Skip to main content
Log in

Competitive reasons for the Name-Your-Own-Price channel

  • Published:
Marketing Letters Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper shows that the Name-Your-Own-Price (NYOP) business model can help soften competition. When consumers differ in their frictional costs (i.e., the shopping hassle) they experience when bidding at an NYOP retailer, the NYOP format can be a mechanism for differentiating a retailer from a posted-price rival. Beyond providing a motivation for using an NYOP mechanism, competition also has important implications for the optimal structure of the NYOP format. For example, this paper shows that prohibiting rebidding may benefit an NYOP firm by reducing price rivalry.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Hann and Terwiesch (2003) estimate the frictional costs (in euros) for three products, PDAs, CD-RW drives, and MP3 players. The median frictional costs for bids on the three products are 6.08, 4.29, and 3.54, respectively. Standard deviations of costs are 7.57, 4.42, and 3.81. The numbers in the text are averages across these three products converted into dollars (at a rate of euro 1 = 0.90$, which was the exchange rate when the original data were collected).

  2. Other non-posted price mechanisms may also be able to mitigate price competition in this context. However, it is beyond the scope of the current paper to compare the NYOP format to all possible pricing mechanisms.

  3. Fay (2008) and Fay and Xie (2008) provide additional discussion of the role of opacity in market interactions.

  4. There is some evidence that current NYOP sellers have indeed committed to such a decision structure. For example, Priceline determines whether a given bid is accepted using a complicated computer formula which includes a random element (Segan 2005) and employs a “randomizer” program for deciding whether to accept a bid for a hotel room (Malhotra and Desira 2002; Haussman 2001). In particular, rather than setting the threshold price equal to the lowest rate offered by the entire set of hotels that have rooms available, Priceline only compares the bidder’s offer to the rates set by two randomly selected hotels. Such an action is consistent with the speculation in Kannan and Praveen (2001) that Priceline may “deliberately forgo a successful transaction” in order to influence consumers’ expectations, i.e., persuade consumers to bid higher in the future.

  5. Notice that if the second type also believed that the threshold price was drawn from U[0, 101], they would not bid 150, but instead bid 101 or less.

  6. Sequential format choices are not required for the core results of this paper. However, with simultaneous format decisions, multiple equilibria may arise—one in which firm A selects the NYOP format and firm B selects posted prices and one in which firm A selects the posted-price format while firm B selects the NYOP format. Thus, coordination issues (i.e., which equilibria is played) may arise in a simultaneous-choice setting.

  7. While assuming a common reservation value dramatically simplifies the analysis, it is not essential for the paper’s main qualitative results. A more subtle point is that variation in frictional costs is essential for appropriately segmenting consumers. The NYOP mechanism is an effective means of targeting consumers with low frictional costs but not those with low valuations. Thus, to receive the price discrimination effect touted in the literature (e.g., Hann and Terwiesch 2003), variation in frictional costs is essential, but variation in reservation values is not.

  8. In particular, for \(0 < \bar c < \frac{1}{4}\) and \(\bar c > \frac{1}{2}\), the key idea of Proposition 1 continues to hold, i.e., one firm will choose the NYOP form if there is “sufficiently” little brand loyalty. However, the amount of brand loyalty that is “sufficient” to generate this result depends on \(\bar c\). For \(\bar c < \frac{1}{4}\), it is possible for the NYOP format to be chosen in equilibrium even when λ exceeds \(\frac{1}{9}\) (since the cost of bidding on the NYOP channel is not as onerous, on average). But, for \(\bar c > \frac{1}{2}\), the sufficient condition for the NYOP format to be chosen in equilibrium is tighter (since fewer consumers are willing to bid at an NYOP site).

References

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Scott Fay.

