Skip to main content
Log in

A General Model of Subjective Value and Stimulus-Intensity-Sensitive Hedonic Editing Strategy

  • Research Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Happiness Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Subjective value is foundational to decision-making processes and people's sense of happiness. To better represent decision-makers' psychological characteristics when subjective value is formed, we establish an attention-and-reference-dependent subjective value model by simultaneously considering the absolute subjective value, relative subjective value, and attention distribution. Our model provides researchers with a theoretical tool for explaining, predicting, and adjusting decision behaviors. Additionally, to maximize the total experienced subjective value brought by multiple events, we compare hedonic editing strategies and demonstrate that the optimal hedonic editing strategy is sensitive to the stimulus intensity. This stimulus-intensity-sensitive strategy is contrary to the hedonic editing strategy inferred from the prospect theory value function when stimulus intensity is relatively small. The results of this study enrich transaction utility theory and expectation-disconfirmation theory and can guide decision-makers in enhancing happiness by rationally dealing with gains and losses.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Data Availability

Not applicable.

Code Availability

Not applicable.

Notes

  1. In our formulation, golfers do not consistently deliver maximum effort for each putt. Golfers may devote different amounts of effort to their putts throughout the Tournament. This conceptualization is consistent with previous works, which found that rather than playing consistently across every hole, golfers' performance varies according to the incentives and pressures they face (Jennifer, 2011; Ozbeklik & Smith, 2017; Elmore & Urbaczewski, 2021).

  2. For simplicity, Pope & Schweitzer start by assuming that if a golfer misses his first putt, he makes his following putt and earns a lower score x-1 His utility function is: \(U = \left[ { f \left( e \right) + \varepsilon } \right]V \left( x \right) + \left[ {1 - f \left( e \right) - \varepsilon } \right]V \left( {x {-}1} \right) - \cos t\left( e \right)\). Here e is the effort level, f(e) is the shot accuracy, \(\varepsilon\) is an error term, and V(\(x\)) is the value function under the score x. We can see there exists a unique optimum (but not maximum) effort level e that the golfer could generate a maximum utility.

References

  • Barberis, N., & Xiong, W. (2012). Realization utility. Journal of Financial Economics, 104(2), 251–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhatia, S., & Golman, R. (2019). Attention and reference dependence. Decision, 6(2), 145–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordalo, P., Gennaioli, N., & Shleifer, A. (2012a). Salience in experimental tests of the endowment effect. The American Economic Review, 102(3), 47–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordalo, P., Gennaioli, N., & Shleifer, A. (2012b). Salience theory of choice under risk. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127(3), 1243–1285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bower, G. H. (1961). A contrast effect in differential conditioning. Journal of Experimental Psychology, 62(2), 196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chai, J. (2021). A model of ambition, aspiration and happiness. European Journal of Operational Research, 288(2), 692–702.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Churchill, G. A., Jr., & Surprenant, C. (1982). An investigation into the determinants of customer satisfaction. Journal of Marketing Research, 19, 491–504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowley, E. (2008). The perils of hedonic editing. Journal of Consumer Research, 35(1), 71–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dehaene, S. (2003). The neural basis of the weber-fechner law: a logarithmic mental number line. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 7(4), 145–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elmore, R., & Urbaczewski, A. (2021). Loss aversion in professional golf. Journal of Sports Economics, 22(2), 202–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Embree, L., & James, W. (1983). The principles of psychology. Philosophy and Phenomenological Research, 44(1).

  • Fan, L., & Suh, Y.-H. (2014). Why do users switch to a disruptive technology? an empirical study based on expectation-disconfirmation theory. Information & Management, 51(2), 240–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fishburn, P., & Luce, R. (1996). Joint receipt and thaler’s hedonic editing rule. Mathematical Social Sciences, 1(31), 52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grabenhorst, F., & Rolls, E. T. (2009). Different representations of relative and absolute subjective value in the human brain. NeuroImage, 48(1), 258–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grant, A., Johnstone, D., & Kwon, O. K. (2021). A cumulative prospect theory explanation of gamblers cashing-out. Journal of Mathematical Psychology, 102, 102534.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imas, A. (2016). The realization effect: Risk-taking after realized versus paper losses. American Economic Review, 106(8), 2086–2109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ingersoll, J. E., & Jin, L. J. (2013). Realization utility with reference-dependent preferences. Review of Financial Studies, 26(3), 723–767.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, J. G., & Busemeyer, J. R. (2016). A computational model of the attention process in risky choice. Decision, 3(4), 254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. (1992). Reference points, anchors, norms, and mixed feelings. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 51(2), 296–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Thaler, R. H. (2006). Anomalies: utility maximization and experienced utility. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(1), 221–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: Analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (2000). Choices, values and frames. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Wakker, P. P., & Sarin, R. (1997). Back to bentham? Explorations of experienced utility. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), 375–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kellen, M., & Leaf, V. B. (2020). Salience theory of mere exposure: Relative exposure increases liking, extremity, and emotional intensity. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 118(6), 1118–1145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knetsch, J. L., Tang, F. F., & Thaler, R. H. (2001). The endowment effect and repeated market trials: Is the Vickrey auction demand revealing? Experimental Economics, 4(3), 257–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koszegi, B., & Rabin, M. (2006). A model of reference-dependent preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4), 1133–1165.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehenkari, M. (2009). The hedonic editing hypothesis: evidence from the finnish stock market. Journal of Behavioral Finance, 10(1), 9–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, N., Cui, H., Zhu, C., Zhang, X., & Su, L. (2016). Grey preference analysis of indoor environmental factors using sub-indexes based on Weber/Fechner’s law and predicted mean vote. Indoor and Built Environment, 25(8), 1197–1208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Linville, P. W., & Fischer, G. W. (1991). Preferences for separating or combining events. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 60(1), 5–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lyon, D. M. (1923). Does the reaction to adrenalin obey Weber’s law? Journal of Pharmacology & Experimental Therapeutics, 21, 229–235.

