Skip to main content
Log in

Entry of Innovator and License in Oligopoly

  • Published:
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

When an outside innovating firm has a cost-reducing technology, it can sell licenses of its technology to incumbent firms using a combination of royalty and fixed fee. Alternatively, the innovating firm can enter the market and at the same time sell licenses, or enter the market without license. We examine the credibility of the threat of entry by the innovating firm using a two-step auction under oligopoly with three firms, one outside innovating firm and two incumbent firms. With general demand function, we show that the credibility of the two-step auction depends on the form of the cost function of the new technology, whether it is concave or convex. Also we analyze the optimal strategy for the innovator in a case of linear demand and quadratic cost functions in which the two-step auction is credible.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Please see Section 6.2.2.

  2. About the meanings of strategic substitutability and complementarity, please see Section 4.1

  3. The definitions of strategic substitutability and complementarity are according to Bulow et al. (1985).

  4. This is a stability condition in the case of duopoly with Firm A and Firm B.

  5. This property of the cost function is called strict super-additivity. Thus, strict convexity of the cost function with zero fixed cost implies strict super-additivity.

  6. This property of the cost function is called strict sub-additivity. Thus, strict concavity of the cost function with zero fixed cost implies strict sub-additivity.

  7. More details of calculations such as the equilibrium values of the outputs and profits are available upon request.

References

  • Boone J (2001) Intensity of competition and the incentive to innovate. Int J Ind Organ 19:705–726

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bulow J, Geanakoplos J, Klemperer P (1985) Multimarket oligopoly: strategic substitutes and strategic complements. J Political Econ 93:488–511

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen CS (2017) Endogenous market structure and technology licensing. Jpn Econ Rev 68:115–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Creane A, Chiu YK, Konishi H (2013) Choosing a licensee from heterogeneous rivals. GEB 82:254–268

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A (1986) Comparative statics for oligopoly. IER 27:107–122

    Google Scholar 

  • Duchene A, Sen D, Serfes K (2015) Patent licensing and entry deterrence: the role of low royalties. Economica 82:1324–1348

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hattori M, Tanaka Y (2015) Subsidy or tax policy for new technology adoption in duopoly with quadratic and linear cost functions. Econ Bull 35:1423–1433

    Google Scholar 

  • Hattori M, Tanaka Y (2016a) Subsidizing new technology adoption in a Stackelberg duopoly: cases of substitutes and complements. Ital Econ J 2:197–215

  • Hattori M, Tanaka Y (2016b) License or entry with vertical differentiation in duopoly. Econ Bus Lett 5:17–29

  • Hattori M, Tanaka Y (2018) License and entry strategies for an outside innovator under duopoly. Ital Econ J 4:135–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kabiraj T (2004) Patent licensing in a leadership structure. The Manchester School 72:188–205

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien T, Tauman Y (1986) Fees versus royalties and the private value of a patent. QJE 101:471–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien T, Tauman Y (2002) Patent licensing: the inside story. The Manchester School 70:7–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz M, Shapiro C (1985) On the licensing of innovations. Rand J Econ 16:504–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • La Manna M (1993) Asymmetric oligopoly and technology transfers. EJ 103:436–443

    Google Scholar 

  • Liao C, Sen D (2005) Subsidy in licensing: optimality and welfare implications. The Manchester School 73:281–299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T, Matsushima N, Cato S (2013) Competitiveness and R&D competition revisited. Econ Model 31:541–547

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pal R (2010) Technology adoption in a differentiated duopoly: Cournot versus Bertrand. Res Econ 64:128–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rebolledo M, Sandonís J (2012) The effectiveness of R&D subsidies. Econ Innovat New Tech 21:815–825

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seade JK (1980) The stability of Cournot revisited. J Econ Theory 23:15–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen D, Tauman Y (2007) General licensing schemes for a cost-reducing Innovation. GEB 59:163–186

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang XH, Yang BZ (2004) On technology licensing in a Stackelberg duopoly. Aust Econ Pap 43:448–458

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watanabe N, Muto S (2008) Stable profit sharing in a patent licensing game: general bargaining outcomes. Int J Game Theory 37:505–523

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Funding

This work was financially supported by Japan Society for the Promotion of Science KAKENHI Grant Number 18K01594 and 18K12780.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Masahiko Hattori.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A. Details of Calculations

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \lambda_{A}&=& {c}_{A}^{2} {c}_{B}^{3} +4c_{A} {c}_{B}^{3} +4 {c}_{B}^{3} - {c}_{A}^{3} {c}_{B}^{2} +13c_{A} {c}_{B}^{2} +16 {c}_{B}^{2} -4 {c}_{A}^{3} c_{B}-10 {c}_{A}^{2} c_{B}+14c_{A}c_{B}\\ &&+25c_{B}-4 {c}_{A}^{3} -12 {c}_{A}^{2} +7c_{A}+14, \end{array} $$
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \lambda_{B}&=&3{c}_{A}^{8} {c}_{B}^{4} + 42 {c}_{A}^{7} {c}_{B}^{4} + 236 {c}_{A}^{6} {c}_{B}^{4} + 684 {c}_{A}^{5} {c}_{B}^{4} + 1095 {c}_{A}^{4} {c}_{B}^{4} + 962 {c}_{A}^{3} {c}_{B}^{4} + 438 {c}_{A}^{2} {c}_{B}^{4} \\ && + 96c_{A} {c}_{B}^{4} + 8 {c}_{B}^{4} - 2 {c}_{A}^{9} {c}_{B}^{3} - 8 {c}_{A}^{8} {c}_{B}^{3} + 114 {c}_{A}^{7} {c}_{B}^{3} + 1012 {c}_{A}^{6} {c}_{B}^{3} + 3364 {c}_{A}^{5} {c}_{B}^{3} + 5696 {c}_{A}^{4} {c}_{B}^{3} \\ && + 5160 {c}_{A}^{3} {c}_{B}^{3} + 2424 {c}_{A}^{2} {c}_{B}^{3} + 552 c_{A} {c}_{B}^{3} + 48 {c}_{B}^{3} - 12 {c}_{A}^{9} {c}_{B}^{2} - 112 {c}_{A}^{8} {c}_{B}^{2} - 216 {c}_{A}^{7} {c}_{B}^{2} \\ && + 995 {c}_{A}^{6} {c}_{B}^{2} + 5454 {c}_{A}^{5} {c}_{B}^{2} + 10628 {c}_{A}^{4} {c}_{B}^{2} + 10296 {c}_{A}^{3} {c}_{B}^{2} + 5103 {c}_{A}^{2} {c}_{B}^{2} + 1230 c_{A} {c}_{B}^{2} + 114 {c}_{B}^{2} \\ && -24 {c}_{A}^{9} c_{B} - 256 {c}_{A}^{8} c_{B} - 896 {c}_{A}^{7} c_{B} - 700 {c}_{A}^{6} c_{B} + 2970 {c}_{A}^{5} c_{B} + 8444 {c}_{A}^{4} c_{B} + 9262 {c}_{A}^{3} c_{B}\\ && + 4964 {c}_{A}^{2} c_{B} + 1284 c_{A} c_{B} + 128 c_{B} - 16 {c}_{A}^{9} - 176 {c}_{A}^{8} - 688 {c}_{A}^{7} - 1060 {c}_{A}^{6} + 92 {c}_{A}^{5} + 2436 {c}_{A}^{4} \\ && + 3252 {c}_{A}^{3} + 1908 {c}_{A}^{2} + 528 c_{A} + 56, \end{array} $$
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \lambda_{C} &=& {c}_{A}^{6} {c}_{B}^{6} + 12 {c}_{A}^{5} {c}_{B}^{6} + 54 {c}_{A}^{4} {c}_{B}^{6} + 112 {c}_{A}^{3} {c}_{B}^{6} + 105 {c}_{A}^{2} {c}_{B}^{6} + 36 c_{A} {c}_{B}^{6} + 4 {c}_{B}^{6} - {c}_{A}^{7} {c}_{B}^{5} + 74 {c}_{A}^{5} {c}_{B}^{5} \\ && + 406 {c}_{A}^{4} {c}_{B}^{5} +876 {c}_{A}^{3} {c}_{B}^{5} +826 {c}_{A}^{2} {c}_{B}^{5} +293c_{A} {c}_{B}^{5} +34 {c}_{B}^{5} -10 {c}_{A}^{7} {c}_{B}^{4} -53 {c}_{A}^{6} {c}_{B}^{4} +90 {c}_{A}^{5} {c}_{B}^{4} \\ &&+1125 {c}_{A}^{4} {c}_{B}^{4} +2716 {c}_{A}^{3} {c}_{B}^{4} +2641 {c}_{A}^{2} {c}_{B}^{4} +976c_{A} {c}_{B}^{4} +119 {c}_{B}^{4} -40 {c}_{A}^{7} {c}_{B}^{3} -264 {c}_{A}^{6} {c}_{B}^{3} \\ &&-338 {c}_{A}^{5} {c}_{B}^{3} +1258 {c}_{A}^{4} {c}_{B}^{3} +4179 {c}_{A}^{3} {c}_{B}^{3} +4372 {c}_{A}^{2} {c}_{B}^{3} +1705c_{A} {c}_{B}^{3} +220 {c}_{B}^{3} -80 {c}_{A}^{7} {c}_{B}^{2} \\ &&-552 {c}_{A}^{6} {c}_{B}^{2} -1148 {c}_{A}^{5} {c}_{B}^{2} +89{c}_{A}^{4} {c}_{B}^{2} +3210 {c}_{A}^{3} {c}_{B}^{2} +3928 {c}_{A}^{2} {c}_{B}^{2} +1650c_{A} {c}_{B}^{2} +227 {c}_{B}^{2} \\ && -80 {c}_{A}^{7} c_{B}-544 {c}_{A}^{6} c_{B}-1272 {c}_{A}^{5} c_{B}-852{c}_{A}^{4} c_{B}+1016 {c}_{A}^{3} c_{B}+1800 {c}_{A}^{2} c_{B}+840c_{A}c_{B}\\ && +124c_{B}-32 {c}_{A}^{7} -208 {c}_{A}^{6} -496 {c}_{A}^{5} -460{c}_{A}^{4} +32 {c}_{A}^{3} +324 {c}_{A}^{2} +176c_{A}+28, \end{array} $$
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \lambda_{D} &=& 2(c_{B}+2)(c_{A}c_{B}+2c_{B}+2c_{A}+2)(c_{A}c_{B}+2c_{B}+2c_{A}+3)^{2}({c}_{A}^{2} c_{B}+4c_{A}c_{B}+c_{B}\\ &&+2 {c}_{A}^{2} +6c_{A}+2)^{2}, \end{array} $$
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \lambda_{E} &=& {c}_{A}^{6} {c}_{B}^{4} +12 {c}_{A}^{5} {c}_{B}^{4} +54 {c}_{A}^{4} {c}_{B}^{4} +112 {c}_{A}^{3} {c}_{B}^{4} +105 {c}_{A}^{2} {c}_{B}^{4} +36c_{A} {c}_{B}^{4} +4 {c}_{B}^{4} - {c}_{A}^{7} {c}_{B}^{3} -4 {c}_{A}^{6} {c}_{B}^{3} \\ &&+34 {c}_{A}^{5} {c}_{B}^{3} +250 {c}_{A}^{4} {c}_{B}^{3} +584 {c}_{A}^{3} {c}_{B}^{3} +568 {c}_{A}^{2} {c}_{B}^{3} +205c_{A} {c}_{B}^{3} +24 {c}_{B}^{3} -6 {c}_{A}^{7} {c}_{B}^{2} -44 {c}_{A}^{6} {c}_{B}^{2} \\ &&-46 {c}_{A}^{5} {c}_{B}^{2} +347{c}_{A}^{4} {c}_{B}^{2} +1092 {c}_{A}^{3} {c}_{B}^{2} +1152 {c}_{A}^{2} {c}_{B}^{2} +448c_{A} {c}_{B}^{2} +57 {c}_{B}^{2} -12 {c}_{A}^{7} c_{B}-96 {c}_{A}^{6} c_{B}\\ &&-212 {c}_{A}^{5} c_{B}+88{c}_{A}^{4} c_{B}+871 {c}_{A}^{3} c_{B}+1062 {c}_{A}^{2} c_{B}+455c_{A}c_{B}+64c_{B}-8 {c}_{A}^{7} -64 {c}_{A}^{6} \\ &&-160 {c}_{A}^{5} -76{c}_{A}^{4} +254 {c}_{A}^{3} +384 {c}_{A}^{2} +182c_{A}+28, \end{array} $$

