Skip to main content
Log in

Structural models of complementary choices

  • Published:
Marketing Letters Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article reviews the rapidly growing literature on structural models of complementary choices. It discusses recent modeling developments and identifies promising areas for future research.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A related definition based on super-additivity comes from Brandenburger et al. (2011). It defines complementarity as value from product A increases with availability of product B.

  2. Mickey Mantle (1931–95, NY Yankees first baseman) famously remarked in his 60s, “If I knew I was going to live this long, I’d have taken better care of myself.”

  3. Similar methods for dynamic discrete choice models include Ching et al. (2009), Norets (2009) and Gallant et al. (2013b).

References

  • Allenby, G., Fennell, G., Huber, J., Eagle, T., Gilbride, T., Horsky, D., Kim, J., Lenk, P., Johnson, R., Ofek, E., Orme, B., Otter, T., & Walker, J. (2005). Adjusting choice models to better predict market behavior. Marketing Letters, 16(3), 197–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anand, B. N., & Khanna, T. (2000). Do firms learn to create value? The case of alliances. Strategic Management Journal, 21(3), 295–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anand, B. N., & Shachar, R. (2011). Advertising, the matchmaker. The RAND Journal of Economics, 42(2), 205–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong, M. (2013). A more general theory of commodity bundling. Journal of Economic Theory, 148(2).

  • Athey, Susan, Scott Stern (1998), An empirical framework for testing theories about complementarity in organizational design. Mimeo

  • Badev, Anton (2013), Discrete games in endogenous networks: theory and policy. Mimeo

  • Berry, S. T., & Waldfogel, J. (2001). Do mergers increase product variety? Evidence from radio broadcasting. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(3), 1009–1025.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry, S., Gandhi, A., & Haile, P. (2013). Connected substitutes and the invertibility of demand. Econometrica, 81(5), 2087–2111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhat, C. (2008). The multiple discrete-continuous extreme value (mdcev) model: role of utility function parameters, identification considerations, and model extensions. Transportation Research Part B, 42, 274–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhat, C.R., Castro, M., & Pinjari, A. R. (2013). “Allowing for Non-Additively Separable and Flexible Utility Forms in Multiple Discrete-Continuous Models,” Technical paper, Department of Civil, Architectural and Environmental Engineering, The University of Texas at Austin.

  • Blevins, J, A. Khwaja, N. Yang (2013), Market share dynamics, size spillovers and industry structure: evidence from hamburger chain expansion, Mimeo

  • Bramoullé, Y., Djebbari, H., & Fortin, B. (2009). “Identification of peer effects through social networks.” Journal of econometrics 150.1, 41–55.

  • Brandenburger, Adam M., Barry J. Nalebuff. Co-opetition. Random House Digital, 2011

  • Bresnahan, T. F., Brynjolfsson, E., & Hitt, L. (2002). Information technology, workplace organization, and the demand for skilled labor: firm-level evidence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(1), 339–376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chan, T. (2006). Estimating a continuous hedonic choice model with an application to demand for soft drinks. RAND Journal of Economics, 37(2).

  • Chandrasekhar, Arun, Matthew Jackson (2012), Tractable and consistent exponential random graph models. Mimeo

  • Ching, A., Imai, S., & Jain, N. (2009). Bayesian estimation of dynamic discrete choice models. Econometrica, 77(6), 1865–1899.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cockburn, I., Henderson, R., & Stern, S. (2000). Untangling the origins of competitive advantage. Strategic Management Journal, 21(10–11), 1123–1145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DePaula, Aureo, Seth Richards-Shubik, Elie Tamer (2011), Inference approaches with network data, Mimeo

  • Derdenger, T., & Kumar, V. (2013). The dynamic effects of bundling as a product strategy. Marketing Science, 32(6), 827–859.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, J., & Shapiro, C. (1990). Horizontal mergers: an equilibrium analysis. The American Economic Review, 107–126

  • Figurelli, L. (2012). Store choice in spatially differentiated markets, Working Paper

  • Gallant, R., H. Hong, A. Khwaja (2013a). The dynamic spillovers of entry: an application to the generic drug industry. Mimeo

  • Gallant, R., H. Hong,, A. Khwaja (2013b), Bayesian estimation of a dynamic game with endogenous, partially observed, serially correlated state. Mimeo

  • Gentzkow, M. (2007). Valuing new goods in a model with complementarities: online newspapers. American Economic Review, 97(3), 713–744.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldsmith-Pinkham, Paul, Guido W. Imbens (2013), Social networks and the identification of peer effects, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics.

  • Groeger, J. (2012). A study of participation in dynamic auctions. Carnegie Mellon University Working Paper

  • Hanemann, W. M. (1984). Discrete/continuous models of demand. Econometrica, 52(3), 541–561.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh, Chih-Sheng, Lung-Fei Lee (2013), A structural modeling approach for network formation and social interactions with applications to students’ friendship choices and selectivity on activities. Mimeo

  • Huang, G., A. Khwaja, K. Sudhir (2012), Short run needs and long term goals: a dynamic model of thirst management. Mimeo

  • Ichniowski, C., & Shaw, K. (1999). The effects of human resource systems on productivity: an international comparison of U.S. and Japanese plants. Management Science, 45(5), 704–722.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ichniowski, C., Shaw, K., & Prennushi, G. (1997). The effects of human resource management practices on productivity: a study of steel finishing lines. The American Economic Review, 87(3), 291–313.

    Google Scholar 

  • Imbens, G., B. Graham, G. Ridder (2010), Complementarity and aggregate implications of assortative matching: a nonparametric analysis. Mimeo

  • Jackson, Matthew O. (2008), Social and economics networks, Princeton.

  • Jeziorski (2013). Estimation of cost synergies from mergers: Application to U.S. Radio, mimeo

  • Khwaja, A. (2010). Estimating willingness to pay for medicare using a dynamic life-cycle model of demand for health insurance. Journal of Econometrics, 156, 130–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khwaja, A. (2013), Health related consumption, health insurance and moral hazard in a dynamic stochastic model of demand for health and endogenous longevity, Mimeo

  • Kim, J., Allenby, G. M., & Rossi, P. E. (2002). Modeling consumer demand for variety. Marketing Science, 21(3), 229–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar, V., Sun, B., & Srinivasan, K. (2014). “Why Do Consumers Contribute to Connected Goods? A Dynamic Model of Competition and Cooperation” Working Paper.

  • Lee, S., & Allenby, G. M. (2013). Modeling indivisible demand, mimeo. Ohio State: University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, S., Kim, J., & Allenby, G. M. (2013a). A direct utility model for asymmetric complements. Marketing: Science.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, C., V. Kumar, S. Gupta (2013b) Designing freemium: a model of consumer usage, upgrade, and referral dynamics, Mimeo

  • Leung, Michael (2013), Two-step estimation of network formation models with incomplete information, Mimeo

  • Manchanda, P., Ansari, A., & Gupta, S. (1999). The ‘shopping basket’: a model for multi-category purchase incidence decisions. Marketing Science, 18, 95–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manski, C. F. (1993). “Identification of endogenous social effects: The reflection problem.” The review of economic studies, 60.3, 531–542.

  • Mele, Angelo (2013), A structural model of segregation in social networks, Mimeo

  • Milgrom, P., & Roberts, J. (1990). Rationalizability, learning, and equilibrium in games with strategic complementarities. Econometrica, 58(6), 1255–1277.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miyauchi, Yuhei (2012), Structural estimation of a pairwise stable network formation with nonnegative externality, Mimeo

  • Musalem, Andres, Wilbur, Kenneth C., Del Sol, Patricio (2013), A parsimonious structural model of individual demand for multiple related goods, Mimeo.

  • Norets, A. (2009). Inference in dynamic discrete choice models with serially correlated unobserved state variables. Econometrica, 77(5), 1665–1682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Novak, S., & Stern, S. (2009). Complementarity among vertical integration decisions: evidence from automobile product development. Management Science, 55(2), 311–332.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pakes, A. (2010). Alternative models for moment inequalities. Econometrica, 78(6), 1783–1822.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Park, M., Town, R. (2012) New evidence on the relationship between managed care and hospital consolidation. Mimeo

  • Porter, Michael E. (1996), What is strategy, Harvard Business Review, November-December, 61–78

  • Porter, M. E., & Siggelkow, N. (2008). Contextual interactions within activity systems and sustainability of competitive advantage. Academy of Management Perspectives, 22(2), 34–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rossi, Peter E., Greg M. Allenby, Robert McCulloch (2005) Bayesian statistics and marketing, John Wiley & Sons

  • Sato, K. (1967). A two-level constant-elasticity-of-substitution production function. The Review of Economic Studies, 34, 201–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Satomura, T., Kim, J., & Allenby, G. M. (2011). Multiple constraint choice models with corner and interior solutions. Marketing Science, 30(3), 481–490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sheng, Shuyang (2012), Identification and estimation of network formation games, Mimeo

  • Shy, O. (2011). A short survey of network economics. Review of Industrial Organization, 38(2), 119–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Song, I., & Chintagunta, P. K. (2007). A discrete-continuous model for multicategory purchase behavior of households. Journal of Marketing Research, 44(4), 595–612.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sriram, S., Chintagunta, P. K., & Agarwal, M. K. (2010). Investigating consumer purchase behavior in related technology product categories. Marketing Science, 29(2), 291–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sweeting, A. (2010). The effects of mergers on product positioning: evidence from the music radio industry. The RAND Journal of Economics, 41(2), 372–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vásquez, Felipe, Michael Hanemann. 2008. Functional forms in discrete/continuous choice models with general corner solution. Mimeo

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kenneth C. Wilbur.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Berry, S., Khwaja, A., Kumar, V. et al. Structural models of complementary choices. Mark Lett 25, 245–256 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-014-9309-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-014-9309-y

Keywords

Navigation