases if speculators have bullish price expectations. As suggested by the leaning against the wind strategy, the central authority sells the risky asset, which should depress its price. Likewise, the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy recommends that the central authority sells the risky asset if the market is overvalued, which should also bring its price back to more moderate levels. At least at first sight, both the leaning against the wind strategy and the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy sound plausible. As we will see, however, the model’s nonlinear price formation process is less trivial to stabilize as our intuition may suggest.Footnote 6
Analytical and numerical results
Before we conduct a detailed numerical analysis of the impact of the central authority’s intervention strategies on the model’s dynamics, preliminary remarks are in order. In the absence of exogenous shocks, the dynamics of the model is driven by the iteration of a three-dimensional nonlinear deterministic map. In Appendix A, we show the following results (an overbar denotes steady-state quantities):
-
1.
Our model possesses a fundamental steady state according to which \( \bar{P}_{1} = F = \bar{D}/r \), implying, among other things, that \( \bar{N}_{1}^{C} = (1 + \exp \left[ { - \beta \kappa } \right])^{ - 1} \) and \( \bar{N}_{1}^{F} = (1 + \exp \left[ {\beta \kappa } \right])^{ - 1} \). Note that neither the leaning against the wind strategy nor the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy influences the model’s fundamental steady state. Moreover, speculators’ distribution among expectation rules is also independent of parameters m and d. Of course, the reason for this is that the central authority is inactive at \( \bar{P}_{1} \), i.e., \( \bar{Z}_{1}^{G} = 0 \).
-
2.
The fundamental steady state undergoes a pitchfork bifurcation if the stability condition \( \bar{N}_{1}^{C} \chi - \bar{N}_{1}^{F} \phi < r + \alpha \sigma_{R}^{2} d \) is violated. Such a bifurcation may occur if the extrapolation parameter of the technical expectation rule increases. While the leaning against the wind strategy does not affect the stability domain of the model’s fundamental steady state, the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy may suppress or reverse a pitchfork bifurcation.
-
3.
The pitchfork bifurcation gives rise to two further steady states. These nonfundamental steady states are given by \( \bar{P}_{2,3} = \bar{P}_{1} \pm \sqrt {\frac{{2\alpha \sigma_{R}^{2} \left( {\frac{\beta }{2}\kappa + {arctanh} \left[ {\frac{{\chi - \phi - 2r - 2\alpha \sigma_{R}^{2} d}}{\chi + \phi }} \right]} \right)}}{{r\beta \left( {\chi + \phi } \right)}}} \), implying among others, that \( \bar{N}_{2,3}^{C} = \frac{{\phi + r + \alpha \sigma_{R}^{2} d}}{\chi + \phi } \) and \( \bar{N}_{2,3}^{F} = \frac{{\chi - r - \alpha \sigma_{R}^{2} d}}{\chi + \phi } \). Importantly, the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy allows the central authority to cut the gap between \( \bar{P}_{1} \) and \( \bar{P}_{2,3} \), i.e., to reduce mispricing of the risky asset. Unfortunately, this increases speculators’ use of the technical expectation rule and necessitates permanent interventions, given by \( \bar{Z}_{2,3}^{G} = \pm d\sqrt {\frac{{2\alpha \sigma_{R}^{2} \left( {\frac{\beta }{2}\kappa + 2{arctanh} \left[ {\frac{{\chi - \phi - 2r - 2\alpha \sigma_{R}^{2} d}}{\chi + \phi }} \right]} \right)}}{{r\beta \left( {\chi + \phi } \right)}}}. \).Footnote 7 Since the leaning against the wind strategy does not generate interventions when the price of the risky asset is at rest, \( \bar{P}_{2,3} \), \( \bar{N}_{2,3}^{C} \), \( \bar{N}_{2,3}^{F} \) and \( \bar{Z}_{2,3}^{G} \) are independent of parameter m.
-
4.
The nonfundamental steady states may become unstable due to a Neimark–Sacker bifurcation. For instance, a Neimark–Sacker bifurcation occurs if the extrapolation parameter of the technical expectation rule becomes sufficiently large. Further numerical explorations suggest that both intervention strategies may prevent the emergence of complex (chaotic) dynamics.
