Skip to main content
Log in

Objectives and the Optimal Structure of Competition Authorities Revisited

  • Published:
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This article contributes to the discussion of the implications of different objectives pursued by the competition authorities (CAs) for their optimal structure in terms of whether one or more functions (or activities) should be assigned to them. Different areas of enforcement activity that can be assigned to CAs may differ in the extent to which they contribute to welfare-enhancing or reputation-enhancing objectives. In their recent paper, Avdasheva et al. (Rev Ind Organ 54:251–282, 2019) showed that when the CAs are reputation-maximizing, it may then be optimal to have activities undertaken by specialist authorities, each specializing in one activity. In this article, we generalize the utility function of the CAs, allowing also the welfare impact of the decisions made to influence their utility, and show that if the CAs are welfare maximizers, then all the activities should be undertaken by one generalist authority.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. With a degree of independence that varies quite a lot between countries—see Jenny (2016), Sect. 4.

  2. See for an extensive discussion of these assumptions and of empirical evidence, as well as for a review of related theoretical work, Schinkel et al. (2015) and Katsoulacos (2017). For further justification see also below.

  3. That of the Dutch Authority (ACM). For the UK’s agency (CMA), this is, however, an important performance indicator.

  4. A review of which CAs have, in the last 15 years or so, gone for a more generalist and which have gone for a more specialist structure is given in Jenny (2016). Most agencies in Europe and North America are “mildly” generalist, having both responsibilities for consumer law and consumer protection. In some cases, as in Australia, in the BRICS and other developing countries, the agencies have now many more responsibilities including for sectoral regulation and/or for procurement law and unfair trade practices (e.g., in Russia). See also for more details, Avdasheva et al. (2019).

  5. The debate on institutional design and the review by Jenny (2016) extends to issues of the goals of CAs and of the organization of antitrust institutions more generally. Here, our focus is narrower: we are concerned with the institutional structure purely in terms of whether this is a specialist or a generalist one.

  6. The welfare benefits of competition law enforcement can be measured by the impact on consumer welfare of infringmeent decisions taken by CAs that are not annulled, and this is an important part of the perforrmance assessment of some CAs for a long time, as for example, for the case of CMA (and of the OFT before)—the UK agency, or for ACM (Holland) or for the Australian agency (all generalist agencies). Welfare will of course also be influenced by deterrence and advocacy measures taken by the agency. However, we need to formulate the utility function in terms of variables that have a measurable impact on utility. Non-annulled infringement decisions constitute the primary measurable variable affecting the agency’s performance indicators (utility) when the latter depend on consumer welfare. It is not possible to identify the impact on welfare and hence on the performance of the agency of its measures to improve deterrence or on advocacy.

  7. To be more explicit, we assume that this degree of freedom is unavoidable even though the principal (the government) finally has to decide on the structure of the agency (generalist or specialist). As a referee noted, we abstract from the issues that would be raised by a principal—agent approach under imperfect information, as in Dixit (2002), but our approach is effective in allowing us to skip these issues and to show that the optimal CA structure depends on the motivation of the authority.

  8. In these cases, explicit assessment (performance) criteria are set that focus on the consumer welfare impact of decisions. We fully recognize that such welfare focused objectives will often not be obtained (see also our review of a number of authorities in Avdasheva et al. 2019), as recognized in particular by Buchanan’s (Buchanan and Tullock, 1962) public-choice theory, and at best they require strong institutional design and incentives.

  9. E.g., because of deadlines imposed by law that require the CA to reach decisions within a certain period once a case is filed. Alternatively, we can plausibly think of \(c_{k} \underline{D}_{k} \;\) as the budget over which the division k in the CA is given direct responsibility (so the assumption is that each division has some but not complete autonomy in the way the overall budget is divided).

  10. Of course, a number of other factors influence whether it is optimal to use a generalist or a specialist CA. For example, the incorporation of fixed costs in the model would provide an added benefit to a more generalist agency—to the extent that having one agency rather than several specialist agencies would save on overall fixed costs. This factor has been noted and discussed before in the literature, including in Avdasheva et al. (2019) and in Jenny (2016). So the effect of this factor is already well understood and thus in our model we assume it away, as indeed also some other factors mentioned in the literature, in order to focus on the effect of different agency objectives, a factor which was hitherto unexplored.

References

  • Avdasheva S, Golovanova S, Katsoulacos Y (2019) Optimal institutional structure of competition authorities under reputation maximization: a model and empirical evidence from the case of Russia. Rev Ind Org 54:251–282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan J, Tullock G (1962) The calculus of consent. Michigan University Press, Michigan, p 1962

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A (2002) Incentives and organisations in the public sector: an interpretative review. J Hum Res 37:696–727

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fels A, Ergas H (2014) Note, institutional design of competition authorities. OECD Competition Committee, Madrid

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox EM, Trebilcox MJ (2012) The design of competition law institutions and the global convergence of process norms: the GAL competition project. New York University Law and Economics Working Papers.

  • Harringtion J (2011) When is an antitrust authority not aggressive enough in fighting cartels? Int J Econ Theory 7:39–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jenny F (2016) The institutional design of competition authorities: debates and trends. In: Jenny F, Katsoulacos Y (eds) Competition law enforcement in the BRICS and in developing countries. Springer International Publishing, New York, pp 1–58

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Kovacic WE, Hyman DA (2013) Competition agencies with complex policy portfolios: divide or conquer?. GW Law Faculty Publications & Other Works. Paper 631. http://scholarship.law.gwu.edu/faculty_publications/631

  • OECD Global Forum on Competition (2003) Session I “The objectives of competition law and policy”.

  • OECD, Note BIAC (2014) Roundtable on institutional changes. OECD Competition Committee, DAF/COMP/WD(2014)126.

  • Schinkel MP, Tóth L, Tuinstra J (2015) Discretionary authority and prioritizing in government agencies. Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper 15-058/VII. SSRN. https://ssrn.com/abstract=2607868 or https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2607868

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful for research assistance to Galateia Makri and Eleni Metsiou and for the comments and suggestions on a previous version of the paper presented at the 13th CRESSE Conference (July 2018) and, particularly, from Paulo Furquin de Azevedo, Boris Begovic, Frederic Jenny, Louis Kaplow, Martin Peitz, Maarten Pieter Schinkel, and David Ulph also for the comments of the three referees. Of course, all errors and ambiguities remain our sole responsibility. We are also grateful for financial support from the Hellenic Foundation for Research and Innovation (H.F.R.I.) under the “1st Call for H.F.R.I. Research Projects to support Faculty Members & Researchers and the Procurement of High-cost research equipment grant” (Project Number: 1314; 2020–2023).

Funding

This study was funded by the Hellenic Foundation for Research and Innovation (H.F.R.I.), Project number 1314; 2020-2023.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yannis Katsoulacos.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Ethical Approval

Not applicable.

Informed Consent

Not applicable.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Katsoulacos, Y., Bageri, V. Objectives and the Optimal Structure of Competition Authorities Revisited. J Ind Compet Trade 22, 69–81 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-021-00370-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-021-00370-8

Keywords

Navigation