Additional information

I wish to thank Randy Bucklin, Rabi Chatterjee, Anne Coughlan, Joel Huber, Xiaoqing Jing, Steve Shugan, Martin Spann, Jinhong Xie, and several anonymous reviewers for their helpful comments. As always, any remaining errors are entirely my own.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Derivation of consumers’ optimal bids when retailer B uses an NYOP format

Retailer B’s loyal consumers can either bid at B’s NYOP site or they can forego bidding. A bid of b is accepted with a probability of b, in which case the consumer gets a net surplus of (1 − b). Thus, the consumer’s expected value from bidding b is:

$${\text{EV}}_{\text{L}} \left( b \right) = \left( {1 - b} \right)b - c_i $$
(8)

The first-order condition (FOC) of this maximization problem is: \(\frac{{\partial {\text{EV}}_{\text{L}} \left( b \right)}}{{\partial b}} = 1 - 2b \equiv 0\). This FOC is satisfied when \(b = \frac{1}{2} \equiv \hat b\) and \({\text{EV}}_{\text{L}} \left( {\hat b} \right)\) is non-negative (so as to induce bidding rather than abstaining) iff \(c_i \leqslant \frac{1}{4} \equiv \hat c\).

Suppose retailer A sells at a posted price of P A . A switcher who purchases at the posted price earns a surplus of (1 − P A ). A switcher can bid at B’s NYOP site if she so chooses. The expected value from placing a bid of b and then purchasing at the posted price if that bid is rejected is:

$${\text{EV}}_{{\text{S1}}} \left( b \right) = \left( {1 - b} \right)b - c_i + \left( {1 - b} \right)\left( {1 - P_A } \right)$$
(9)

Using the FOC, this expected value is maximized when \(b = \hat b_1 \)and weakly exceeds the surplus from buying at the posted price without bidding iff \(c_i \leqslant \hat c_1 \), where \(\hat b_1 \)and \(\hat c_1 \) are defined in Eq. 2.

Now suppose retailer A also uses an NYOP format. If a switcher were to not bid on either site, she would earn a surplus of 0. Another alternative bidding strategy would be to place a bid of b at one of the two sites and then not bid at the other site if this bid were rejected. This strategy generates an expected value given by Eq. 8, which is maximized when \(b = \hat b\), yielding an expected value of \(\frac{1}{4} - c_i \). Finally, a switcher could place a bid of b 1 at one of the two sites and then place a bid of b 2 at the other site if the first bid is rejected. This strategy yields an expected value of:

$${\text{EV}}_{{\text{S2}}} \left( {b_1 {\text{,}}b_2 } \right) = \left( {1 - b_1 } \right)b_1 - c_i + \left( {1 - b_1 } \right)\left[ {\left( {1 - b_2 } \right)b_2 - c_i } \right]$$
(10)

Using the resulting FOCs, the consumer’s expected value is maximized when \(b_1 = \hat b_{11} \) and \(b_2 = \hat b\) where \(\hat b_{11} \) and \(\hat b\) are defined in Eqs. 3 and 1, respectively. This dual-bidding strategy yields a higher expected surplus than the single-bidding strategy \(\forall c_i \leqslant \hat c\). This dual-bidding strategy is weakly superior to not bidding at all iff \(c_i \leqslant \hat c\).

1.2 Derivation of equilibrium prices and profit for each subgame

In accordance with Proposition 1, the remainder of the derivations in the “Appendix” proceeds under the assumptions \(\frac{1}{4} \leqslant \bar c \leqslant \frac{1}{2}\) and \(\lambda <\frac{1}{9}\).

1.2.1 Both firms use posted prices

The loyal-switcher model whereby both firms sell at a posted price is a slightly simplified version of a model which has previously been analyzed by Varian (1980; using the terms “informed” and “uninformed” to describe the two segments). Rather than replicating that entire analysis, below, I simply report the results.

There is no pure-strategy equilibrium to this game. Instead, there is a mixed-strategy equilibrium in prices in which each retailer charges price P with a probability f(P). f(P) = 0 if \(P <\hat P\) or P > 1, where \(\hat P = \frac{\lambda }{{1 - \lambda }}\). On the interval \(\left[ {\hat P{\text{,}}1} \right]\), \({\text{f}}\left( P \right) = \frac{\lambda }{{\left( {1 - 2\lambda } \right)P^2 }}\). Each firm’s expected profit is \(\Pi _A^{{\text{PP,PP}}} = \Pi _B^{{\text{PP,PP}}} = \lambda \).