Armed with these insights, we are now ready to conduct a systematic numerical investigation of our setup. In doing so, our goal is to show that speculators’ behavior may cause endogenous boom-bust dynamics. Moreover, we describe how the central authority’s intervention strategies fare against their destabilizing trading behavior. The base parameter setting we use for our simulations closely follows Brock and Hommes [16]. To be precise, we assume that \( r = 0.1 \), \( \bar{D} = 1 \), \( \sigma_{\delta }^{2} = 0 \), \( \alpha = 1 \), \( \sigma_{R}^{2} = 1 \), \( \chi = 0.2 \), \( \phi = 1 \), \( \kappa = 1 \), \( \beta = 3.6 \), \( \sigma_{L}^{2} = 0 \), \( m = 0 \) and \( d = 0 \). Since \( \bar{N}_{1}^{C} = 0.973 \) and \( \bar{N}_{1}^{F} = 0.027 \), the fundamental steady state \( \bar{P}_{1} = F = 10 \) is unstable. For instance, the critical value for the intensity of choice that would just ensure the local asymptotic stability of the fundamental steady state is given by \( \beta_{\text{crit}}^{\text{PF}} = 2.4 \). As we will see in the sequel, the nonfundamental steady states are also unstable, and the model’s dynamics is characterized by two coexisting limit cycles. Numerically, we can compute that the Neimark–Sacker bifurcation occurs at about \( \beta_{\text{crit}}^{\text{NS}} = 3.3 \). Our stochastic simulations always rely on \( \sigma_{L}^{2} = 0.0025 \).
Figure 1 provides an overview of the dynamics of the unregulated market, i.e., of the dynamics of the original model by Brock and Hommes [16]. Panels (a) and (b) of Fig. 1 present the evolution of the price of the risky asset for 400 periods in the time domain; they differ only with respect to their initial conditions. Apparently, the model is able to generate endogenous bull or bear market dynamics. Depending on the initial conditions, we observe endogenous fluctuations either above or below the fundamental value. Panel (c) of Fig. 1 reveals that minimal random demand shocks, induced by liquidity traders, are sufficient to create erratic transitions between bull and bear market dynamics. Moreover, the dynamics appears less regular. Panels (d) and (e) of Fig. 1 show routes to complex asset-price dynamics via a pitchfork and Neimark–Sacker bifurcation. The intensity of choice parameter β is varied between 2 and 4; the panels rely on different initial conditions.Footnote 8 Panel (f) of Fig. 1 repeats these experiments for a stochastic environment. Consistent with panel (c) of Fig. 1, we observe intricate attractor switching dynamics.Footnote 9
Figure 2 provides examples of time series for the effectiveness of the leaning against the wind strategy with \( m = 0.25 \) in the deterministic setting, panels (a) and (b), and \( m = 1 \) in the stochastic setting, panels (c) and (d). The top panels present the evolution of the price of the risky asset, while the bottom panels report the level of the central authority’s interventions. A comparison of panel (a) of Fig. 1 with panel (a) of Fig. 2 reveals that the leaning against the wind strategy manages to reduce fluctuations of the price of the risky asset. But while a stabilization effect in terms of a lower price variability is clearly visible, the price of the risky asset keeps a distance to its fundamental value. Panel (b) of Fig. 2 indicates that the central authority has to intervene in the risky asset market in each time step. Panels (c) and (d) of Fig. 2 suggest that these observations are robust with respect to exogenous shocks.
Figure 3 provides a more systematic analysis of the leaning against the wind strategy. Panel (a) of Fig. 3 shows a bifurcation diagram for parameter m and reveals that the leaning against the wind strategy stabilizes the dynamics around the upper nonfundamental steady state if parameter m exceeds a value of about 0.32.Footnote 10 Such an outcome should be regarded as a mixed blessing: While the leaning against the wind strategy enables the central authority to reduce the risky asset’s price fluctuations, it fails to reduce the market’s mispricing. Panel (b) of Fig. 3 depicts the central authority’s associated interventions. Note that if parameter m is set high enough, interventions can be low or even zero. Panel (c) of Fig. 3 confirms the stabilizing potential of the leaning against the wind strategy within a stochastic environment. However, panel (d) of Fig. 3 suggests that the central authority’s intervention intensity increases with parameter m. This is clearly different to what we see in panel (b) of Fig. 3, where the central authority’s intervention intensity eventually goes to zero. (There are no price changes at the nonfundamental steady state.) Of course, the stochastic environment is the relevant environment for judging the effectiveness of interventions.
