1 Introduction

The Chinese housing market has witnessed a boom over the last two decades. Following the privatization of the housing sector in 1998, home ownership in China has risen substantially, standing at roughly 90% compared to about 65% in the US (Glaeser et al., 2017). The increased demand for houses has driven prices up, especially in areas such as Beijing, Shanghai, and Shenzhen. Several households own more than one home and often these houses are unoccupied. One questions therefore what has driven this housing boom, and in particular, the decision of households to acquire multiple homes. The literature on this topic is scant and mainly concentrates on investment (Li and Wu, 2014) and/or speculation as motives for multiple-home ownership (Cao et al., 2018).

In this paper, we propose an alternative explanation, centered on the role of male children present in the family. This line of research is motivated by literature, which has suggested that due to the unbalanced sex ratio in China,Footnote 1 those parents who have a male child save more in order to improve their son’s marriage prospects (Wei and Zhang, 2011). Considering that a house is viewed as a status good in China (Wei et al., 2017),Footnote 2 we extend this literature by investigating the extent to which the acquisition of multiple dwellings may also be a way for families to improve the marriage prospects of their son. Specifically, we investigate the extent to which families with at least one son close to marriage age are more likely to acquire additional houses. Next, we investigate whether the association between having a son and multiple-home acquisition is stronger in those provinces characterized by a more unbalanced sex ratio. This would support our hypothesis that the acquisition of multiple dwellings is driven by a desire to improve sons’ marriage prospects.

In order to investigate these issues, we use the 2011 and 2013 waves of the China Household Finance Survey (CHFS) to estimate a model aimed at understanding the determinants of multiple-home acquisition, controlling for demographic, education, and job-related characteristics of the household head, as well as risk attitudes and family income. We find that around 10% of households acquired an additional house between the two waves of the CHFS. Furthermore, we find that Chinese families with at least one son aged 25 or above have a significantly higher probability of acquiring an additional home. This effect is highest in regions characterized by a high sex ratio, especially in rural areas.

The remaining part of this paper is laid out as follows. Section 2 contains a brief literature review. Section 3 describes our hypotheses. Section 4 illustrates our baseline specifications. Section 5 describes our data and presents some descriptive statistics. Section 6 presents our empirical results and Sect. 7 concludes.

2 Literature review

In this section, we first survey the literature on multiple-home ownership in countries other than China. We then provide a brief overview of the housing reforms in China, and describe the literature on multiple-home ownership in China, as well as research relating to son preferences, sex ratios, and home ownership. Finally, we outline our contribution to the literature.

2.1 Multiple-home ownership in countries other than China

Multiple-home ownership has become increasingly widespread worldwide. A large empirical literature has emphasized that the proportion of the population owning multiple houses is booming in some countries. For instance, more than 36% and 22% of households own additional houses for recreational and business purposes, respectively in Spain and Italy (Sierminska and Doorley, 2013). Similarly, around 20% of Swedish households and 50% of all Northern European households have access to second houses (Dijst et al., 2005; Müller, 2007). However, there are only few studies on the determinants of multiple-home ownership (Paris, 2009).

Relying on the European Union Survey of Income and Living Conditions (EU SILC) over the period 2003–2006, Norris and Winston (2010) examine the correlation between demographic factors and multiple-home ownership in Ireland. Their first finding is that household wealth affects second-home ownership. Secondly, the authors find that second-home ownership peaks just before retirement, as it is seen as a sort of retirement plan. Hall et al. (2004) and Brown et al. (2008) also find a significant association between retirement and the acquisition of multiple homes.

Based on the 2011 Eurosystem Household Finance and Consumption Survey (HFCS), which covers household balance sheets of 15 European countries, Arrondel et al. (2014) examine which household characteristics can explain multiple-home ownership. Firstly, they argue that household income is positively associated with both the probability and the value of owning second/third homes. Di et al. (2001) reach a similar conclusion for the US. Secondly, Arrondel et al. (2014) find that the probability of owning multiple homes is positively correlated to inheritance in Europe. Based on data drawn from 12,652 pre-retirement age households in the US, Cox and Stark (2005) also uncover a significant association between inheritance and multiple-home ownership.