1.2.2 Firm A uses posted prices; firm B uses an NYOP format

Retailer A chooses its posted price in order to maximize the expected profit given in Eq. 6 (with the profit function for retailer B, \(\Pi _B^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}} \), given by Eq. 5). At the interior solution of \(P_A^{{\text{IS}}} = \sqrt[{\text{3}}]{{\frac{{{\text{2}}\overline {\text{c}} \left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}{{{\text{1}} - {\text{2}}\lambda }}}}\), profit for firm A (who uses a posted price) is \(\Pi _A^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}\left( {{\text{IS}}} \right)} = \frac{{3\left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}{2}\sqrt[{\text{3}}]{{\frac{{\overline {\text{c}} \left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}{{4\left( {{\text{1}} - {\text{2}}\lambda } \right)}}}}\). The profit for firm B is \(\Pi _B^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}\left( {{\text{IS}}} \right)} = \frac{\lambda }{{16\overline {\text{c}} }} + \frac{{1 - {\text{2}}\lambda }}{4}\sqrt[{\text{3}}]{{\frac{{\overline {\text{c}} ^{\text{3}} \left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)^4 }}{{4\left( {{\text{1}} - {\text{2}}\lambda } \right)^4 }}}}\). There is also a potential corner solution at \(P_A^{{\text{CS}}} = 1\). Here, firm A’s profit is \(\Pi _A^{{\text{PP,NYOP(CS)}}} = 1 - \lambda - \frac{{{\text{1}} - {\text{2}}\lambda }}{{{\text{8}}\overline {\text{c}} }}\) and firm B’s profit is \(\Pi _B^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}\left( {{\text{CS}}} \right)} = \frac{{1 - \lambda }}{{{\text{16}}\overline {\text{c}} }}\). Firm A chooses the posted price that yields the highest profit:

$$\Pi _A^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}} = {\text{Max}}\left[ {\Pi _A^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}\left( {{\text{IS}}} \right)} {\text{,}}\Pi _A^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}\left( {{\text{CS}}} \right)} } \right]{\text{ = }}\left\{ {\matrix {\frac{{3\left( {{\text{1 - }}\lambda } \right)}}{2}\sqrt[{\text{3}}]{{\frac{{\overline {\text{c}} \left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}{{4\left( {{\text{1}} - {\text{2}}\lambda } \right)}}}}} \hfill {{\text{if }}\overline {\text{c}} \leqslant \frac{{{\text{1}} - 2\lambda }}{{{\text{2}}\left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}} \hfill \\ {1 - \lambda - \frac{{{\text{1}} - {\text{2}}\lambda }}{{{\text{8}}\overline {\text{c}} }}} \hfill {{\text{if }}\overline {\text{c}} > \frac{{{\text{1}} - 2\lambda }}{{{\text{2}}\left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}} \hfill \ } \right.$$
(11)

1.2.3 Both firms use a NYOP format

When both retailers use an NYOP format, profit is given by Eq. 7. Taking these integrals,

$$\Pi _A^{{\text{NYOP,NYOP}}} = \Pi _B^{{\text{NYOP,NYOP}}} = \frac{{2 - \lambda }}{{48\overline c }}$$
(12)

1.3 Derivation of the optimal market format—proposition 1

For (PP, NYOP) to be a subgame perfect Nash equilibrium, then firm B must earn greater profit by choosing the NYOP format rather than the posted-price format. One can calculate the difference in profit under these two formats as:

$$\Pi _B^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}} - \Pi _B^{{\text{PP,PP}}} {\text{ = }}\left\{ {\matrix {\frac{{1 - {\text{2}}\lambda }}{4}\sqrt[{\text{3}}]{{\frac{{\overline {\text{c}} ^{\text{3}} \left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)^4 }}{{4\left( {{\text{1}} - {\text{2}}\lambda } \right)^4 }}}} - \lambda + \frac{\lambda }{{16\overline c }}} \hfill {{\text{if }}\overline {\text{c}} \leqslant \frac{{{\text{1}} - 2\lambda }}{{{\text{2}}\left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}} \hfill \\ {\frac{{1 - \lambda }}{{16\overline c }} - \lambda } \hfill {{\text{if }}\overline c > \frac{{{\text{1}} - 2\lambda }}{{{\text{2}}\left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}} \hfill \ } \right.$$
(13)