To be able to quantify the success of the central authority’s interventions, we introduce six summary statistics. Let T be the sample length used for computing these statistics. We capture the risky asset’s volatility by the average absolute price change of the risky asset \( \frac{1}{T}\sum\nolimits_{t = 1}^{T} {\left| {P_{t} - P_{t - 1} } \right|} \), the risky asset’s mispricing by the average absolute distance between the price of the risky asset and its fundamental value \( \frac{1}{T}\sum\nolimits_{t = 1}^{T} {\left| {P_{t} - F} \right|} \), the central authority’s intervention intensity by the average absolute level of interventions \( \frac{1}{T}\sum\nolimits_{t = 1}^{T} {\left| {Z_{t}^{G} } \right|} \), the average profitability of their interventions by \( \frac{1}{T}\sum\nolimits_{t = 1}^{T} {\left( {P_{t} + D_{t} - \left( {1 + r} \right)P_{t - 1} } \right)} Z_{t - 1}^{G} \), the average market share of fundamentalists by \( \frac{1}{T}\sum\nolimits_{t = 1}^{T} {N_{t}^{F} } \) and their average absolute position by \( \frac{1}{T}\sum\nolimits_{t = 1}^{T} {N_{t}^{F} \left| {Z_{t}^{F} } \right|} \). Note that we measure the central authority’s profits in the same way as we do for speculators. For simplicity, we ignore the costs associated with conducting these interventions. There may be fixed costs, for instance, that could simply be subtracted from our profit measure. To obtain reasonable estimates of these statistics, we focus on the stochastic environment and use \( T = 10,000 \) observations.
Based on these statistics, we can now quantify the success of the leaning against the wind strategy. Overall, the results are mixed. According to panels (a) and (b) of Fig. 4, volatility declines when this strategy is applied, while mispricing increases. As discussed above, the leaning against the wind strategy manages to stabilize the dynamics, albeit around the model’s nonfundamental steady states. Moreover, panel (c) of Fig. 4 indicates that the central authority has to intervene more and more aggressively if it wants to reduce volatility. Apparently, the leaning against the wind strategy also produces losses, as depicted in panel (d) of Fig. 4. Interestingly, the average market share of fundamentalists increases (slightly) with parameter m. The same is true for the average absolute position of fundamentalists, an outcome that is driven by an increase in fundamentalists’ average market share and an increase in the market’s mispricing. See panels (e) and (f) of Fig. 4. So far, we can thus conclude that the leaning against the wind strategy may offset endogenous fluctuations, engendered by a Neimark–Sacker bifurcation, but has no real power to fight deviations from fundamental values, as created by a pitchfork bifurcation.
Figures 5 and 6 show the effects of the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy. Most importantly, the bifurcation diagram depicted in panel (a) of Fig. 6 shows that the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy may allow the central authority to reduce volatility and mispricing of the risky asset. In line with our analytical results, the price of the risky asset approaches its fundamental value for \( d > 0.68 \). To diminish mispricing connected with a bull (bear) market, however, the central authority needs to go permanently short (long), as visible from panel (b) of Fig. 6. Importantly, this strategy also seems to work in a stochastic environment. Panel (c) of Fig. 6 reveals that asset prices fluctuate much closer around the fundamental value as parameter d increases. Moreover, we can conclude from panel (d) of Fig. 6 that the central authority’s interventions oscillate around zero if parameter d is set high enough. To illustrate these findings, panels (a) and (c) of Fig. 5 show examples of time series for the price of the risky asset when the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy is applied with \( d = 0.01 \) (deterministic setting) and \( d = 0.1 \) (stochastic setting). Panels (b) and (d) of Fig. 5 depict the central authority’s corresponding interventions.
Figure 7 shows how the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy may affect our four policy measures. As can be seen from panels (a) and (b) of Fig. 7, the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy allows the central authority to reduce volatility and mispricing of the risky asset, provided that it executes its interventions forcefully enough. Interestingly, the absolute level of interventions shrinks if parameter d becomes large enough. The reason for this is as follows. For intermediate values of parameter d, the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy stabilizes the dynamics around one of the two nonfundamental steady states. If parameter d is set high enough, this strategy stabilizes the dynamics around the risky asset’s fundamental value. Panel (d) of Fig. 7 suggests that this strategy may even be profitable. In line with our analytical results, we can conclude from panel (e) of Fig. 7 that the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy diminishes the market impact of fundamentalists. According to panel (f) of Fig. 7, this also holds for the average absolute position of fundamentalists, at least if this strategy is applied forcefully. Nevertheless, and this is the important message, the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy achieves to reduce the market’s volatility and mispricing.