2.2 Housing reforms in China

As a result of the transition from a planned economy to a market economy, market mechanisms were introduced into socialist China. In order to stimulate housing consumption, the government created a housing market in the traditional housing system and allowed the housing stock to be privatized. Welfare housing was gradually transformed into commodity housing. These changes affected households’ housing acquisition behaviour, as well as the entire socialist housing system in China. As a result, private housing ownership increased drastically: Chamon and Prasad (2010) document that whilst in 1990, only 17% of Chinese households owned their homes, the corresponding figure in 2005 was 86%. Furthermore, the increased demand for houses has driven prices up, especially in areas such as Beijing, Shanghai, and Shenzhen (Glaeser et al., 2017). Several Chinese households now own more than one house and often these houses are unoccupied.

2.3 Multiple-home ownership in China

Although multiple-home ownership has received attention in the US and European countries (Arrondel et al., 2014; Di et al., 2001; Dijst et al., 2005; Cox and Stark, 2005; Müller, 2007; Norris and Winston, 2010; Sierminska and Doorley, 2013), little is known about the situation in China.

Using a survey conducted in 2005, which includes 93 interviewees from Haikou (the capital city of the Hainan province), Wang (2006) analyzes the second-home boom in the city. He argues that because of its superb environmental conditions, Haikou is one of the most popular cities in China where people, and especially those who suffer from M2.5 air pollution in the mainland, acquire second homes. This finding is similar to that in Gallent and Tewdwr-Jones (2018), who also finds that water-side areas in Western countries are attractive to second residential dwelling buyers. Another reason for non-local households to acquire second homes in Haikou is down to the so called ‘examination immigration’: The admission criterion of the ‘China college entrance examination’ for Hainan students is in fact lower than in mainland areas. This encourages parents to gain Hainan hukou for their college-age children through local housing acquisitions, so that the children can benefit from the local admission criteria.

Hui and Yu (2009) make use of a survey conducted by the Census and Statistics Department (CSD), which covers 13,397 Hong Kong households over the period May–July 2005. The authors explore reasons why Hong Kong residents purchase second homes in mainland China. Specifically, mainland second-home acquisitions are likely to occur among middle-aged Hong Kong households. Due to the improved transportation between Hong Kong and the mainland, about 200,000 Hong Kong residents work on mainland China. This makes owning second homes on the mainland convenient. The authors argue that young people are more likely to acquire their first or primary residence in the mainland, while the middle-aged residents prefer second-home ownership. This can be explained bearing in mind that middle-aged households are more constrained by their family responsibilities in Hong Kong.

Feng and Zhou (2004) analyse data drawn from 1,000 questionnaires filled in by Beijing households in 8 representative districts. They report that, due to the very high commuting times in Beijing, 23.7% of Beijing households own second homes that are close to their workplaces. Lee and Xiao (1998) study the distinct relationship between inheritance and home ownership in China using data from the China Survey on Support Systems for the Elderly in 1992. They find that short-term exchanges between generations involving housing and financial transfers are peculiar to China, while these are not common in other countries. Specifically, elderly Chinese parents are likely to provide financial support for their adult children’s home acquisitions.

Based on the 2005 CGSS (China General Social Survey) that covers 26 provinces in China, Huang and Yi (2011) examine the housing acquisition behaviour of Chinese households. They find that public housing has a positive influence on second-home acquisition in China. This is because households having access to public housing only enjoy partial property rights, but are not de facto homeowners. This encourages them to buy secondary real estate of their own. Furthermore, even if the property rights of public housing are possessed by public institutions and work units, households can still benefit from low housing prices. Therefore, public housing reduces the burden on households, enabling them to afford further real estate. This phenomenon is unique to China.