This difference in the bottom term is positive as long as \(1 > \lambda \left( {1 + {\text{16}}\overline {\text{c}} } \right)\) or \(\lambda < \frac{1}{{1 + {\text{16}}\overline {\text{c}} }}\). Note that this condition will be met when \(\lambda <\frac{1}{9}\) (since \(\overline {\text{c}} < \frac{1}{2}\)). Furthermore, the top term is decreasing in \(\overline {\text{c}} \). Thus, on the range, \(\overline c \in \left[ {\frac{{\text{1}}}{{\text{4}}}{\text{,}}\frac{{{\text{1}} - 2\lambda }}{{{\text{2}}\left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}} \right]\), the difference in profit \(\left( {\Pi _B^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}} - \Pi _B^{{\text{PP,PP}}} } \right)\)is minimized at \(\overline c = \frac{{{\text{1}} - 2\lambda }}{{{\text{2}}\left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}\). When \(\overline c = \frac{{{\text{1}} - 2\lambda }}{{{\text{2}}\left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}\), \(\Pi _B^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}} - \Pi _B^{{\text{PP,PP}}} = \frac{{\left( {1 - \lambda } \right)^2 \left( {1 - 5\lambda } \right)}}{{12\left( {1 - 2\lambda } \right)^2 }}\), which is positive for all \(\lambda <\frac{1}{5}\). Therefore, \(\lambda <\frac{1}{9}\) is a sufficient condition for retailer B to prefer the NYOP format over a posted-price format.

In addition, for (PP, NYOP) to be a subgame perfect Nash equilibrium, firm A must earn greater profit by choosing the posted-price format rather than the NYOP format. The preceding analysis shows that if firm A chooses the posted-price format, then firm B will select the NYOP format. To determine firm A’s profit from selecting the NYOP format instead, one needs to anticipate whether firm B would best respond by selecting the posted-price format or the NYOP format. Specifically, one can calculate:

$$\Pi _B^{{\text{NYOP,PP}}} - \Pi _B^{{\text{NYOP,NYOP}}} {\text{ = = }}\left\{ {\matrix {\frac{{3\left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}{2}\sqrt[{\text{3}}]{{\frac{{\overline {\text{c}} \left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}{{4\left( {{\text{1}} - {\text{2}}\lambda } \right)}}}} - \frac{{2 - \lambda }}{{48\overline {\text{c}} }}} \hfill {{\text{if }}\overline {\text{c}} \leqslant \frac{{{\text{1}} - 2\lambda }}{{{\text{2}}\left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}} \hfill \\ {1 - \lambda - \frac{{{\text{8}} - {\text{13}}\lambda }}{{{\text{48}}\overline {\text{c}} }}} \hfill {{\text{if }}\overline c > \frac{{{\text{1}} - 2\lambda }}{{{\text{2}}\left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}} \hfill \ } \right.$$
(14)

Numerical calculations verify that this difference is positive over the entire relevant parameter range. Therefore, firm B will choose the posted-price format if firm A has chosen the NYOP format. For (PP, NYOP) to be a subgame perfect Nash equilibrium, we must have \(\Pi _A^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}} \geqslant \Pi _A^{{\text{NYOP,PP}}} \) We can show

$$\Pi _A^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}} - \Pi _A^{{\text{NYOP,PP}}} {\text{ = }}\left\{ {\matrix {\frac{{10\overline {\text{c}} \left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)\sqrt[{\text{3}}]{{2\overline {\text{c}} \left( {1 - \lambda } \right)}} - \sqrt[{\text{3}}]{{1 - 2\lambda }}}}{{{\text{16}}\overline {\text{c}} \sqrt[{\text{3}}]{{1 - 2\lambda }}}}} \hfill {{\text{if }}\overline {\text{c}} \leqslant \frac{{{\text{1}} - 2\lambda }}{{{\text{2}}\left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}} \hfill \\ {1 - \lambda - \frac{{{\text{3}} - {\text{5}}\lambda }}{{{\text{16}}\overline {\text{c}} }}} \hfill {{\text{if }}\overline {\text{c}} > \frac{{{\text{1}} - 2\lambda }}{{{\text{2}}\left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}} \hfill \ } \right.$$
(15)

