Skip to main content
Log in

Impact of Vertical Integration on Market Power in Indian Manufacturing Sector During the Post-Reform Period

  • Published:
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In the context of declining degrees of vertical integration in major industries of Indian manufacturing sector during the post-reform period, the present paper is an attempt to examine how such “vertical disintegration” has affected firms’ market power and its implications for competition policy. Using panel dataset of 49 majors industries of Indian manufacturing sector for the period 2003–04 to 2010–11 and applying the system generalized method of moments approach to estimate of dynamic panel data models, the paper finds that vertical integration does not cause any significant impact on average market power of firms in an industry. Instead, it is influenced by market size, and selling and technology-related efforts. While selling intensity has a positive impact on market power, the impact of market size and technology intensity is found to be negative. Notably, like vertical integration, market concentration, import to export ratio, and capital intensity also do not have any significant impact on market power. The findings of this paper, therefore, have important implications for competition law and policy in general and policies and regulation relating to technology development and international trade in particular.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. However, if the upstream and downstream markets become more competitive, such a situation may not arise.

  2. This is so particularly when the downstream firms are unaware of the price mark-up by the upstream firm and is referred to as vertical externality (Tirole 1988).

  3. In addition, firms consider vertical integration whenever there are uncertainties in the supply of inputs (Carlton 1979). Vertical integration can also benefit an infant industry which produces a new downstream input as the demand for such inputs in open market may be limited for survival of these infant industries (Stigler 1951).

  4. Analyzing impact of multimarket vertical merger on prices of retail gasoline, Hastings (2004) found evidences of higher retail prices following decline in market share of retailers that are not integrated.

  5. However, Rosengren and James (1994) and Asker (2004) did not find any support for the theory of foreclosure.

  6. The anti-trust laws of the USA were critical on vertical mergers on the ground that such combinations can reduce competition by limiting access to resources in input markets, reducing number of competitors, and leveraging monopoly power across markets.

  7. A number of studies in recent years have used dynamic framework to analyze industry level market power (e.g., Mishra 2008) or firm-level profit margins (Kambhampati and Parikh 2005) in Indian context

  8. These measures of vertical integration were first propounded by Adelman (1955). Although they have various limitations (Nugent and Hamblin 1996), these measures, especially the ratio of value added to sales have been widely used in empirical research on vertical integration. A number of studies (e.g., Adelman 1955; Gort 1962; Nelson 1963; Laffer 1969; Tucker and Wilder 1977) have used ratio of value added to sales as a measure of vertical integration with some variations.

  9. The details are available at Mishra et al. (2011) and Mishra and Rao (2014).

  10. Robust conclusions on relationship between vertical integration and market power require defining market at relevant level, whereas it is not clear what should be the appropriate level of relevant market. This may have serious implications on the findings given that competition is localized in many markets. Given data limitations and non-availability of location-specific information, the paper addresses this problem in two ways—(i) by using more disaggregate classification of industries (at 3-digit level), and (ii) using two alternative additive measures of market concentration. Consistent findings across alternative indices at disaggregate level are expected to give robust conclusions in this regard. Further, the HHI is considered as a standard measure of market concentration and used widely in empirical research.

  11. Three-year moving averages of the variables reduce their temporal variations. Hence, one may expect that such inter-locking would make the variables independent of the random disturbance term.

  12. Using such average measure of the dependent variable is very important in a multidimensional framework, as in such a framework, the adjustment process is likely to be slow and a single lag dependent variable based on annual values as an explanatory variable may not be enough to capture the entire dynamics of the model.

  13. For the details on GRS, see Ginevicius and Cibra (2009).

  14. High advertising intensity of existing firms may require the potential entrants to incur disproportionately high advertising expenses to win over the incumbents, and this may discourage entry.

  15. There are evidences (e.g., Scherer and Ross 1990) of positive relationship between profit margin and advertising intensity.

  16. It is observed that expenditure on distribution and marketing activities results in higher profitability (Majumdar 1997).

  17. There are evidences (e.g., Mishra and Chandra 2010; Mishra and Vikas 2010) of no significant impact of innovation on firms’ profitability in Indian pharmaceutical industry.

  18. Since industry is the unit of observation in the present context, endogeneity problem is unlikely to be acute (Salinger et al. 1990).

  19. The use of such dynamic models is favored, especially, for panels that have a large number of cross-sectional units with a small number of time periods, as we have in the present case. This is so because their estimation methods do not require larger time periods to obtain consistent parameter estimates.

  20. Use of lagged value is a widely used practice to control the endogeneity problem (e.g., Gupta 2005; Aschhoff and Schmidt 2008; Clemens et al. 2012). Since the present paper estimates dynamic model, lagged explanatory variables capture both short and long-term effects, and hence are expected to be valid instruments. More importantly, since the three-year moving averages of the variables are used, such measures also add deeper lags in the process. Further, the method of system GMM adds both lagged vales of the variables and their differences as the instruments. This improves efficiency of the estimates as well.

  21. It is also found that there is no severe multicollinearity as the variance inflation factors (VIFs) are very low.

  22. These contradictions may also largely be due to model specification and period of analysis. For example, while both Kambhampati and Parikh (2005) and Mishra (2008) have added majority of the variables as the independent variables like the present paper, impact of vertical integration is not controlled in either of these two studies. Hence, inclusion of vertical integration in the present paper makes marked departure from nay of the existing studies and this is reflected in the findings. Further, while Kambhampati and Parikh (2005) and Mishra (2008) focused in the 1990s and applied Arellano and Bond (1991) dynamic panel data estimation techniques, the present paper covers the decade of 2000s and applies the system GMM of Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998). Such differences in period of coverage and estimation techniques might have bearings on the findings of the present paper vis-à-vis the earlier studies.

References

  • Adelman MA (1955) Concept and statistical measure of vertical integration. In: NBER (ed) Business Concentration and Price Policy. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 281–330

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahn SC, Schmidt P (1995) Efficient estimation of models for dynamic panel data. J Econ 68(1):5–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson TW, Hsiao C (1982) Formulation and estimation of dynamic models using panel data. J Econ 18(1):47–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58(2):277–297

    Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bover O (1995) Another look at instrumental variables estimation of error component models. J Econ 68(1):29–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aschhoff B, Schmidt T (2008) Empirical evidence on the success of R&D cooperation—happy together? Rev Ind Organ 33(1):41–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asker J (2004) Diagnosing foreclosure due to exclusive dealing, Working Paper 04–36, Leonard N. Stern School of Business, Department of Economics, New York University

  • Bain JS (1951) Relation of profit rate to industrial concentration: American manufacturing, 1936-1940. Q J Econ 65(3):293–324

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bain JS (1956) Barriers to new competition: their character and consequences in manufacturing industries. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Balcer Y, Lippman SA (1984) Technological expectations and adoption of improved technology. J Econ Theory 34(2):292–318

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balestra P, Nerlove M (1966) Pooling cross section and time-series data in the estimation of a dynamic model: the demand for natural gas. Econometrica 34(3):585–612

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basant R, Mishra P (2016) Trends in strategies and performance of the Indian corporate sector what has changed in two decades of economic reforms?, working paper no 2016-03-31. Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad

    Google Scholar 

  • Basant R, Saha SN (2005) Determinants of entry in the Indian manufacturing sector, working paper no 2005-01-01. Indian Institute of Management, Ahmedabad

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol WJ, Penzar JC, Willig RD (1982) Contestable markets and the theory of industry structure. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, San Diego

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhandari A (2010) Concentration, entry barriers and profitability in the Indian industries: an empirical analysis. J Quant Econ 8(2):61–80

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhargava A, Sargan J (1983) Estimating dynamic random effects models from panel data covering short periods. Econometrica 51(6):1635–1660

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya M (2002) Industrial concentration and competition in Malaysian manufacturing. Appl Econ 34(17):2127–2134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhuyan S (2005) Does vertical integration effect market power? Evidence from U. S. Food manufacturing industries. J Agric Appl Econ 37(1):263–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Bond S (1998) Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J Econ 87(1):115–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Branstetter LG (2004) Do stronger patents induce more local innovation? J Int Econ Law 7(2):359–370

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlton DW (1979) Vertical Integration in Competitive Markets under Uncertainty, J Ind Econ 27(3):189–209

  • Carlton DW, Perloff J (2005) Modern industrial organization, 4th edn. Pearson Addison Wesley, Boston

  • Cefis E (1998) Persistence in profitability and in innovative activities, Working Paper. Bocconi University and University of Bergano

  • Chamberlin EH (1933) The theory of monopolistic competition. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Chatterjee S (1986) Types of synergy and economic value: the impact of acquisitions on merging and rival firms. Strateg Manag J 7(2):119–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chipty T (2001) Vertical integration, market foreclosure, and consumer welfare in the cable television industry. Am Econ Rev 91(3):428–453

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi I (2001) Unit root tests for panel data. J Int Money Financ 20(2):249–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clemens MA, Radelet S, Bhavnani RR, Bazzi S (2012) Counting chickens when they hatch: timing and the effects of aid on growth. Econ J 122:590–617

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica 4(16):386–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Comanor WS, Wilson TA (1967) Advertising, market structure and performance. Rev Econ Stat 49(4):423–440

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Comanor WS and Wilson TA (1974) Advertising and Market Power, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press