Based on the 2011 wave of the CHFS, Cao et al. (2018) find that households are more likely to own multiple houses when expecting higher capital gains. They also argue that wealthier households are more sensitive to changes in expected capital gains.

2.4 Son preference, sex ratios and home ownership in China

The paper closest to ours are Li and Wu (2017) and Wei et al. (2017). The former makes use of the 2010 wave of the China Family Panel Survey (CFPS) to study the extent to which having a son is associated with family wealth. They find that having a son has a significant positive effect on various components of family wealth. Specifically, households with a son have a higher probability of owning a house, own more and larger houses, and acquire their houses earlier. Wei et al. (2017) use data from the 2005 1% survey of the Chinese population to show that in regions characterised by higher sex ratios, households, and especially those with unmarried sons at home, tend to buy larger houses and to pay a higher price per square meter.

2.5 Our contribution

We advance the literature by analysing, for the first time, the extent to which having a son affects decisions to acquire additional houses. This research question is motivated by the existence of high sex ratios in China, which make it difficult for many men to find a wife (Wei and Zhang, 2011; Wei et al., 2017). As a house is regarded as a status good, households with one or more sons may decide to acquire additional houses for their son(s) in order to enhance their marriage prospects. We build on Li and Wu (2017) by focusing on the determinants of the actual acquisition of additional houses rather than just the ownership of multiple houses, which may have been acquired a long time ago, before the start of the survey.Footnote 3 We then investigate, for the first time, whether the association between sons and the acquisition of multiple dwellings varies according to the age of the son, and whether this phenomenon is more widespread in provinces with higher sex ratios. This part of our work builds on Wei et al. (2017), who show that average home value and size in China vary systematically with local sex ratios.

3 Hypotheses

3.1 General hypothesis on multiple-home acquisition in China

There is a long history of preference for having baby boys in China (Chen et al., 2013). Although, this preference is no longer popular among young generations and not encouraged by the government, it is still deeply rooted within Chinese traditional cultural values. In this context, having sons is believed to have an impact on households’ financial behaviour in China.

Because of the son-preference culture, parents in China typically tend to provide more support to their sons than their daughters, especially on the financial side. Knight et al. (2010) find that Chinese households are motivated to earn more if their child is male. They intend to earn more for their sons because they believe that sons deserve more than daughters. In addition, Chinese families with boys are found to spend more on health relative to families with girls (Song, 2000). The same applies to the share of expenditure on education, given that parents in China have higher expectations from boys in terms of educational achievements (Burgess and Zhuang, 2000). We hypothesise that housing expenditures follow a similar pattern. We therefore hypothesise that:

H1: Families with (a) son(s) are more likely to acquire multiple residential dwellings, compared to families with no son(s).

3.2 Multiple-home acquisition and children’s marriage status in China

As a result of the one child policy, the son-preference culture, and the increased availability of ultrasound B machines after the mid-80s, aggressive sex selective abortions took place in China from the mid-1980s onwards (Wei et al., 2017). This has led to a very high sex ratio in the country. Wei and Zhang (2011) argue that families with sons save more in China to enhance their sons’ marriage prospects, in a society characterised by an unbalanced sex ratio. A higher wealth level is in fact considered as a great advantage in the marriage market. As a home is seen as a status good in China (Wei et al., 2017), we believe that families with a son close to marriage age are more likely to acquire second homes.Footnote 4 As a result, we hypothesise that:

H2: Families with (a) son(s) close to marriage age are more likely to acquire multiple residential dwellings, compared to families with no/younger son(s).

3.3 Multiple-home acquisition and sex ratios

If the acquisition of additional houses is motivated by the desire to enhance the marriage prospects of sons, as discussed in Sect. 3.2, then we expect the association between male children close to marriage age and multiple-home acquisition to be stronger in provinces characterised by higher sex ratios. In other words:

H3: Families with (a) son(s) close to marriage age located in provinces characterised by relatively higher sex ratios are more likely to acquire multiple residential dwellings, compared to families located in other provinces.