For both the upper and lower expressions of Eq. 15, the difference, \(\Pi _A^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}} - \Pi _A^{{\text{NYOP,PP}}} \), is increasing in \(\overline c \). Thus, the minima over the two ranges are reached at \(\overline c = \frac{1}{4}\) and \(\overline c = \frac{{{\text{1}} - 2\lambda }}{{{\text{2}}\left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)}}\), respectively. At these minimizing points, the differences, \(\Pi _A^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}} - \Pi _A^{{\text{NYOP,PP}}} \), are \(\frac{{5\left( {{\text{1}} - \lambda } \right)\sqrt[{\text{3}}]{{4\left( {1 - \lambda } \right)}} - 4\lambda \sqrt[{\text{3}}]{{1 - 2\lambda }}}}{{{\text{16}}\sqrt[{\text{3}}]{{1 - 2\lambda }}}}\) and \(\frac{{\left( {1 - \lambda } \right)\left( {5 - 11\lambda } \right)}}{{8\left( {1 - 2\lambda } \right)}}\), respectively. These values are positive for all \(\lambda <\frac{1}{9}\).

1.4 Incentive to allow rebids

Customers who are loyal to retailer B (who uses the NYOP format) can place up to two bids. The optimal bidding strategy is:

$$\left\{ {\matrix {{\text{bid }}b_{12} {\text{, then bid }}b_{22} {\text{ if }}b_{12} {\text{ is rejected}}} \hfill {{\text{if 0}} \leqslant c_i \leqslant c_2 } \hfill {} \hfill \\ {{\text{place a single bid of }}\hat b} \hfill {{\text{if }}c_2 <c_i \leqslant \hat c} \hfill {{\text{where}}b_{12} = \frac{{1 + 2c_i }}{3}{\text{,}}b_{22} = \frac{{2 + c_i }}{3}{\text{,}}c_2 = \frac{{2 - \sqrt 3 }}{2}} \hfill \\ {{\text{do not bid at all}}} \hfill {{\text{if }}c_i >\hat c} \hfill {} \hfill \ } \right.$$
(16)

For the switchers, the optimal bidding strategy is:

$$\left\{ {\matrix {{\text{bid }}\hat b_{12} {\text{, then bid }}\hat b_{22} {\text{ if }}\hat b_{12} {\text{ is rejected; purchase at }}P_A {\text{ if }}\hat b_{12} {\text{ is rejected}}} \hfill {{\text{if 0}} \leqslant c_i \leqslant \hat c_2 } \hfill {} \hfill \\ {{\text{place a single bid of }}\hat b_1 {\text{; purchase at }}P_A {\text{ if }}\hat b_1 {\text{ is rejected}}} \hfill {{\text{if }}\hat c_2 <c_i \leqslant \hat c_1 } \hfill {{\text{where }}\hat b_{12} = \frac{{P_A + 2c_i }}{3},\hat b_{22} = \frac{{2P_A + c_i }}{3},\hat c_2 = \frac{{3 - P_A - \sqrt {9 - 6P_A } }}{2}} \hfill \\ {{\text{purchase at }}P_A {\text{ without bidding at all}}} \hfill {{\text{if }}c_i >\hat c_1 } \hfill {} \hfill \ } \right.$$
(17)

The following analysis proceeds under the assumption that \({\text{ }}\overline c \geqslant \frac{{1 - 2\lambda }}{{2\left( {1 - \lambda } \right)}}\) and \(\lambda \leqslant \frac{1}{9}\). These restrictions ensure that, when retailer B (i.e., the NYOP firm) restricts consumers to a single bid, retailer A selects a posted price P A  = 1. The equilibrium expected profit for each firm is:

$$\Pi _A^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}\left( {1{\text{ bid}}} \right)} = 1 - \lambda - \frac{{1 - 2\lambda }}{{8\overline c }}$$
(18)
$$\Pi _B^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}\left( {1{\text{ bid}}} \right)} = \frac{{1 - \lambda }}{{16\overline c }}$$
(19)