Model extensions and robustness checks
Robustness checks are important for policy analysis. Here, we consider two kinds of robustness checks. As a first and rather simple robustness check, we explore the effectiveness of the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy in a stochastic environment for alternative parameter settings. In panels (a) and (b) of Fig. 8, we plot how volatility and mispricing react to an increase in parameter d, assuming different values for speculators’ variance beliefs (red dots: \( \sigma_{R}^{2} = 0.8 \), black dots: \( \sigma_{R}^{2} = 1 \), blue dots: \( \sigma_{R}^{2} = 1.2 \)). Apparently, the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy is able to stabilize the dynamics when speculators’ variance beliefs change. In panels (c) and (d) of Fig. 8, we assume that the market impact of liquidity traders is, say, low (red dots: \( \sigma_{L}^{2} = 0.001 \)), medium (black dots: \( \sigma_{L}^{2} = 0.0025 \)) or high (blue dots: \( \sigma_{L}^{2} = 0.004 \)). As can be seen, an increase in \( \sigma_{L}^{2} \), reflecting more aggressive liquidity traders, shifts volatility and mispricing upwards, yet does not affect the effectiveness of the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy. In panels (e) and (f) of Fig. 8, we vary the costs associated with conducting fundamental analysis (red dots: \( \kappa = 0.9 \), black dots: \( \kappa = 1 \), blue dots: \( \kappa = 1.25 \)). For all three values of parameter k, the central authority manages to reduce volatility and mispricing. Note that by providing better information about the fundamental value of the risky asset, the central authority may be able to reduce information costs. Such a policy has a stabilizing effect too.
As a second and slightly more involved robustness check, let us assume that the risky asset’s dividend process follows a random walk. Accordingly, we specify the dividend process by \( D_{t} = D_{t - 1} + D_{t - 1} \delta_{t} \), where \( \delta_{t} \sim N\left( {0,\sigma_{\delta }^{2} } \right) \), implying that \( E_{t} [D_{t + 1} ] = D_{t - 1} \) and, consequently, that \( F_{t - 1} = D_{t - 1} /r \), i.e., the fundamental value of the risky assets follows a random walk, too. Moreover, the price of the risky asset now obeys \( P_{t} = \frac{{E_{t} [P_{t + 1} ] + D_{t - 1} + \alpha \sigma_{R}^{2} \left( {Z_{t}^{G} + Z_{t}^{L} } \right)}}{1 + r} \), the technical expectation rule turns into \( E_{t}^{C} \left[ {P_{t + 1} } \right] = P_{t - 1} + \chi \left( {P_{t - 1} - F_{t - 1} } \right) \), and the fundamental expectation rule reads \( E_{t}^{F} \left[ {P_{t + 1} } \right] = P_{t - 1} + \phi \left( {F_{t - 1} - P_{t - 1} } \right) \). The attractiveness of the two expectation rules is due to \( A_{t}^{C} = \left( {P_{t - 1} + D_{t - 1} - \left( {1 + r} \right)P_{t - 2} } \right)Z_{t - 2}^{C} \) and \( A_{t}^{F} = \left( {P_{t - 1} + D_{t - 1} - \left( {1 + r} \right)P_{t - 2} } \right)Z_{t - 2}^{F} - \kappa \), where \( Z_{t - 2}^{C} = \frac{{E_{t - 2}^{C} \left[ {P_{t - 1} } \right] + D_{t - 3} - \left( {1 + r} \right)P_{t - 2} }}{{\alpha \sigma_{R}^{2} }} \) and \( Z_{t - 2}^{F} = \frac{{E_{t - 2}^{F} \left[ {P_{t - 1} } \right] + D_{t - 3} - \left( {1 + r} \right)P_{t - 2} }}{{\alpha \sigma_{R}^{2} }} \). Finally, the central authority’s demand for the risky asset is given by \( Z_{t}^{G} = - m\left( {P_{t - 1} - P_{t - 2} } \right) - d\left( {P_{t - 1} - F_{t - 1} } \right) \). The model’s other building blocks remain as before.
The simulation results depicted in Fig. 9 rely on our stochastic parameter setting, except that the variance of the dividend shocks is given by \( \sigma_{\delta }^{2} = 0.0001 \). Panel (a) of Fig. 9 shows the dynamics of the asset price (black line) and its fundamental value (red line) when the central authority is inactive (\( d = 0 \)). As can be seen, the asset price fluctuates widely around it time-varying fundamental value. Panel (b) of Fig. 9 depicts the behavior of the asset price and its fundamental value when the central authority is active (\( d = 0.1 \)). Without question, the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy manages to push the price of the risky asset closer toward its fundamental value. Finally, panels (c) and (d) of Fig. 9 report how volatility and mispricing react to an increase in parameter d. Once again, we can conclude that the central authority may stabilize the risky asset market by using the targeting long-run fundamentals strategy.Footnote 11