The EU climate policies and trading market
The EU climate actions are directed by implementing a sustainable climate and energy policy (Tol 2012), aiming to achieve net-zero greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions by 2050. The current policy includes at least 40% cuts in GHG emissions from 1990 levels, 32% share for renewable energy and 32.5% improvement in energy efficiency. There is a sectoral division between ETS and non-ETS sectors. The ETS covers energy-intensive industries and has set a 43% emission reduction target for 2030 from 2005 level. The non-ETS sectors, which also include the fossil energy consumption of households, endeavor to cut 30% GHG emissions from 2005.
The ETS constitutes an exchange-tradable permits market for firms, characterized by a uniform CO2 price (Venmans 2012). The allocation of allowances is primarily based on free allowances with some auctioning. The Commission estimated that 57% of the total amount of allowances were auctioned during 2013–2020, while the remaining allowances are available for free allocation.Footnote 2 It is predicted that auctioning will become the default method in future allocations (Hepburn et al. 2006). For the non-ETS market, CO2 abatement objectives are based on the so-called “Effort Sharing Decision”, where emission targets for MS adjusted to their economic capacity. Two rounds of burden-sharing were already defined, for the years 2020Footnote 3 and 2030 (European Commission 2016b). Table 1 reports these targets for 2020, 2030 and 2040 for the ETS and the non-ETS sectors.Footnote 4
Table 1 European GHG emissions targets The effectiveness of ETS to reduce emissions in the EU is unquestionable. It has been instrumental for effective mitigation strategies (Muûls et al. 2016). In the first 2 years of implementation, approximately 100 to 200 MtCO2 were abated across all ETS sectors.Footnote 5 ETS significantly reduced Europe’s emission intensity by 3.35% during the second phase, which is 43% than the 2005 level.
There has been no detrimental effect on the economic performance since the first phase of implementation of the EU ETS (Hu et al. 2015; Bel and Joseph 2015). The power and manufacturing industries pass on the additional cost to consumer with relatively insignificant increase in output price. There was a small negative effect on return of capital, but no effect on employment, productivity and investment.Footnote 6
Chinese climate target and emissions trading scheme
As the largest CO2 emitter and the second largest economy in the world, China targets to lower CO2 emissions per unit of GDP by 40 to 45% from the 2005 level by 2020. Beyond 2020, China strives to peak the CO2 emissions in year 2030 or sooner, and to reduce CO2 emissions per unit of GDP by 60 to 65% compared to the 2005 level. The annual emission intensity is targeted to fall to a minimum rate of 3.3% during 2005–2020 and 3.1% during 2020–2030. Following this trend, the emission intensity is assumed to fall to a minimum annual rate of 2.9% during 2030–2040 and at least by 75 to 80% lower from the 2005 level (Table 2).
Table 2 China’s emission intensity targets China’s ETS follows a “Cap-and-Trade” system where a company needs one unit of carbon credits for every ton of GHG emission. The government controls the total amount of carbon emissions and manages the emission quota that could be given for free or by auction and trade with others. China’s national ETS was officially launched in 2017 in the “National Carbon Emissions Trading Market Construction Plan (Power Generation Industry)” report (Lin and Jia 2019; Tang et al. 2020). At present, the market only covers the power industry sectors for its significant CO2 emissions.Footnote 7
In line with the EU, analytical studies on individual implementations of ETS in China generally confirm the effectiveness of emission trading with comparatively minor negative impact on the economy.Footnote 8 ETS helps to effectively reduce China’s emissions with no significant distortion (Wu et al. 2016; Meng et al. 2018; Cao et al. 2019). The implication among sectors are different, with the largest impact on the employment on China’s coal industry (Huang et al. 2019).
Addressing differences and potential markets integration
Integrating both the EU and Chinese trading markets has been a particular interest to further analysis in current research (Heindl and Voigt 2012; Fragkos et al. 2018). Its potential emerges with two factors, the lower abatement cost and the electricity sector (Zeng 2017). A relatively lower abatement cost attracts the EU to consider China as a potential market to offset their permits, while the electricity generation industry has been the largest source of CO2 emission in both regions.
Some studies addressed the economic impacts of this integration despite the focal points only cover the macro perspective in both regions. Details on the national level, particularly for EU MS, are still limited. A relevant analysis on this potential integration is offered by Gavard et al. (2013) by measuring the impact of trading in carbon permits between the EU ETS and Chinese electricity sector. Using the EPPA CGE model, they found the EU carbon price would decrease by more than 76% under condition of unlimited sector trading. The general equilibrium effect dominated the revenue effect to the advantage of the EU, but not China. The latest study by Gavard et al. (2016) also confirms this finding on the opposite welfare impact between China and the EU. Adding the USA to the integrated market, again, advances the EU and enables the USA have welfare improvements. However, China is still worse off.
Another study by Alexeeva and Anger (2016) also confirms positive welfare implications for the EU, but not for its trading partner. Despite not specifically addressing China in the analysis, this paper measures the welfare impacts and trade competitiveness for the EU and non-EU as trading partners. The EU’s economic efficiency losses are diminished by integration, improving the terms of trade. The non-EU partner faces the opposite trade effect with competitiveness losses.
Other notable studies focusing on the sectoral analysis, however, conclude different results. Using the Global Responses to Anthropogenic Change in the Environment (GRACE) model, Liu and Wei (2016) find that the integrated market can help China achieve its renewable energy target accompanied by CO2 emissions and abatement cost reductions. Thus, China is relatively better off by market linkage, while integration will do the opposite for the EU’s renewables. The recent study of Li et al. (2019) also confirms that unlimited linking of EU and Chinese ETSs can benefit the development of clean energy in China, but hinder to meet the EU’s renewable energy target.