If retailer A allows consumers to rebid if their initial bid is rejected, then the profits for the two firms are given by:

$$\Pi _A^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}\left( {{\text{2 bids}}} \right)} = P_A \left\lceil {1 - \lambda - \left( {1 - 2\lambda } \right)\left( {\int\limits_{c_i = 0}^{\hat c_2 } {\int\limits_{P_{{\text{NYOP}}} = 0}^{\hat b_{22} } {{\text{f}}\left( {c_i } \right){\text{d}}P_{{\text{NYOP}}} {\text{ d}}c_i } } + \int\limits_{c_i = \hat c_2 }^{\hat c_1 } {\int\limits_{P_{{\text{NYOP}}} = 0}^{\hat b_1 } {{\text{f}}\left( {c_i } \right){\text{d}}P_{{\text{NYOP}}} {\text{ d}}c_i } } } \right)} \right\rceil $$
(20)
$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _B^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}\left( {{\text{2 bids}}} \right)} = \lambda \left[ {\int\limits_{c_i = 0}^{c_2 } {\left( {\int\limits_{P_{{\text{NYOP}}} = 0}^{b_{12} } {b_{12} {\text{f}}\left( {c_i } \right){\text{d}}P_{{\text{NYOP}}} } + \int\limits_{P_{{\text{NYOP}}} = b_{12} }^{b_{22} } {b_{22} {\text{f}}\left( {c_i } \right){\text{d}}P_{{\text{NYOP}}} } } \right){\text{d}}c_i + } \int\limits_{c_i = c_2 }^{\hat c} {\int\limits_{P_{NYOP} = 0}^{\hat b} {\hat b{\text{f}}\left( {c_i } \right){\text{d}}P_{{\text{NYOP}}} } {\text{d}}c_i } } \right] \\ + \left( {1 - 2\lambda } \right)\left[ {\int\limits_{c_i = 0}^{\hat c_2 } {\left( {\int\limits_{P_{{\text{NYOP}}} = 0}^{\hat b_{12} } {\hat b_{12} {\text{f}}\left( {c_i } \right){\text{d}}P_{{\text{NYOP}}} } + \int\limits_{P_{{\text{NYOP}}} = \hat b_{12} }^{\hat b_{22} } {\hat b_{22} {\text{f}}\left( {c_i } \right){\text{d}}P_{{\text{NYOP}}} } } \right){\text{d}}c_i + } \int\limits_{c_i = \hat c_2 }^{\hat c_1 } {\int\limits_{P_{{\text{NYOP}}} = 0}^{\hat b_1 } {\hat b_1 {\text{f}}\left( {c_i } \right){\text{d}}P_{{\text{NYOP}}} } {\text{d}}c_i } } \right] \\ \end{aligned} $$
(21)

Retailer A chooses P A to maximize Eq. 20. The closed-form solution is extremely complex. But Fig. 2 provides an example that verifies the claim in Proposition 2. In particular, when λ = 0.05, \(\Pi _B^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}\left( {1{\text{ bid}}} \right)} >\Pi _B^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}\left( {2{\text{ bids}}} \right)} \) for \(\overline c \in \left[ {\frac{9}{{19}},0.476} \right]\).

Furthermore, one can verify that in the absence of this strategic effect on prices (i.e., that P A is lower when rebidding is allowed), the NYOP firm is always more profitable when rebidding is allowed. In particular,

$$\left( {\left. {\Pi _B^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}\left( {{\text{2 bids}}} \right)} } \right|P_A = 1} \right) - \left( {\left. {\Pi _B^{{\text{PP,NYOP}}\left( {{\text{1 bid}}} \right)} } \right|P_A = 1} \right) = \frac{{1,605 - 882\sqrt 3 + \left( {214 - 156\sqrt 3 } \right)\lambda }}{{6,912\overline c }} \approx \frac{{77.3 - 56.2\lambda }}{{6{\text{,}}912\overline c }} > 0$$
(22)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Fay, S. Competitive reasons for the Name-Your-Own-Price channel. Mark Lett 20, 277–293 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-009-9070-9

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-009-9070-9

Keywords

Navigation