4 Baseline models and estimation methodology

4.1 Baseline models

4.1.1 Testing the effect of children’s gender on multiple-home acquisition

To test the effects of having son(s) on the probability of acquiring additional homes, we estimate the following equation using a Probit model. This follows the approaches of Arrondel et al. (2014) and Huang and Yi (2011):

$$ Pr [Acquiremulti_{i,t} = 1] = \Phi [\alpha + \beta_{1} Son_{i,t} + \beta_{2} Daughter_{i,t} + \beta_{3} X_{i,t} + V_{p} + \varepsilon_{i,t} ] $$
(1)

The subscript i represents households, and the subscript t represents time. \(Acquiremulti_{i,t}\) is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the household has acquired an additional home between the 2011 and the 2013 waves of the CHFS, and 0 otherwise.Footnote 5

When focusing on the determinants of \(Acquiremulti_{i,t}\), the independent variables include \(Son_{i,t}\) (a dummy variable equal to 1 if household i has at least one son at time t, and 0 otherwise), which aims at testing the effect of having a son on multiple-home acquisition, as well as some control variables, \(X_{i,t}\), which represent a series of socio-demographic factors for household i. We also include the dummy \(Daughter_{i,t}\), which is equal to 1 if the household has at least one daughter, and 0 otherwise. \(V_{p}\) represents a series of provincial dummies, which encompass province-specific house prices, aimed at taking into account the investment opportunity motive for acquiring additional houses. The error term is indicated by \(\varepsilon_{i,t}\).

In line with Wei and Zhang (2011), who show that parents in China are willing to increase their saving ratios in order to enhance their sons’ marriage prospects, and with our first hypothesis, we expect to observe a positive and significant marginal effect associated with the \(Son_{i,t}\)variable.Footnote 6 We remain sceptical about the marginal effect associated with \(Daughter_{i,t}\). A positive sign could be explained by the fact that households with a daughter may want to acquire more houses to increase the bargaining power of the daughters in their marriages (Wei and Zhang, 2011). On the other hand, households with a daughter may not need to acquire an additional residential dwelling for the daughter, as daughters in China typically move to their husbands’ family houses once married.

Our models control for age, education, household size, migrant status, party membership, income, wealth and types of occupation of the head of the household.Footnote 7 Consistent with widespread evidence, we would expect a household with an older, richer and better educated head, having higher political status and local hukou to show a higher probability of acquiring multiple houses (e.g. Hall et al., 2004; Wang, 2006; Norris and Winston, 2010).

We also take the influence of households’ risk attitude into consideration. This is indicated by the dummy variable \(Riskaversion_{i,t}\) which takes the value of 1 if household i prefers low-risk investments, and 0 otherwise. We expect to observe a positive marginal effect on risk aversion, as housing is a relatively safe asset.

Furthermore, we consider the effect of regional disparities on multiple-home acquisition. To this end, we include provincial dummies in all our models, and also control for a dummy variable, \(Policyarea_{i,t}\), which is equal to 1 if the household is located in the three first-tier cities in China (Beijing, Shanghai and Guangzhou), and 0 otherwise. We do not have clear expectations about the sign of this variable. On the one hand, the housing market is booming in those areas, which could lead to a higher incentive for acquiring an additional house. On the other hand, house prices in these areas are very high, which may act as a deterrent to the acquisition of additional dwellings.

4.1.2 Differentiating the effect of children’s age on multiple- home acquisition

We then investigate the extent to which households’ multiple-home acquisition decisions depend on children’s age. Following Wei and Zhang (2011), we argue that households with sons are likely to improve their sons’ marriage competitiveness by providing additional houses for them. As a result, we expect parents with sons closer to the marriage age to be more likely to acquire additional houses. To test whether this is the case, we estimate Eq. (2), which differentiates children by gender and age:

$$ Pr [Acquiremulti_{i,t} = 1] = \Phi [\alpha + \beta_{1} Son12_{i,t} + \beta_{2} Son13\_{24_{i,t}} + \beta_{3} Son25_{i,t} + \beta_{4} Daughter12_{i,t} + \beta_{5} Daughter13\_{24_{i,t}} + \beta_{6} Daughter25_{i,t} + \beta_{7} X_{i,t} + V_{p} + \varepsilon_{i,t} ] $$
(2)

The subscript i represents households, and t represents time. \(Son12_{i,t}\) is a dummy equal to 1 if the household has a son aged at least 12, and 0 otherwise. \(Son13\_24_{i,t}\) is a dummy equal to 1 if the household has a son aged 13 to 24, and 0 otherwise. \(Son25_{i,t}\) is a dummy equal to 1 if the household has a son aged at least 25, and 0 otherwise. Similar age-related dummies are included for daughters. Other control variables are the same as in Eq. (1).

In line with Hypothesis 2, we expect to observe positive and significant marginal effects associated with \(Son13\_24_{i,t}\) and \(Son25_{i,t}\), with the marginal effect associated with the latter dummy being the highest, as sons aged at least 25 are the closest to marriage age.

4.1.3 Testing the effect of living in high sex-ratio provinces on multiple-home acquisition

In order to test whether the effect of having a son close to marriage age on the likelihood to acquire multiple homes is higher for households based in provinces with high sex ratios, we estimate the following two Equations:

$$ \begin{aligned} Pr [Acquiremulti_{i,t} = 1] = \Phi [\alpha + \beta_{1} High_{i,t} + \beta_{21} High_{i,t} Son_{i,t}\\&\quad + \beta_{22} (1 - High_{i,t} )Son_{i,t} + \beta_{31} High_{i,t} Daughter_{i,t} + \beta_{32} (1 - High_{i,t} )Daughter_{i,t} + \beta_{4} X_{i,t} + V_{p} + \varepsilon_{i,t} ]\end{aligned} $$
(3)
$$ \begin{aligned} Pr [Acquiremulti_{i,t} = 1] = \Phi \;[\alpha + \beta_{1} High_{i,t} + \beta_{21} High_{i,t} Son12_{i,t} \\&\quad \beta_{22} (1 - High_{i,t} )Son12_{i,t} + \beta_{31} High_{i,t} Son13\_24_{i,t}\\&\quad + \beta_{32} (1 - High_{i,t} )Son13\_24_{i,t} + \beta_{41} High_{i,t} Son25_{i,t} + \beta_{42} (1 - High_{i,t} )Son25_{i,t}\\&\quad + \beta_{51} High_{i,t} Daughter12_{i,t} + \beta_{52} (1 - High_{i,t} )Daughter12_{i,t}\\&\quad +\beta_{61} High_{i,t} Daughter13\_24_{i,t} + \beta_{62} (1 - High_{i,t} )Daughter13\_24_{i,t}\\&\quad +\beta_{71} High_{i,t} Daughter25_{i,t} + \beta_{72} (1 - High_{i,t} )Daughter25_{i,t} + \beta_{8} X_{i,t} + V_{p} + \varepsilon_{i,t} ]\end{aligned} $$
(4)

where \(High_{i,t}\) is a dummy variable equal to 1 if household i lives in a province with high sex ratio at time t, and 0 otherwise. In line with Hypothesis 3, we expect to observe the following relationship in Eq. (3): \(\beta_{21} > \beta_{22} > 0\). Similarly, in Eq. (4), we expect to observe: \(\beta_{31} > \beta_{32} > 0\) and \(\beta_{41} > \beta_{42} > 0\).

4.2 Estimation methodology

Because our dependent variable is binary, all our models are estimated using a Probit estimator, and marginal effects are reported and discussed in all Tables. Considering that our dependent variable represents the acquisition of additional dwellings and is calculated as a dummy equal to 1 if the difference between the number of houses owned by the household in the 2013 and 2011 waves of the CHFS is greater than or equal to 1, only 2013 data are effectively used in estimation. All our regressions are therefore cross-sectional, and the subscript t in all equations corresponds to 2013.

5 Data and summary statistics

5.1 Data

We use the 2011 and 2013 waves of the China Household Finance Survey (CHFS), a biannual survey collected at the Southwestern University of Finance and Economics in Chengdu (China).Footnote 8 The survey is based on a three-stage stratified random sampling design. Specifically, at first, counties are randomly selected among 29 Chinese provinces. Second, communities are randomly selected within each county. Finally, both urban and rural households are randomly selected within each community. The final sample, which is representative of the Chinese population, and contains accurate and detailed information on households’ demographic characteristics, their financial and non-financial assets, and their business activities, contained 8,438 households in 2011 (Gan et al., 2014). In 2013, the survey was expanded to 28,413 households to enhance representativeness at the provincial level.

Bearing in mind that our Acquiremulti variable is calculated as the difference in the number of dwellings owned in the two waves, only the 2013 wave is used in estimation. Moreover, because our focus is on multiple-home ownership, we only consider households which were already home owners in 2011. We also drop those observations with missing values for any of the regression variables in our models. Finally, in order to control for extreme values, we set the values of wealth and income in the top and bottom 1% of the distribution to missing. After the above adjustments, our final dataset includes 5,815 observations over the year 2013.

5.2 Summary statistics

Table 1 contains descriptive statistics for our regression variables. We observe that 10.2% of our observations acquired an additional house between 2011 and 2013. Furthermore, 53.9% of the observations in our sample have at least one son, whist 31.9% have at least one daughter. Focusing on socio-economic characteristics of the heads of the households included in our sample, we can see that the average age is 52.7 and that 7.4% of the household heads have a college education. About 5% of the household head are migrants, 31.8% are employed, 25.8% work in agriculture, and 16.0% are retired. 66.4% of our households live in urban areas.

Table 1 Sample means and standard deviations (in parentheses)

Table 2 presents means of all our regression variables for households who acquired an additional house between the two waves and households who did not. We can see that 62.0% (37.5%) of acquirers have a son (daughter), while the corresponding figure for non-acquirers is 53.0% (31.2%). Both differences are statistically significant, and suggest that people who acquire second homes are more likely to have children, particularly sons. This provides some preliminary support for our Hypothesis 1.

Table 2 Descriptive statistics differentiating households on the basis of whether or not they acquired an additional house between 2011 and 2013

Looking at the age of children, acquirers are more likely to have sons aged between 13 and 24 and sons aged 25 or above, which is in line with the predictions of Hypothesis 2. Acquirers are also more likely to have daughters aged below 13. The differences among other age categories are not statistically significant. In terms of other variables, acquirers are typically younger, richer, and more likely to have a college degree, and a larger household. They are also more likely to be party members, employed, or self-employed. Finally, acquirers seem to be less likely to be risk-averse than non-acquirers.

6 Empirical results

6.1 Multiple-home acquisition differentiating children by gender and age

Column 1 of Table 3 reports Probit estimates of Eq. (1). We can see that neither the marginal effect associated with the presence of sons, nor that associated with daughters are statistically significant. These findings do not support our Hypothesis 1 and seem to suggest that, controlling for other factors, multiple-home acquisitions in China are not associated with the presence of children. In line with the literature (e.g. Norris and Winston, 2010; Arrondel et al., 2014), both income and wealth are positively associated with the acquisition of additional houses. Furthermore, families whose head is self-employed and/or a party member are both more likely to acquire additional houses, as are larger households.

Table 3 Determinants of the probability of acquiring multiple homes differentiating households on the basis of the child’s gender and age (marginal effects)

Column 2 presents Probit estimates of Eq. (2), whereby both sons and daughters are differentiated in the following age groups: below 13, between 13 and 24, and 25 and above. We can see that having a male child aged 25 or above is associated with a 3.6 percentage point higher chance to acquire an additional house, whilst having a son aged 13 to 24 is associated with a 2.1 percentage point higher chance. The latter effect is, however, only marginally significant. These findings, which support our second hypothesis, suggest that the acquisition of multiple houses may indeed be a way to enhance the marriage chances of sons in a world characterised by unbalanced sex ratios.