Appendix B. Stability Conditions

According to Seade (1980) and Dixit (1986), we consider stability conditions for a duopoly and an oligopoly. Consider the following matrix for a duopoly with Firm B and Firm C.

$$ \left[\begin{array}{cc} s_{B}\theta_{B}&s_{B}\sigma_{B}\\ s_{C}\sigma_{C}&s_{C}\theta_{C} \end{array}\right] $$

sB and sC are adjustment speeds of the outputs of Firms B and C. For the stability, the trace of this matrix must be negative, and its determinant must be positive. Therefore,

$$ s_{B}\theta_{B}+s_{C}\theta_{C}<0, $$

and

$$ s_{B}s_{C}[\theta_{B}\theta_{C}-\sigma_{B}\sigma_{C}]>0. $$

Since these are to hold independently of sB and sC, we need

$$ \theta_{B}<0,\ \theta_{C}<0,\ \theta_{B}\theta_{C}-\sigma_{B}\sigma_{C}>0. $$

Consider the following matrix for an oligopoly with Firms A, B, and C.

$$ \left[\begin{array}{ccc} s_{A}\theta_{A}&s_{A}\sigma_{A}&s_{A}\sigma_{A}\\ s_{B}\sigma_{B}&s_{B}\theta_{B}&s_{B}\sigma_{B}\\ s_{C}\sigma_{C}&s_{C}\sigma_{C}&s_{C}\theta_{C} \end{array}\right] $$

sA, sB, and sC are adjustment speeds of the outputs of Firms A, B, and C. One necessary condition is that the trace of this matrix is negative. Therefore,

$$ s_{A}\theta_{A}+s_{B}\theta_{B}+s_{C}\theta_{C}<0. $$

Since this is to hold independently of sA, sB, and sC, we need

$$ \theta_{A}<0, \theta_{B}<0,\ \theta_{C}<0. $$

Another necessary condition is that the determinant of this matrix has the sign of (− 1)3, that is, it is negative. Thus,

$$ \theta_{A}\theta_{B}\theta_{C}-\theta_{A}\sigma_{B}\sigma_{C}-\sigma_{A}\theta_{B}\sigma_{C}-\sigma_{A}\sigma_{B}\theta_{C}+2\sigma_{A}\sigma_{B}\sigma_{C}<0. $$

The second-order conditions in each case 𝜃A < 0, 𝜃B < 0, 𝜃C < 0 with the stability conditions guarantee the existence of the locally unique stable Nash equilibrium. If the stability conditions are violated, the firms increase (or decrease) their outputs more than a change (increase or decrease) in the rival firm’s output, and then the outputs of the firms diverge from the equilibrium values. For the existence of the globally unique equilibrium, we need that 𝜃A < 0, 𝜃B < 0, 𝜃C < 0 globally hold.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hattori, M., Tanaka, Y. Entry of Innovator and License in Oligopoly. J Ind Compet Trade 20, 709–731 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-020-00334-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-020-00334-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation