Skip to main content
Log in

Econometric Effects of Utility Order-Preserving Transformations in Discrete Choice Models

  • Published:
Networks and Spatial Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the random utility modelling context, choice probabilities are unaffected by increasing linear transformations of the systematic utility; hence its empirical specification is derived on the basis that only differences in utility matters and that the scale of utility is arbitrary. We argue that choice probabilities remain unchanged if these linear transformations are made under the deterministic perspective of a single individual choosing several times. But, in the random utility setting, parameter estimates might be significantly affected by these transformations. In particular we focus on the effect of two order-preserving transformations usually applied in the derivation of the representative utility from the conditional indirect utility function: adding a constant to the utility of all alternatives and multiplying each alternative utility by a constant. We concentrate on the two most popular specifications in transport mode choice: the “wage rate” (Train and McFadden Transport Res 12:349–353, 1978) and the “expenditure rate” (Jara-Díaz and Farah Transport Res 22B:159–171, 1987) specifications. Using a collection of synthetic datasets generated in a new fashion directly from the conditional indirect utility function, i.e. before applying any expansion or transformation, we demonstrate how taking this class of order-preserving transformations could lead to misinterpretation of the econometric results, such as detecting randomly distributed and correlated parameters and/or income and time effects which are in fact not present.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Batley (2008) notes that McFadden’s work actually dates back to 1968, when it first appeared as an unpublished working paper at the University of California, Berkeley.

  2. This same result was found for the two log-linear direct utility functions considered in the Train and McFadden (1978) paper.

  3. Train and McFadden (1978) derive Eqs. (6b) and (6c) from the following direct utility functions: \( U = {\alpha_1}\log G + {\alpha_2}L \) and \( U = {\alpha_1}G + {\alpha_2}\log L \). In maximazing them, respectively α2L and α1G drop out, hence the indirect utilities (6b) and (6c) are obtained, where actually α 1 = 1-β and α 2 = β.

  4. Note that neither the wage rate nor the direct preference parameter β depends on the discrete alternative. Hence, although β plays a relevant role on the goods/leisure trade-off, under a strictly deterministic approach it has no influence on the discrete choice. See Cherchi (2003) and Amador (2005) for more details.

  5. They employ a similar reasoning to justify what they called the expenditure rate specification. Nonetheless, some years later Jara-Díaz (1991, p.343) showed that the aforementioned specification was actually a particular case of the generalized expenditure rate model. On the other hand, Train and McFadden (1978, p.350) suggest two alternative ways of deriving the CIUF as equivalent approaches and they explicitly recognize that the CIUF obtained through one manner is the same or a monotonic transformation of the CIUF resulting from the other approach. Thus, they are implicitly accepting the use of order-preserving transformations of the CIUF.

  6. Note that we use the term direct preference parameter to denote the parameter β influencing the direct utility function. This parameter should not be confused with the parameters θ that appear into the representative utility function, which also reflects individuals’ preferences.

  7. The generalization proposed by Train and McFadden (1978) postulates also the existence of different components of travel time and cost: \( {U_j} = - k\sum\nolimits_{i = 1,..,N} {\delta_c^i{\omega^{ - \beta }}c_j^i} - k\sum\nolimits_{i = 1, \ldots M} {\delta_t^i{\omega^{1 - \beta }}t_j^i} - k\left( {{\eta_{cj}} + {\eta_{tj}}} \right) \). However, considering only one component of time and cost does not affect our discussion.

  8. In fact, this argument could partially explain empirical findings by Amador et al. (2008) on confounding preference heterogeneity and income effect.

  9. This is an assumption that might be discussed, but it was based on average real data, in order to generate a fairly realistic choice set. Following Train and McFadden (1978) the endowment represents the income not generated by work.

  10. These are the correct specifications because are the specifications used to generate the data.

  11. Specifications (4) and (12) were estimated using BIOGEME (Bierlaire 2008), while the other models with the GAUSS code provided by Prof. Kenneth Train in his web-page. However we checked that both softwares gave the same results for the MNL and ML models.

  12. We generated both the ER and WR data using the same process, trying to keep the two dataset as similar as possible in terms of values of the variables involved. However because of differences in the constraints, some explicative variables and of course the final choices are different. So the LL(WR) and LL(ER), even in the true specification, cannot actually be compared among them.

  13. Note that a linear in time and cost specification like WR1 is not an order preserving transformation of the true non-transformed utility (4) even from a deterministic perspective, hence it was expected that models WR2 and WR3 fitted the data better than model WR1.

  14. A normal distribution is assumed for the random parameters in all the Mixed Logit models. Models WR12, WR25, ER8-ER10, assume independent random parameters, while the remaining Mixed Logit models account for correlation between random parameters.

  15. Two income strata were considered; therefore two dummy variables were defined: LowInc = 1 if total income is less or equal than 75 euros while MidInc = 1 if total income is between 75 and 125 euros. The total income is given by the sum of endowment and wage income (E+ωW).

References

  • Amador FJ (2005) Medidas Alternativas de Bienestar Derivadas de un Modelo de Asignación del Tiempo en un Contexto de Elección Discreta: Teoría y Aplicaciones. PhD Thesis. Departamento de Análisis Económico. Universidad de La Laguna (in Spanish)

  • Amador FJ, González RM, Ortúzar J de D (2008) On confounding preference heterogeneity and income effect in discrete choice models. Network Spatial Econ 8:97–108

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Batley R (2008) On ordinal utility, cardinal utility, and random utility. Theory Decis 64:37–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Akiva M, Lerman S (1985) Discrete choice analysis: theory and applications to travel demand. The MIT, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Bierlaire M (2008) An introduction to BIOGEME Version 1.6, biogeme.epfl.ch

  • Cherchi E (2003) On the microeconomic derivation of the systematic utility function. Working Paper 09/03 Crimm, Università di Cagliari

  • Cherchi E, Ortúzar J de D (2001) Multimodal choice models with mixed RP/SP data: correlation, non-linearities and income effect. 9th World Conference on Transport Research Selected Proceeding, Pergamon-Elsevier (ed.), Netherlands (on CD)

  • Debreu G (1954) Representation of a preference ordering by a numerical function. In: Thrall RM, Coombs CH, Davis RL (eds) Decision processes. New York, John Wiley

    Google Scholar 

  • Jara-Díaz SR (1991) Income and taste in mode choice models: are they surrogates? Transport Res 25B:341–350

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jara-Díaz SR (1998) Time and income in travel demand: towards a microeconomic activity-based theoretical framework. In: Gärling T, Laitila T, Westin K (eds) Theoretical foundations of travel choice modelling. Pergamon, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Jara-Diaz SR (2007) Transport economic theory. Elsevier Science, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Jara-Díaz SR, Farah M (1987) Transport demand and user’s benefits with fixed income: the goods/leisure trade-off revisited. Transport Res 22B:159–171

    Google Scholar 

  • Jara-Díaz SR, Ortúzar J de D (1989) Introducing the expenditure rate in the estimation of mode choice models. J Transport Econ Pol 23:293–308

    Google Scholar 

  • Jara-Díaz SR, Videla J (1989) Detection of income effect in mode choice: theory and application. Transport Res 23B:393–400

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster KJ (1966) A new approach to consumer theory. J Polit Econ 74:132–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marschak J, Becker GM, De Groot MH (1963) Stochastic models of choice behavior. Behav Sci 8:41–55

    Google Scholar 

  • McFadden D (1975) The revealed preferences of a government bureaucracy. Bell J Econ Manag Sci 6:401–416

    Google Scholar 

  • McFadden D (1976) Quantal choice analysis: a survey. Ann Econ Soc Meas 5:363–390

    Google Scholar 

  • Ortuzar J de D, Willumsen LG (2001) Modelling transport. Wiley, Chichester

    Google Scholar 

  • Train K (2003) Discrete choice methods with simulation. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Train K, McFadden D (1978) The goods/leisure trade-off and disaggregate work trip mode choice models. Transport Res 12:349–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varian H (1978) Microeconomic analysis. W. W. Norton and Company, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams HCWL, Ortúzar J de D (1982) Behavioural theories of dispersion and the mis-specification of travel demand models. Transport Res 16B:167–219

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This research was partially done during a stay of the second author at La Laguna funded by the Universidad de La Laguna Programme for Research Support. We would also like to thanks Juan de Dios Ortúzar for his amazing job in improving the clarity of the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Francisco Javier Amador.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Amador, F.J., Cherchi, E. Econometric Effects of Utility Order-Preserving Transformations in Discrete Choice Models. Netw Spat Econ 11, 419–438 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11067-010-9134-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11067-010-9134-7

Keywords

Navigation