Several points can be drawn from the above literature. First, it is vital to review the welfare assessment cost of this potential integration scheme. From the macroeconomic perspective, the EU consistently obtains welfare gains while its trading partners experience positive welfare loss as a result of the linkage. However, this result may differ when observed from EU individual MS as each may differ in their energy structure. Following in importance is the second point, which is the representable level of sectoral aggregation in the model and a highly recursive dynamic model to capture this impact.
Another critical point is the limited trading option when both partners are able to achieve the optimal abatement target and avoid welfare losses. Hübler et al. (2014) points out that limited linking is more feasible in the mid term when both partners can achieve 5% more CO2 emission reduction without additional welfare losses. However, the benefit for China is relatively small given the transfer volume is one third of the EU’s reduction effort.
The last, yet arguably the most fundamental, is the scheme of market integration/ linkage between these two markets. Those analyses on the current literature are based on a general assumption of a market follows other markets,Footnote 9 without addressing other challenges involved with an integrated market. In addition to their differences in cap system, there are other critical factors such as the way emissions are measured and the stringency of allowance systems, which symmetrically affects decisions made between both regions. Therefore, how the linkage should be designed is clearly instrumental.
Integration between China and EU ETS promises positive economical and political impacts. Differences in these two markets, however, could impede this potential linkage. This is fundamental, as each system implicates different key elements in the nature of the carbon market. The first element is the duration of the cap system. It reflects the compliance period and influences both the market expectation and the incentives for investment in the long run. Similar to the EU, China also sets its cap duration annually yet without an official trajectory. Despite successful pilots, the Chinese national cap has not yet been confirmed. Implementing a full national system in China is challenging and, without massive reform, the EU will face higher information cost compared to the pre-linkage scenario (Zeng et al. 2016). This factor should have been considered when developing an integrated scheme for further simulations in this paper, yet for simplicity, it is assumed that information cost will be relatively small and negligible.Footnote 10
A striking distinction can be noticed between the absolute versus the intensity-based cap which impinges on scarcity, the abatement incentives, and variability of the cap. For analytical purposes, the analysis follows the assumption that the cap system will converge into the absolute emission limit in this integrated market. This assumption relies on two instrumental factors. First, there is no fixed emission limit under intensity-based cap, which reflects unreliable price predictability and credibility. A pre-defined cap could be adjusted, as in the case of the pilots, but it is unclear how and when this post adjustment should be made. Second, under economic uncertainty, no fixed abatement can not either ensure the scarcity of allowance or the desired environmental outcome. In contrast, the absolute cap system always ensures this environmental target is met.Footnote 11
In addition to this, both EU and Chinese ETS differ in terms of the industries covered and quota mechanism (Ji et al. 2018). While the energy and heavy chemical industries take part of the EU market, China ETS covers some traditional high energy-consuming and high-emission industries. And China mainly allocated quota free of charge, with only 3% of the quota is distributed by auction or fixed price sale. This is far lower than the EU market where more than 50% allowances were allocated through auction recently. This paper takes these aspects into consideration, yet for simplicity and robustness of the analysis, the new integrated market scheme keeps the assumption that China’s national ETS will be only applied to the electricity sector such as in the pilot project and quotas will be distributed through full auction in both markets.
Another element of differences is the stringency factor and its consistency over time. The EU has set 1.74% annual reduction in power generation, while no defined target for China has been set. To deal with this, the integrated market analysis relates this stringency factor into the Advanced Technology and Renewable Energy Development (AT & RED) projection, following the previous study of (Tang et al. 2018). In addition to the Business as Usual (BAU),Footnote 12 AT & RED represents China’s commitment to peak its emissions before 2030 while incorporating policies to improve the energy efficiency, to promote advanced technologies and to increase the share of renewable electricity generation. Under AT & RED, the CO2 emissions will peak at 4842 MtCO2 in 2023, then decrease to 4755 MtCO2 and to 4203 MtCO2 in 2030 and 2040, respectively. With higher commitment of renewable used in generation, AT & RED predicts a more significant emission reduction, achieving levels under 3000 MtCO2 in 2040 (see Fig. 1).
For further simulations, China’s commitment is divided into two. The AT & RED represents China’s low commitment for electricity generation and assuming lower CO2 marginal abatement cost in electricity generation to factor its high commitment. If additional CO2 emissions reductions are required, the electricity would have to undergo further abatement.Footnote 13
Other significant differences to be addressed include the coverage of the ETS, compliance and monitoring scheme. The integrated market should only cover the direct CO2 emission since the inclusion of indirect CO2 under the current ETS market will face monitoring and accounting difficulties. Given the non-compliance costs are relatively low for China, this linkage market assumes a uniform stringent penalty regime to ensure participants will buy emission allowances instead of paying the fines. Borrowing allowances is considered acceptable and the monitoring scheme is transparent in both regions.
The last point of differences is on the definition of climate objectives which affects the time span on simulation periods. While the European Union has clearly defined its climate policy objectives for 2050, the Chinese goal was officially determined for the year 2030 through its Intended Nationally Determined Contributions (INDC). After year 2030, President Xi Jinping (Xi 2020) announced China’s target to achieve carbon neutrality before year 2060, but short-term targets and followed up regulation remain undefined. This difference in climate policy objectives matters, affecting the assumption of Chinese target post 2030. For development in this paper, further simulations will be limited to year 2040, involving some assumptions on the Chinese target of 2031 to 2040. Analysis post 2040 will be challenging with increasing uncertainties on the design of the Chinese climate policy targets.