  • Das BJ, Chappell WF, Shughartii WF (1993) Advertising, competition and market share instability. Appl Econ 25(11):1409–1412

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delorme CD, Klein PG, Kamerschen DR, Voeks LF (2002) Structure conduct and performance: a simultaneous equations approach. Appl Econ 35(17):13–20

    Google Scholar 

  • Domowitz I, Hubbard RG, Petersen BC (1986) Business cycles and the relationship between concentration and price-cost margins. RAND J Econ 17(1):1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghose A (1975) Concentration and controls in the Indian industry. J Ind Econ 23(3):203–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ginevicius R, Cibra S (2009) Additive measurement of market concentration. J Bus Econ Manag 10(3):191–198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldar B, Aggarwal SC (2004) Trade Liberalization and Price-Cost Margin in Indian Industries, Working Paper No. 130. Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • Gort M (1962) Diversification and Integration in American Industry, Princeton: Princeton University Press

  • Grossman S, Hart O (1986) The costs and benefits of ownership: a theory of vertical and lateral integration. J Polit Econ 94(4):691–719

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gupta N (2005) Partial privatization and firm performance. J Financ 60(2):987–1015

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart O (1995) Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure. Oxford University Press, Clarendon Press, Oxford and New York

  • Hart O, Moore J (1990) Property rights and the nature of the firm. J Polit Econ 98(6):1119–1158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hastings JS (2004) Vertical relationships and competition in retail gasoline markets: empirical evidence from contract changes in Southern California. Am Econ Rev 94(1):317–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hastings JS, Gilbert RJ (2005) Market power, vertical integration and the wholesale price of gasoline. J Ind Econ 53(4):469–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hay D, Morris D (1991) Industrial economics and organization. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Hendricks K, McAfee RP (2000) A theory of bilateral oligopoly, with applications to vertical mergers. Mimeo, Department of Economics, University of Texas at Austin

  • Hinomoto H (1965) Capacity expansion with facilities under technological improvement. Manag Sci 11(5):581–592

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hortac ̧su A, Syverson C (2007) Cementing relationships: vertical integration, foreclosure, productivity, and prices. J Polit Econ 115(2):250–301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kambhampati US (1996) Industrial concentration and performance; a study of the structure, conduct and performance of Indian industry. Oxford University Press, Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • Kambhampati US, Parikh A (2005) Has liberalization affected profit margins in Indian industry? Bull Econ Res 57(3):273–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katrak H (1980) Industry structure, foreign trade and price-cost margins in Indian manufacturing industries. J Dev Stud 17(1):62–79

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koch JV (1980) Industrial organization and prices. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuhn KU, Wives X (1999) Excess entry, vertical integration, and welfare. RAND J Econ 30(4):575–603

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laffer AB (1969) Vertical Integration by Corporations, 1929-1965 The Review of Economics and Statistics, 51(1):91–93

  • Liebowitz SJ (1982) What do census price-cost margins measure? J Law Econ 25(2):231–246

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Majumdar S (1997) The impact of size and age on firm-level performance: some evidence from India. Rev Ind Organ 12(2):231–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin S (1979) Advertising, concentration, and profitability: the simultaneity problem. Bell J Econ 10(2):639–647

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin S (1988) Market power and/or efficiency? Rev Econ Stat 70(2):331–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin S (1993) Advanced Industrial Economics, Oxford: Blackwell Publishers

  • Martin S (1994) Industrial economics: economic analysis and public policy. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs

    Google Scholar 

  • McAfee RP (1999) The effects of vertical integration on competing input suppliers. Fed Reserv Bank Cleve Econ Rev 35(1):2–8

    Google Scholar 

  • McDonald JT (1999) The determinants of firm profitability in Australian manufacturing. Econ Rec 75(2):115–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mishra P (2008) Concentration-markup relationship in Indian manufacturing sector. Econ Polit Wkly 43(39):74–81

    Google Scholar 

  • Mishra P, Chandra T (2010) Mergers, acquisitions and firms’ performance: experience of Indian pharmaceutical industry. Eurasian J Bus Econ 3(5):111–126

    Google Scholar 

  • Mishra P, Vikas (2010) Structure, conduct and performance in Indian pharmaceutical industry, a simultaneous equations investigation. Rev Dev Chang 15(1):69–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mishra P, Mohit D, Parimal (2011) Market concentration in Indian manufacturing sector: measurement issues. Econ Polit Wkly 46(49):76–80

    Google Scholar 

  • Mishra P, and Rao US (2014) Concentration vs. Inequality Measures of Market Structure: An Exploration of Indian Manufacturing, Economic and Political Weekly 49(33):59–65

  • Mueller DC (1990) The dynamics of company profits, an international comparison. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RL (1963) Concentration in the Manufacturing Industries of the United States, New Haven: Yale University Press

  • Newey WK, West KD (1994) Automatic lag selection in covariance matrix estimation. Rev Econ Stud 61(4):631–653

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nocke V, White L (2007) Do vertical mergers facilitate upstream collusion? Am Econ Rev 97(4):1321–1339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Normann HT (2009) Vertical integration, raising rival’s costs and upstream collusion. Eur Econ Rev 53(4):461–480

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nugent EJ, Hamblin DJ (1996) Improved methodologies for vertical integration research. Integr Manuf Syst 7(1):16–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ordover JA, Saloner G, Salop SC (1990) Equilibrium vertical foreclosure. Am Econ Rev 80(1):127–142

    Google Scholar 

  • Ornstein SI (1975) Empirical uses of the price-cost margin. J Ind Econ 24(2):105–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panchamukhi VR (1974) A Quantitative analysis of trade policies in India. In: Sandesara JC (ed) The Indian Economy: Performance and Prospects. University of Bombay, Bombay

    Google Scholar 

  • Perry M (1989) Vertical integration: determinants and effects. In: Schmalensee R, Willig R (eds) Handbook of Industrial Organization I. Elsevier

  • Perry MK (1978) Price discrimination and forward integration. Bell J Econ 9(1):209

  • Porter ME (1985) The competitive advantage. The Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Quirmbach H (1986) The path of price changes in vertical integration. J Polit Econ 94(5):1100–1109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rao PA (2001) A study of the determinants of firm profitability in selected industries in post-reform India, Unpublished M. Phil. Dissertation, Delhi School of Economics, University of Delhi

  • Ravenscraft DJ (1983) Structure-profit relationships at the line of business and industry level. Rev Econ Stat 65(1):22–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riordan MH (1998) Anticompetitive vertical integration by a dominant firm. Am Econ Rev 88:1232–1248

    Google Scholar 

  • Riordan MH (2005) Competitive effects of vertical integration, Discussion Paper No.: 0506–11, Department of Economic, Columbia University

  • Riordan MH, Salop SC (1995) Evaluating vertical mergers: a post-Chicago approach. Antitrust Law J 63(2):513–568

    Google Scholar 

  • Roodman D (2006) How to do xtabond2: an Introduction to “Difference” and “System” GMM in Stata, Working Paper No. 103. Center for Global Development, Washington DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosengren ES, James WM Jr (1994) Empirical evidence on vertical foreclosure. Econ Inq 32(2):303–317

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salinger M (1988) Vertical mergers and market foreclosure. Q J Econ 103(2):345–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salinger M, Caves RE, Peltzman S (1990) The concentration-margins relationship reconsidered. In: Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, pp 287–335

  • Saluja MR (1968) Structure of Indian economy: inter-industry flows and pattern of final demands 1964-65. Sankhya Ser B 30(1/2):97–122

    Google Scholar 

  • Sargan JD (1958) The estimation of economic relationships using instrumental variables. Econometrica 26(3):393–415

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scherer FM, Ross D (1990) Industrial market structure and economic performance. Rand Mcnally, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Shelton LM (1988) Strategic business fits and corporate acquisitions: empirical evidence. Strateg Manag J 9(3):279–287

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepherd WG (1982) Causes of industrial competition in the U. S. Economy, 1939-1980. Rev Econ Stat 64(4):613–626

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepherd WG, Shepherd JM (2004) The economics of industrial organization, 5th edn. Waveland Press, Inc., Long Grove

    Google Scholar 

  • Steiner PO (1975) Mergers, Motives, Effects and Policies, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press

  • Stigler G (1951) The division of labor is limited by the extent of the market. J Polit Econ 59(3):185–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler GJ (1964) A theory of oligopoly. J Polit Econ 72(1):44–61

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suzuki A (2008) Market foreclosure and vertical merger: a case study of the vertical merger between turner broadcasting and Time Warner. Int J Ind Organ 27(4):532–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole J (1988) The theory of industrial organization, MIT Press

  • Tucker IB and Wilder RP (1977) Trends in Vertical Integration in the U.S. Manufacturing Sector, Journal of Ind Econ 26(1):81–94

  • Weiss LW (1974) The concentration-profits relationship and antitrust. In: Goldschmid HJ, Michael Mann H, Fred Weston J (eds) Industrial concentration, the new learning. Little Brown, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson OE (1971) The vertical integration of production: market failure considerations. Am Econ Rev 61(2):112–123

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rakesh Basant.

Additional information

Publisher’s Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Basant, R., Mishra, P. Impact of Vertical Integration on Market Power in Indian Manufacturing Sector During the Post-Reform Period. J Ind Compet Trade 19, 561–581 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-019-00294-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-019-00294-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation