Skip to main content
Log in

The Silence of the Lambdas: Deterring Incapacitation Research

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Quantitative Criminology Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This essay provides an economist’s perspective on criminological research into incapacitation effects on crime. Our central argument is that criminologists would do well to substantially scale back the enterprise of trying to estimate the various behavioral parameters central to a micro-level approach to measuring incapacitation effects, including the annual rate of offending outside of prison (λ) and the lengths of criminal careers. One problem with this line of research is practical: for example, mean estimates of self-reported criminal activity by incarcerated prisoners are quite sensitive to reports by the most criminally active offenders. But the larger concern is conceptual—the incapacitation effects from a given change in sentencing policy may be undermined by the possibility of replacement effects, and at the same time omit other benefits that may arise from deterrent effects on crime. A more promising approach is to identify plausibly exogenous changes in sentencing policy in order to estimate the net impact on crime from the combined effects of incapacitation, deterrence and replacement.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Others have also pointed out the problems with the incapacitation literature in criminology; see for example Zimring and Hawkins (1995) and Donohue and Siegelman (1998). Yet the interest in estimating pure incapacitation effects in criminology persists, perhaps in part because criminologists do not accept the conceptual challenges posed by the possibility of deterrence and replacement effects.

  2. Jeffrey Smith reminds us that if there are diminishing marginal returns to any activity then the optimal research portfolio will include both pure incapacitation studies and “natural experiment” studies. Given the relative rarity of criminological studies that attempt to estimate the net effects on crime from incapacitation, deterrence and replacement using plausibly exogenous natural experiments, there is room for a substantial shift in research activities from the former to the latter.

  3. BCA requires that benefits and costs be converted to a common dollar metric. This is the approach that Becker (1968) took in articulating the modern economic framework for analyzing social policy toward crime and that Ehrlich (1981) took in articulating the first economic model distinguishing deterrence and incapacitation. All subsequent economic research on crime has also adopted this approach (e.g., Donohue and Siegelman 1998). This metric is imperfect because important aspects of human experience, such as emotions, do not translate well into monetary equivalents.

  4. For example as Cook (1980) notes, experience within one’s social network provides a plausible alternative mechanism for deriving information about sentencing policies.

  5. When the Earned Income Tax Credit increases the after-tax wage at the bottom of the income distribution there is a resulting change in labor supply by low-income workers (Eissa and Liebman,1996). When parents have a strong tax incentive to have their babies before January 1, there is an increase in the likelihood that children are born during the last week of December rather than first week of January (Dickert-Conlin and Chandra 1999). When malpractice liability declines, doctors are less likely to practice defensive medicine (Kessler and McClellan 1996). When the costs of obtaining an abortion are reduced through legalization, abortion rates increase (Ananat et al. 2006).

  6. Note also that another potential mechanism by which a prison policy may influence the crime rate is the extent of private precautions (Philipson and Posner 1996). The evidence on this point is extremely limited.

  7. Perhaps too obvious to mention is that the largest opportunity cost is often the net benefit of the alternative policy that could have been pursued in lieu of the chosen policy. If for example the marginal $1 billion in the federal government goes to new prisons rather than the NIH then the opportunity cost of the marginal expansion to federal prisons could in principle be the failure to cure some dreadful disease.

  8. Not all criminologists believe that research on lambda is useful. For example, Laub and Sampson (2001) characterize this research as having attained a “point of stagnation ... because of its narrow focus on measurement and policy.”

  9. The alternative approach of relying on administrative arrest data is widely recognized to under-state criminal activity, and any effort to project from arrests to crimes will employ some inflation factor that necessarily requires some use of survey reports about criminal activity.

  10. Donohue and Siegelman (1998) make the parallel point about comparing the stock of inmates and the flow of inmates who are about to be released. Offenders with shorter sentences are those more likely to be released, and their offending rates are surely lower than those who receive longer sentences. The average lambda of inmates will therefore be a biased estimate of the offending rate of the marginal releasee and will overstate the benefit of delaying release dates.

  11. While some criminologists, such as Canela-Cacho et al. (1997), have focused on selection as offenders enter the criminal justice system and filter through its stages, less often have criminologists developed estimates for offenders who are filtering out of the system.

  12. See for example the discussion of Ehrlich’s (1973) seminal work by the National Research Council’s report on the early deterrence literature (Blumstein et al. 1978).

  13. As Meyer (1995, p. 151) notes, “[t]he natural experiment approach emphasizes the general issue of understanding the sources of variation used to estimate the key parameters ... If one cannot experimentally control the variation one is using, one should understand its source.”