We also observe that having a son aged less than 13 is associated with a 2.8 percentage point lower chance of acquiring an additional house: This may be explained considering that parents of very young sons may prefer to save the money for the education of the child. By contrast, having a daughter aged below 13 is associated with a 2.5 percentage point higher chance of acquiring an additional house. This association, which can be explained considering that families with a young daughter may acquire an additional house to enhance their daughter’s bargaining power once she gets married (Wei and Zhang, 2011), is, however, only marginally significant.Footnote 9

Focusing on other control variables, as in column 1, we observe that richer families, with self-employed heads who are also party members are more likely to acquire additional houses, whilst a larger household size is also linked with a higher chance of acquiring an additional dwelling.

Colum 3 of Table 3 reports results where the legal marriage ages for males (22) and females (20) are considered instead of the threshold of 25. Specifically, the age categories for males (females) are less than 13, 13 to 21 (13 to 20), and 22 (20) and above.Footnote 10 The results are very similar to those reported in column 2.Footnote 11

6.2 Does living in a high sex-ratio province make a difference?

Table 4 presents Probit estimates of Eqs. (3) and (4).Footnote 12 High-sex ratio provinces are defined as those provinces with sex ratios falling in the top half of the distribution.Footnote 13 Sex ratios are calculated at birth and are taken from the 2010 Population Census (National Bureau of Statistics, 2010). Focusing on column 1, we observe that the son and daughter dummy variables never show statistically significant marginal effects in both high-sex ratio provinces and other provinces.

Table 4 Determinants of the probability of acquiring multiple homes differentiating households on the basis of the child’s gender and age, as well as on whether the household lives in a province characterized by a high sex ratio (marginal effects)

Column 2 differentiates children by age using 25 as the marriage age and column 3 uses instead the legal marriage age for males and females. Focusing on column 2 (3), we can see that having a son aged 25 (22) or above is associated with a 5.0 (4.8) percentage point higher chance of acquiring an additional dwelling in the regions with the highest sex ratios. Theses findings, which are consistent with Hypothesis 3, suggest that, especially in regions characterised by high sex ratios, households with a son close to marriage age are more likely to acquire additional houses, to enhance their son’s chance in the marriage market.

In regions characterised by relatively low sex ratios, having a son aged between 13 and 24, or 25 and above does not affect the chance of acquiring an additional dwelling. Yet, in these regions, having a son younger than 13 is associated with a 3.6 percentage point (column 2) or 3.3 percentage point (column 3) lower chance of acquiring an additional house. This could be explained bearing in mind that in regions with low sex ratios, where the competition for marriage is less fierce, parents may prefer to use their savings to provide a better education to their young son. As a result, they are less likely to acquire additional houses. To justify this claim, we observe that in regions with low sex ratios, education expenditure is 432.217 RMB higher than in provinces characterized by high sex ratios.Footnote 14 This difference corresponds to about 5.3% of the average education expenditure (8146.249 RMB) in China.

Finally, the marginal effects reported in columns 2 and 3 of Table 4 show that having a daughter, regardless of her age, and regardless of the type of region the family lives in, does not affect the likelihood of acquiring an additional dwelling. It is also interesting to note that the marginal effects associated with the high-sex ratio dummies are never statistically significant. The marginal effects associated with the other control variables are similar to those observed in Table 3.

It could be that what determines multiple dwelling acquisition is the number of children/sons in the family and the number of children/sons at the marriage age rather than the presence of children in relevant groups. To test whether this is the case, in columns 4 and 5 of Table 4, we have replaced the children dummies in our models with numerical variables denoting the number of children in relevant groups. The results suggest that none of the variables denoting number of sons/daughters in general and in each age category attract statistically significant marginal effects. Hence, we conclude that what matters is not the number of children in given categories, but simply the presence of at least one child in a given group.

6.3 Are rural areas different from urban areas?

Lei and Pals (2011) show that son preferences are weaker in cities, which could lead to a weaker association between the presence of sons and the likelihood to purchase additional houses. To see whether this is the case, we next test whether there are any differences in our results across urban and rural areas.

Table 5 reports estimates of our main specifications separately for rural and urban samples. The estimates of Eq. (3) are presented in column 1 for urban households and column 3 for rural households, whilst the estimates of Eq. (4) appear in columns 2 and 4, for urban and rural households respectively. Focusing on columns 1 and 3, we observe that only in rural areas, having a son is associated with a higher chance of acquiring an additional house in provinces with high sex ratio (column 3). Specifically, having a son is associated with a 3.6 percentage point higher chance of acquiring an additional dwelling.

Table 5 Determinants of the probability of acquiring multiple homes differentiating households on the basis of the child’s gender and age, as well as on whether the household lives in a province characterized by a high sex ratio (marginal effects)—Urban/Rural households

Next, differentiating the children by age, we observe that in rural areas characterised by a high sex ratio, having a son aged 25 or above is associated with a 6.0 percentage point higher chance of acquiring an additional house (column 4). The corresponding percentage in urban areas is much smaller (4.2 percentage points, column 2). It is also noteworthy that, in rural areas with high sex ratios, the presence of a son aged 13 to 24 is also associated with a 4.0 percentage point higher chance of acquiring an additional house.

Furthermore, in urban areas having a son aged 12 or younger is associated with a lower chance of acquiring an additional house (column 2). This effect is apparent in all types of provinces, but is only marginally significant and relatively small in high-sex ratio provinces. As discussed in Sect. 6.2, this pattern can be explained bearing in mind that parents with young sons may prefer to spend their money on the education of their sons, especially in provinces with relatively low sex ratio, where the competition for marriage is less fierce, and in urban areas where the son preference is weaker. Finally, the marginal effects associated with the presence of female children in the family are never statistically significant regardless of the age of the child and location.

7 Conclusions

We have used the 2011 and 2013 waves of the China Household Finance Survey to test, for the first time, the extent to which the acquisition of multiple houses is determined by the presence of male children in the family. We have differentiated children according to age and have assessed the extent to which living in a high-sex ratio region makes a difference. We have found that families with sons aged 25 or older are most likely to acquire additional houses. This effect is highest in regions characterised by higher sex ratios, especially in rural areas. Our findings complement those in Li and Wu (2017) who find that households with a son have a higher probability of owning a house, own more and larger houses, and acquire their houses earlier. They also complement Wei et al. (2017) who show that in regions characterised by higher sex ratios, households, and especially those with unmarried sons at home, tend to buy larger houses and to pay a higher price per square meter.

Our results suggest that Chinese families’ son-preference culture may be an explanation for the housing boom in China, a country characterised by unbalanced sex ratios. The termination of the one child policy in 2016 is likely to slowly restore the sex ratio to normal levels. When this happens, households may have a lower incentive to acquire additional dwellings to enhance their sons’ marriage prospects. That may contribute to a slowing down of the housing boom.

Yet, the improvement of sons’ marriage prospects is not the only reason why Chinese people acquire multiple homes. The investment motive for acquiring houses plays in fact an important role too. Bearing in mind the very high saving rate characterising Chinese households (Choi et al., 2017) and the substantial increase in house prices observed in recent years, which allows home owners to benefit from substantial capital gains (Li and Wu, 2014; Cao et al., 2018), housing represents a lucrative and popular type of investment in China. The investment motive for acquiring additional houses in China is strong also because the relatively poorly developed financial sector offers few alternative investment channels. Moreover, Chinese households find it difficult to invest overseas due to the stringent capital controls imposed by the government (Liu and Xiong, 2018). A thorough study of other explanations for why Chinese households tend to acquire multiple homes is on the agenda for future research.