    Google Scholar 

  • March, J. G. (1988). Variable risk preferences and adaptive aspirations. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 9(1), 5–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masatlioglu, Y., Nakajima, D., & Ozbay, E. Y. (2012). Revealed attention. American Economic Review, 102(5), 2183–2205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Masatlioglu, Y., & Ok, E. A. (2014). A canonical model of choice with initial endowments. Review of Economic Studies, 81(2), 851–883.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Messick, D. M., & Sentis, K. P. (1985). Estimating social and nonsocial utility functions from ordinal data. European Journal of Social Psychology, 15(4), 389–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mourao, P. J. R. (2012). The weber-fechner law and public expenditures impact to the win-margins at parliamentary elections. Prague Economic Papers, 21(3), 291–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moyer, R. S., & Landauer, T. K. (1967). Time required for judgements of numerical inequality. Nature, 215(5109), 1519–1520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mussweiler, T., Strack, F., & Pfeiffer, T. (2000). Overcoming the inevitable anchoring Effect: considering the opposite compensates for selective accessibility. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 26(9), 1142–1150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Novemsky, N., & Kahneman, D. (2005). The boundaries of loss aversion. Journal of Marketing Research, 42(2), 119–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oliver, R. L. (1980). A cognitive model of the antecedents and consequences of satisfaction decisions. Journal of Marketing Research, 17(4), 460–469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Mahony, M. (1986). Sensory adaption. Journal of Sensory Studies, 1(3–4), 237–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ordóñez, L. D., Connolly, T., & Coughlan, R. (2000). Multiple reference points in satisfaction and fairness assessment. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 13(3), 329–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ozbeklik, S., & Smith, J. (2017). Risk taking in competition: evidence from match play golf tournaments. Journal of Corporate Finance, 44, 506–523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pope, D. G., & Schweitzer, M. E. (2011). Is tiger woods loss averse? persistent bias in the face of experience, competition, and high stakes. American Economic Review, 101(1), 129–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosch, E. (1975). Cognitive reference points. Cognitive Psychology, 7(4), 532–547.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, W. (2016). Dopamine reward prediction-error signalling: a two-component response. Nature Reviews Neuroscience, 17, 183–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sicherman, N., Loewenstein, G., Seppi, D. J., & Utkus, S. P. (2015). Financial attention. Review of Financial Studies, 29(4), 863–897.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sul, S., Kim, J., & Choi, I. (2013). Subjective well-being and hedonic editing: how happy people maximize joint outcomes of loss and gain. Journal of Happiness Studies, 14(4), 1409–1430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Szeidl, A., & Koszegi, B. (2013). A model of focusing in economic choice. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(1), 53–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. (1985). Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science, 4(3), 199–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H., & Johnson, E. J. (1990). Gambling with the house money and trying to break even: The effects of prior outcomes on risky choice. Management Science, 36(6), 643–660.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, S. D. (1990). The casue of preference reversal. American Economic Review, 80(1), 204–217.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, X. T., & Johnson, J. G. (2012). A tri-reference point theory of decision making under risk. Journal of Experimental Psychology General, 141(4), 743–756.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yates, J.F., & Stone, E.R. (1992). The risk construct. In Risk-taking behavior. (pp. 1–25). Oxford, England: John Wiley & Sons.

Download references

Funding

The study is supported by the Natural Science Foundation of Zhejiang Province [Grant No. LQ20E060001], and the National Natural Science Foundation of China [Grant No. 71901096, 71971099].

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

All authors contributed to the study conception and design. Material preparation and analysis were performed by Haijiao Cui, Bin Cao, Aimei Li and Zhaohui Li. The first draft of the manuscript was written by Haijiao Cui and all authors commented on previous/revised versions of the manuscript. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding authors

Correspondence to Bin Cao or Zhaohui Li.

Ethics declarations

Conflicts of interest

The authors have no relevant financial or non-financial interests to disclose. The authors have no conficts to report.

Informed consent

The research is not applicable.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cui, H., Cao, B., Li, A. et al. A General Model of Subjective Value and Stimulus-Intensity-Sensitive Hedonic Editing Strategy. J Happiness Stud 24, 1191–1217 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10902-023-00635-5

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10902-023-00635-5

Keywords

Navigation