  14. Those states in which overcrowding lawsuits have been filed at all are not systematically different from other states in the sense that such cases have been filed in almost every state in the nation (plus DC).

  15. Federal as well as state court decisions can sometimes provide sources of useful natural experiments, as for example occurred when the US Supreme Court’s Roe v. Wade decision changed the “cost” of abortion nationwide. See Ananat et al. (2006) for a summary of this research.

  16. For example Ludwig and Cook (2000) take advantage of the fact that the Brady Act’s requirements for gun-dealer background checks and waiting periods took effect in 1994 in some states but not others. State fixed effects help account for the fact that states affected and not affected by Brady may be systematically different with respect to permanently higher or lower rates of crime, while the fact that the timing of the Brady Act’s provisions were determined by the federal government rather than local states helps overcome concerns about endogeneity in the timing of the policy implementation.

  17. Why crime rates would increase at the age of majority in systems with the most punitive juvenile justice systems is not clear, but could be driven in part by whatever factors cause offending rates to increase in general by age starting in early adolescence.

  18. Recently, economists have taken a step in the direction of evaluating the ex ante benefits of crime control by employing contingent valuation methods to estimate the willingness-to-pay for crime reductions. In this approach, a survey asks individuals how much they would be willing to pay in order to achieve a particular policy outcome, here reductions in crime, by essentially constructing a hypothetical “market” situation. An advantage of this approach is that the responses reflect ex ante expectations of the benefits that are anticipated to accrue rather than ex post attempts to compensate victims. Also, the responses also measure the respondent’s fear of victimization as well as concern for others, such as family and the broader community, which may not correlate with the risk of victimization. Using this method, Cook and Ludwig (2001) estimated that the average household was willing to pay more than $200 to reduce gun violence by 30%, and this implies a willingness to pay about $1 million to prevent each gun injury. Cohen et al. (2004) using similar methods estimated willingness to pay to prevent crime of approximately $25,000 per burglary, $232,000 per armed robbery, and $9.7 million per murder.

References

  • Ananat EO, Gruber J, Levine PB, Staiger D (2006) Abortion and selection. NBER Working Paper 12150, Cambridge, MA

  • Angrist JD, Krueger AB (2001) Instrumental variables and the search for identification: from supply and demand to natural experiments. J Econ Perspect 15(4):69–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1968) Crime and punishment: an economic approach. J Polit Econ 76(2):169–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black D, Nagin DS (1998) Do ‘Right-to-Carry’ laws reduce violent crime? J Legal Stud 27:209–219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blumstein A, Cohen J, Nagin D (eds) (1978) Deterrence and incapacitation: estimating the effects of criminal sanctions on crime rates. National Academy of Sciences Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Bushway S, Reuter P (2005) Collaborating with economists. The Criminologist. January, 2005

  • Canela-Cacho JE, Blumstein A, Cohen J (1997) Relationship between the offending frequency (λ) of imprisoned and free offenders. Criminology 35:133–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen MA, Rust RT, Steen S, Tidd ST (2004) Willingness-to-pay for crime control programs. Criminology 42(1):89–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook PJ (1980) Research in criminal deterrence: laying the groundwork for the second decade. Crime and justice: an annual review of research. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 211–268

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook PJ (1986a) The demand and supply of criminal opportunities. In: Tonry M, Morris N (eds) Crime and justice: an annual review of research. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 1–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook PJ (1986b) Criminal incapacitation effects considered in an adaptive choice framework. In: Cornish D, Clarke R (eds) The reasoning criminal. Springer Verlag, New York, pp 202–216

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook PJ, Ludwig J (2000) Gun violence: the real costs. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Cook PJ, Ludwig J (2001) The costs and benefits of reducing gun violence. Harvard Health Pol Rev 2(2):23–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Dickert-Conlin S, Chandra A (1999) Taxes and the timing of births. J Polit Econ 107(1):161–177

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donohue JJ III (2003) The impact of concealed-carry laws. In: Ludwig J, Cook PJ (eds) Evaluating gun policy brookings institution press, Washington, DC, pp 287–344

  • Donohue JJ III, Siegelman P (1998) Allocating resources among prisons and social programs in the battle against crime. J Legal Stud 27(1):1–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doob AN, Webster CM (2003) Sentence severity and crime: accepting the null hypothesis. Crime and justice: an annual review of research. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 143–195

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich I (1973) Participation in illegitimate activities: a theoretical and empirical investigation. J Polit Econ 81(3):521–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich I (1981) On the usefulness of controlling individuals: an economic analysis of rehabilitation, incapacitation and deterrence. Am Econ Rev LXXII:307–322

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich I (1996) Crime, punishment and the market for offenses. J Econ Perspect X:43–68

    Google Scholar 

  • Eissa N, Liebman JB (1996) Labor supply response to the earned income tax credit. Q J Econ 111(2):605–637

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson RC, Raphael S (2006) The effects of male incarceration dynamics on AIDS infection rates among African-American women and men. Working Paper, University of California at Berkeley

  • Kessler D, McClellan M (1996) Do doctors practice defensive medicine? Q J Econ 111(2):353–390

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kessler D, Levitt SD (1999) Using sentence enhancements to distinguish between deterrence and incapacitation. J Law Econ 42(1):343–363

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laub JH, Sampson RJ (2001) Understanding desistence from crime. crime and justice: an annual review of research. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 1–69

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee DS, McCrary J (2005) Crime, punishment, and myopia. NBER Working Paper 11491, Cambridge, MA

  • Levitt SD (1996) The effect of prison population size on crime rates: evidence from prison overcrowding. Q J Econ 111(2):319–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt SD (1998a) Why do increased arrest rates appear to reduce crime: deterrence, incapacitation, or measurement error? Econ Inq 36(3):353–372

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt SD (1998b) Juvenile crime and punishment. J Polit Econ 106(6):1156–1185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt SD (2002) Deterrence. In: Wilson JQ, Petersilia J (eds) Crime: public policies for crime control. ICS Press, Oakland, CA

    Google Scholar 

  • Levitt SD (2006) The case of the critics who missed the point: a reply to Webster et al. Criminol Public Pol 5(3):449–460

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt SD, Kessler D (1999) Using sentence enhancements to distinguish between deterrence and incapacitation. J L Econ 42(1-Part 2):343–364

    Google Scholar 

  • Ludwig J, Cook PJ (2000) Homicide and suicide rates associated with the brady handgun violence prevention act. J Am Med Assoc 284(5):585–591

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maltz MD (1999) Bridging the gaps in police crime data. NCJ 176365. Bureau of Justice Statistics, Washington, DC

  • Meyer BD (1995) Natural and quasi-experiments in economics. J Bus Econ Stat 13(2):151–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nagin DS (1978) General deterrence: a review of the empirical evidence. In: Blumstein A, Cohen J, Nagin D (eds) Deterrence and incapacitation: estimating the effects if criminal sanctions on crime rates. National Academy of Sciences Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Nagin DS (1998) Criminal deterrence research at the outset of the twenty-first century. crime and justice: an annual review of research. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 1–42

    Google Scholar 

  • Pampel FC, Williams KR (2000) Intimacy and homicide: compensating for missing data in the SHR. Criminology 38(2):661–680

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Philipson T, Posner RA (1996) The economic epidemiology of crime. J Law Econ 39(2):405–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piquero A, Blumstein A (2007) Does incapacitation reduce crime? J Quant Criminol 22, doi: 10.1007/s10940-007-9030-6

  • Piquero AR, Farrington DP, Blumstein A (2003) The career criminal paradigm. Crime and justice: an annual review of research. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 359–506

    Google Scholar 

  • Raphael S, Ludwig J (2003) Do prison sentence enhancements reduce crime? The case of project exile. In: Ludwig J, Cook PJ (eds) Evaluating gun policy. Brookings, Washington, DC, pp 251–286

    Google Scholar 

  • Sherman LW (2002) Fair and effective policing. In: Wilson JQ, Petersilia J (eds) Crime: public policies for crime control. ICS Press, Oakland, CA

    Google Scholar 

  • Webster CM, Doob AN, Zimring F (2005) Proposition 8 and crime rates in California: the case of the disappearing deterrent. Criminol Public Pol 5(3):417–448

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wiersema B, Loftin C, McDowall D (2000) A comparison of supplementary homicide reports and national vital statistics system homicide estimates for U.S. counties. Hom Stud 4(4):317–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williams KR, Flewelling RL (1987) Family, acquaintance, and stranger homicide: alternative procedures for rates calculations. Criminology 25(3):543–560

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zimring FE, Hawkins GJ (1973) Deterrence: the legal threat in crime control. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Zimring FE, Hawkins GJ (1988) The new mathematics of imprisonment. Crime Delinq 34:425–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zimring FE, Hawkins GJ (1995) Incapacitation: penal confinement and restraint of crime. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas J. Miles.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Miles, T.J., Ludwig, J. The Silence of the Lambdas: Deterring Incapacitation Research. J Quant Criminol 23, 287–301 (2007). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10940-007-9031-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10940-007-9031-5

Keywords

Navigation