Skip to main content
Log in

Technology Transfer in Oligopoly in Presence of Fixed-Cost in Production

  • Published:
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper discusses different possibilities of licensing between Cournot duopolists with a technology characterized by constant marginal cost and positive fixed-cost. It is shown that optimal fixed-fee and per-unit royalty can be negative. This implies that the licensor can subsidize the licensee in the equilibrium to license its technology even if they compete in the output market in the post-licensing stage. Moreover superiority of up-front fee as an advance on royalties is also identified. The firm having lower marginal cost and higher fixed cost prefers royalty licensing than licensing by fixed-fee, while the other firm having lower fixed cost and higher marginal cost sometimes prefers fixed-fee licensing. Interestingly, a firm that earns less profit in the no-licensing stage may become the licensor of its technology.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Zachary (1999)

  2. See Reference for Business, Encyclopaedia of Business, 2nd ed.

  3. Published November 4, 2013 by Nokia - Press Release.

  4. See Fershtman and Kamien (1992) and Eswaran (1994) for example.

  5. Published December 3, 2007 by Toshiba - Press Release.

  6. Microsoft News Centre https://www.microsoft.com/en-us/news/press/2008/jan08/01-15msjvcpr.aspx

  7. See Marjit (1990), Wang (1998), Kamien and Tauman (1986), Sen and Tauman (2007), Fauli-Oller and Sandonis (2002) for example.

  8. Sen and Stamatopoulos (2009) consider the licensing by an outside innovator with technology characterized by zero fixed cost and identical linear marginal cost function. Beladi and Mukherjee (2013) consider technologies exhibiting significant decreasing returns in absence of any fixed-cost. Mukherjee (2013) shows licensing of a new product to all potential licensees in the presence of convex costs, which occur under decreasing returns to scale technologies.

  9. As reported by Korea Technology Transfer Center (KTTC), see http://www.wipo.int/export/sites/www/uipc/en/documents/pdf/tmc-korea.pdf

  10. According to Anderson (2013) a negative royalty rate might not be an abnormality if the patentee can offer other services that reduce the marginal costs of the licensee in addition to the innovation itself. It argues that if the innovation involves some kind of new machinery, the contract may also commit the patentee to provide maintenance of the equipment, thereby reducing the marginal costs further than the licensee could have managed on its own.

  11. COMMISSION REGULATION (EU) No 316/2014 of 21 March 2014 on the application of Article 101(3) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union to categories of technology transfer agreements.

  12. It can be assumed that the firms competing like Cournot duopolists are catering a specific part of the market as the government is restricting the rest of the market to a competitive fringe.

  13. The author wishes to thank an anonymous referee for pointing out this fact.

  14. See Appendix 3 for the general demand framework.

  15. This has been relaxed for two-part tariff licensing.

  16. In the pre-licensing stage output of firm i is \(q_{i}=\frac {a-2c_{i}+c_{j}}{3}\), i,j = 1,2 and ij. However, in the post licensing stage \(q_{1}^{T_{2}}=q_{2}^{T_{2}}=\frac {a-c_{2}}{3}\), where \(q_{1}^{T_{2}}\) and \(q_{2}^{T_{2}}\) are the output of firm 1 and firm 2 respectively.

  17. See Marjit (1990), Wang (1998), Mukherjee (2002), Sen and Tauman (2007) and others.

  18. As \(0<L(c_{1})<\bar {F_{2}}\) and \(F_{2}-F_{1}\in (0,\bar {F_{2}})\), this is possible.

  19. In the pre-licensing stage output of firm i is \(q_{i}=\frac {a-2c_{i}+c_{j}}{3}\), i,j = 1,2 and ij. However, in the post licensing stage \(q_{1}^{T_{1}}=q_{2}^{T_{1}}=\frac {a-c_{1}}{3}\), where \(q_{1}^{T_{1}}\) and \(q_{2}^{T_{1}}\) are the output of firm 1 and firm 2 respectively.

  20. As \(\frac {d{\Pi }_{2}^{r_{2}}}{dr_{2}}=\frac {5(a-c_{2}-2r_{2})}{9}\) must be positive as otherwise relation (3) will not be satisfied.

  21. In the pre-licensing stage output of firm i is \(q_{i}=\frac {a-2c_{i}+c_{j}}{3}\), i,j = 1,2 and ij. However, in the post licensing stage \(q_{1}^{r_{2}}=\frac {a-2(c_{2}+\bar {r_{2}})+c_{2}}{3}\) and \(q_{2}^{r_{2}}=\frac {a-2c_{2}+(c_{2}+\bar {r_{2}})}{3}\), where \(q_{1}^{r_{2}}\) and \(q_{2}^{r_{2}}\) are the output of firm 1 and firm 2 respectively.

  22. As \(\frac {d{\Pi }_{1}^{r_{1}}}{dr_{1}}=\frac {5(a-c_{1}-2r_{1})}{9}\) must be positive as otherwise relation (7) will not be satisfied.

  23. As \(0<L(c_{1})<\bar {F_{2}}\) and \(F_{2}-F_{1}\in (0,\bar {F_{2}})\), this is possible.

  24. In the pre-licensing stage output of firm i is \(q_{i}=\frac {a-2c_{i}+c_{j}}{3}\), i,j = 1,2 and ij. However, in the post licensing stage \(q_{2}^{r_{1}}=\frac {a-2(c_{1}+\bar {r_{1}})+c_{1}}{3}\) and \(q_{1}^{r_{1}}=\frac {a-2c_{1}+(c_{1}+\bar {r_{1}})}{3}\), where \(q_{2}^{r_{1}}\) and \(q_{1}^{r_{1}}\) are the output of firm 2 and firm 1 respectively.

  25. \(q_{I}^{r_{2}}>q_{I}\) as \(c_{1}>c_{2}+\bar {r_{2}}\) which follows from equation (5).

  26. It can be shown further that as firm 2 and firm 1 will employ royalty licensing and fixed-fee licensing (when fixed-fee is negative) respectively two-way transfer is possible as Y(c 1) is not always greater than X r(c 1). Two-way transfer is possible when Y(c 1)≤F 2F 1X r(c 1).

  27. As in the main text (Lemma 3), it can be argued that firm 2 will use the licensed technology even if T 1 < 0.

  28. It is discussed in Appendix C.1, that if one of the firm’s unit cost increases then the industry output falls.

References

  • Anderson F (2013) Licensing to a More Efficient Rival. The Manchester School. doi:10.1111/manc.12036

  • Beggs AW (1992) The licensing of patents under asymmetric information. Int J Ind Organ 10:171–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beladi H, Mukherjee A (2013) Optimal licensing contract under convex costs. Mimeo

  • Caballero-Sanz F, Moner-Colonques R, Sempere-Monerris JJ (2002) Optimal Licensing in a Spatial Model. Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, ENSAE 66:257–279

    Google Scholar 

  • Carvalho NP (2010) The TRIPS Regime of Patent Rights. Kluwer Law International

  • Eswaran M (1994) Cross-Licensing of Competing Patents as a Facilitating Device. Can J Econ 27:689–708

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fauli-Oller R, Sandonis J (2002) Welfare reducing licensing. Games Econ Behav 41:192–205

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Fershtman C, Kamien MI (1992) Cross licensing of complementary technologies. Int J Ind Organ 10:329–348

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallini NT, Wright BD (1990) Technology transfer under asymmetric information. Rand J Econ 21:147–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamien MI, Tauman Y (1986) Fees Versus Royalties and the Private Value of a Patent. Q J Econ 101:471–492

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Liao C, Sen D (2005) Subsidy in Licensing: Optimality and Welfare Implications. Manch Sch 73:281–299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macho-Stadler I, Perez-Castrillo D (1991) Contrats de licences et asymtrie d’information. Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, ENSAE 24:189–208

    Google Scholar 

  • Marjit S (1990) On a non-cooperative theory of technology transfer. Econ Lett 33:293–298

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Mukherjee A (2002) Subsidy and Entry: the Role of Licensing. Oxf Econ Pap 54:160–171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mukherjee A (2013) Licensing under convex costs. J Econ. doi:10.1007/s00712-013-0333-9

    Google Scholar 

  • Muto S (1993) On licensing policies in Bertrand competition. Games Econ Behav 5:257–267

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Ottoz E, Cugno F (2009) Hybrid Licensing of Product Innovations. Rev Law Econ 5:579–594

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rostoker MD (1984) A Survey of Corporate Licensing. IDEA: J Law Technol 24:59–92

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen D, Tauman Y (2007) General Licensing Schemes for a Cost-reducing Innovation. Games Econ Behav 59:163–186

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Sen D, Stamatopoulos G (2009) Technology transfer under returns to scale. Manch Sch 77:337–365

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen N (2014) Unilateral technology licensing from an entrant to incumbent monopolist. Econ Bull 34:1028–1037

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro C (1985) Patent Licensing R & D Rivalry. Am Econ Rev 75:25–30

    Google Scholar 

  • Vishwasrao S (2007) Royalties vs. fees: How do firms pay for foreign technology? Int J Ind Organ 25:741–759

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vives X (2001) Oligopoly Pricing: Old ideas and new tools. MIT Press

  • Wang XH (1998) Fee versus royalty licensing in a Cournot duopoly model. Econ Lett 60:55–62

    Article  MATH  ADS  Google Scholar 

  • Zachary GP (1999) Many Industries Are Congealing Into Lineup of Few Dominant Giants. Wall Street J

Download references

Acknowledgments

I am indebted to Dr. Sukanta Bhattacharya, University of Calcutta and Mr. Rajit Biswas, Economic Research Unit, Indian Statistical Institute, Kolkata for their valuable comments and suggestions. The author is also thankful to Dr. Arijit Mukherjee, Nottingham University Business School and Dr. Debapriya Sen, Ryerson University for the discussions he had with them. I am indebted to the anonymous referees and the managing editor of this journal in upgrading this paper. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Neelanjan Sen.

Appendices

The author wishes to thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this extension.

Appendix 1

From Eq. 5 of the main text we have

$${\Pi}_{1}^{r_{2}}(\bar{r_{2}})=\frac{[a-2(c_{2}+\bar{r_{2}})+c_{2}]^{2}}{9}-F_{2}={\Pi}_{1} $$

as firm 2 set the royalty rate as high as possible such that firm 1 is indifferent between licensing and not. From the above equation we get

$$a-c_{2}-2\bar{r_{2}}=\sqrt{(a-2c_{1}+c_{2})^{2}+9(F_{2}-F_{1})} $$

and it must be positive because if \(a-c_{2}-2\bar {r_{2}}<0\) then \({\Pi }_{1}^{r_{2}}(\bar {r_{2}})<{\Pi }_{1}\) and licensing will never be possible. Hence, \(\bar {r_{2}}=\frac {1}{2}\left [(a-c_{2})-\sqrt {(a-2c_{1}+c_{2})^{2}+9(F_{2}-F_{1})}\right ]\) and substituting in \({\Pi }_{2}^{r_{2}}(\bar {r_{2}})\) (defined in the main text) gives

$${\Pi}_{2}^{r_{2}}(\bar{r_{2}})=\frac{(a-c_{2})^{2}}{4}-\frac{5(a-2c_{1}+c_{2})^{2}}{36}-\frac{5(F_{2}-F_{1})}{4}-F_{2}. $$

This is the net profit of firm 2 if licensing is undertaken. Moreover for licensing to be profitable for firm 2, \({\Pi }_{2}^{r_{2}}(\bar {r_{2}})\) must be greater than Π2. This is possible if

$$ X^{r}(c_{1})=\frac{9(a-c_{2})^{2}-5(a-2c_{1}+c_{2})^{2}-4(a-2c_{2}+c_{1})^{2}}{45}\geq F_{2}-F_{1} $$
(A.1)

which is relation (6) of the main text, the necessary and sufficient condition for licensing with royalty from firm 2 to firm 1.

Appendix 2

As discussed in the main text firm 1 will charge the royalty rate as high as possible (\(\bar {r_{1}}\)) such that

$${\Pi}_{2}^{r_{1}}(\bar{r_{1}})=\frac{[a-2(c_{1}+\bar{r_{1}})+c_{1}]^{2}}{9}-F_{1}={\Pi}_{2}. $$

At this royalty rate firm 2 is indifferent between licensing and not. Manipulating the above equation we get

$$a-c_{1}-2\bar{r_{1}}=\sqrt{(a-2c_{2}+c_{1})^{2}+9(F_{1}-F_{2})}. $$

Moreover \(a-c_{1}-2\bar {r_{1}}\) must be positive. As if \(a-c_{1}-2\bar {r_{1}}<0\) then \({\Pi }_{2}^{r_{1}}(\bar {r_{1}})<{\Pi }_{2}\) and licensing will never be possible as firm 2 will always reject the offer. From the above equation we thereby get \(\bar {r_{1}}=\frac {1}{2}[(a-c_{1})-\sqrt {(a-2c_{2}+c_{1})^{2}+9(F_{1}-F_{2})}]\). Further substituting \(\bar {r_{1}}\) in \({\Pi }_{1}^{r_{1}}(\bar {r_{1}})\) (defined in the main text) gives

$${\Pi}_{1}^{r_{1}}(\bar{r_{1}})=\frac{(a-c_{1})^{2}}{4}-\frac{5(a-2c_{2}+c_{1})^{2}}{36}+\frac{5(F_{2}-F_{1})}{4}-F_{1}. $$

Moreover \({\Pi }_{1}^{r_{1}}(\bar {r_{1}})\geq {\Pi }_{1}\) if

$$ F_{2}-F_{1}\geq \frac{4(a-2c_{1}+c_{2})^{2}+5(a-2c_{2}+c_{1})^{2}-9(a-c_{1})^{2}}{45}=Y^{r}(c_{1}). $$
(B.1)

This is relation (9) of the main text which is the necessary and sufficient condition for licensing to be possible. As otherwise if the above inequality is not satisfied firm 1 will not be better off from licensing its technology and thereby not offer any royalty rate to firm 2.

Appendix 3 General Demand Structure

The author wishes to thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this extension.

1.1 Appendix 3.1 Basic Set-Up

The inverse market demand is P = f(q), where P is the price, q = q 1 + q 2 is the total output and q i , i = 1,2, is the output produced by the firm i. Assume same cost structure as in the main text.

Assumptions 1

  1. i)

    f (q)<0,

  2. ii)

    q 0 > 0 such that f(q) > 0 for q < q 0 and f(q)≤0 for qq 0 and

  3. iii)

    f (q) + q i f (q)≤0 for i = 1,2.

For firm i the profit function is Π i = [f(q)−c i ]q i F i , where c i and F i are the unit cost and fixed cost of firm i respectively. For profit maximization by firm i: F.O.C. is f(q)−c i + q i f (q)=0 and S.O.C. is 2f (q) + q i f (q)<0. The above assumptions are standard and guarantee the uniqueness and stability of Cournot equilibrium (see Vives 2001). These assumptions also ensure the uniqueness and stability of Cournot equilibrium is case of licensing. From the F.O.Cs. and S.O.Cs. it can be said that if the unit cost of any firm increases industry output will fall.

1.1.1 No Licensing

If there is no licensing, the profits of firm 1 and firm 2 are \({\Pi }_{1}=[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}-F_{1}\) and \({\Pi }_{2}=[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}-F_{2}\) respectively; \(q^{*}=q_{1}^{*}+q_{2}^{*}\), where \(q_{1}^{*}\) and \(q_{2}^{*}\) are the optimal output of the firm 1 and firm 2 respectively. As c 1 > c 2, therefore \(q_{1}^{*}<q_{2}^{*}\). These profits are assumed to be positive, which implies that \(F_{2}\in \left (0,\bar {F_{2}}=[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}\right )\), \(F_{1}\in \left (0,\bar {F_{1}}=[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}\right )\) and \(F_{2}-F_{1}\in (0,\bar {F_{2}})\) as F 2 > F 1.

1.2 Appendix 3.2 Fixed-Fee Licensing

Firm i offers a fixed-fee (T i ) to license its technology to firm j. The profit(net) of the firm i and firm j respectively are \({\Pi }_{i}^{T_{i}}\) and \({\Pi }_{j}^{T_{i}}\) for i,j = 1,2 when the offer of T i is accepted by firm j and technology is transferred.

1.2.1 Offer by Firm 2

Firm 2 offers T 2 such that \({\Pi }_{1}^{T_{2}}=[f(2q^{a})-c_{2}]q^{a}-F_{2}-T_{2}={\Pi }_{1}\), where q a is the output produced by each firm if firm 2 licenses its technology to firm 1. Therefore if \({\Pi }_{2}^{T_{2}}=[f(2q^{a})-c_{2}]q^{a}-F_{2}+T_{2}\geq {\Pi }_{2}\), such that licensing is profitable for firm 2 or

$$ X=2[f(2q^{a})-c_{2}]q^{a}-[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}-[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}\geq F_{2}-F_{1} $$
(C.1)

technology will be licensed at T 2 > 0. Moreover after licensing,

$$ {\Pi}_{2}^{T_{2}}=2[f(2q^{a})-c_{2}]q^{a}-[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}-2F_{2}+F_{1}. $$
(C.2)

As the unit cost of firm 1 reduces after transfer the industry output also increases after transfer, or \(2q^{a}>q_{1}^{*}+q_{2}^{*}\).

1.2.2 Offer by firm 1

Firm 1 offers T 1 such that \({\Pi }_{2}^{T_{1}}=[f(2q^{b})-c_{1}]q^{b}-F_{1}-T_{1}={\Pi }_{2}\), where q b is the output produced by each firm if firm 1 licenses its technology to firm 2.Footnote 28 As the unit cost of firm 2 increases after transfer the industry output gets reduced after transfer, or \(2q^{b}<q_{1}^{*}+q_{2}^{*}\). Moreover, \({\Pi }_{1}^{T_{1}}=[f(2q^{b})-c_{1}]q^{b}-F_{1}+T_{1}\geq {\Pi }_{1}\) must hold, such that licensing is profitable for firm 1 or

$$ Y=[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}+[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}-2[f(2q^{b})-c_{1}]q^{b}\leq F_{2}-F_{1}. $$
(C.3)

If technology is licensed then

$$ {\Pi}_{1}^{T_{1}}=2[f(2q^{b})-c_{1}]q^{b}-[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}-2F_{1}+F_{2} $$
(C.4)

and T 1≥0 if \(L=[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}-[f(2q^{b})-c_{1}]q^{b}\leq F_{2}-F_{1}\) (this is possible as \([f(2q^{b})-c_{1}]q^{b}>[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}\)) and T 1 < 0 otherwise.

Moreover, assume Π2 > Π1 or \(J=[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}-[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}>F_{2}-F_{1}\) and Y < J (as \([f(2q^{b})-c_{1}]q^{b}>[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}\)). Therefore if YF 2F 1 < J, firm 1 even though earning a lower profit in the no-licensing stage, will license its technology to firm 2.

1.3 Appendix 3.3 Royalty Licensing

Firm i offers a per-unit royalty (r i ) to license its technology to the other firm. Let the profit(net) of the firm i and firm j are respectively \({\Pi }_{i}^{r_{i}}\) and \({\Pi }_{j}^{r_{i}}\) for i,j = 1,2 when the offer of r i is accepted by firm j and technology is transferred.

1.3.1 Offer by Firm 2

Firm 2 offers a per-unit royalty (r 2) to firm 1 to license its technology. Let the profits of firm 1 and firm 2 respectively after the licensing be \({\Pi }_{1}^{r_{2}}=[f(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})-c_{2}-r_{2}]q_{1}^{r_{2}}-F_{2}\) and \({\Pi }_{2}^{r_{2}}=[f(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{r_{2}}-F_{2}+r_{2}q_{1}^{r_{2}}\), where \(q_{i}^{r_{2}}\) is the output of firm i.

The F.O.Cs for profit maximization of firm 1 and firm 2 respectively for given r 2 are

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} f(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})-c_{2}-r_{2}+q_{1}^{r_{2}}f^{\prime}(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})=0\\ f(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})-c_{2}+q_{2}^{r_{2}}f^{\prime}(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})=0 \end{array} $$
(C.5)

and the S.O.Cs are \(2f^{\prime }(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})+q_{i}^{r_{2}}f^{\prime \prime }(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})<0\) for i = 1,2.

Using the F.O.Cs and S.O.Cs it can be shown that

$$ \frac{\delta {\Pi}_{2}^{r_{2}}}{\delta r_{2}}=q_{1}^{r_{2}}f^{\prime}(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})\frac{\delta q_{1}^{r_{2}}}{\delta r_{2}}+q_{1}^{r_{2}}>0 $$
(C.6)

as \(\frac {\delta q_{1}^{r_{2}}}{\delta r_{2}}<0\). Therefore firm 2 will charge r 2 as high as possible such that \({\Pi }_{1}^{r_{2}}={\Pi }_{1}\) but c 2 + r 2 < c 1, as otherwise technology will never be licensed due to the increase in fixed-cost for firm 1. Finally technology is licensed to firm 1 if \({\Pi }_{2}^{r_{2}}\geq {\Pi }_{2}\) or

$$[f(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{r_{2}}+r_{2}q_{1}^{r_{2}}\geq[f(q_{1}^{*}+q_{2}^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}. $$

As, \(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}}>q_{1}^{*}+q_{2}^{*}\) and \(q_{2}^{r_{2}}<q_{2}^{*}\), r 2 must be positive. Therefore technology is licensed if

$$ X^{r}=[f(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})-c_{2}](q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})-[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}-[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}\geq F_{2}-F_{1} $$
(C.7)

and

$$ {\Pi}_{2}^{r_{2}}=[f(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})-c_{2}](q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})-[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}-2F_{2}+F_{1}. $$
(C.8)

1.3.2 Offer by Firm 1

Firm 1 offers a per-unit royalty (r 1) to firm 2 to license its technology. Let the profits of firm 2 and firm 1 respectively after the licensing be \({\Pi }_{2}^{r_{1}}=[f(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-c_{1}-r_{1}]q_{2}^{r_{1}}-F_{1}\) and \({\Pi }_{1}^{r_{1}}=[f(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{r_{1}}-F_{1}+r_{1}q_{2}^{r_{1}}\), where \(q_{i}^{r_{1}}\) is the output of firm i.

The F.O.Cs for profit maximization of firm 2 and firm 1 respectively given r 1 are

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} f(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-c_{1}-r_{1}+q_{2}^{r_{1}}f^{\prime}(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})=0\\ f(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-c_{1}+q_{1}^{r_{1}}f^{\prime}(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})=0 \end{array} $$
(C.9)

and the S.O.Cs are \(2f^{\prime }(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})+q_{i}^{r_{1}}f^{\prime \prime }(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})<0\) for i = 1,2.

As in the previous case, using the F.O.Cs and S.O.Cs it can be shown that

$$ \frac{\delta {\Pi}_{1}^{r_{1}}}{\delta r_{1}}=q_{2}^{r_{1}}f^{\prime}(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})\frac{\delta q_{2}^{r_{1}}}{\delta r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}}>0. $$
(C.10)

Therefore firm 1 will charge r 1 as high as possible such that \({\Pi }_{2}^{r_{1}}={\Pi }_{2}\). Finally firm 1 will license technology if \({\Pi }_{1}^{r_{1}}\geq {\Pi }_{1}\) or

$$[f(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{r_{1}}+r_{1}q_{2}^{r_{1}}\geq[f(q_{1}^{*}+q_{2}^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}. $$

Therefore technology is licensed if

$$ Y^{r}=[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}+[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}-[f(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-c_{1}](q_{1}^{r_{1}}+ q_{2}^{r_{1}})\leq F_{2}-F_{1} $$
(C.11)

and

$$ {\Pi}_{1}^{r_{1}}=[f(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-c_{1}](q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}-2F_{1}+F_{2}. $$
(C.12)

Moreover, r 1≥0 if \(L=[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}-[f(2q^{b})-c_{1}]q^{b}\leq F_{2}-F_{1}\) (this is possible as \([f(2q^{b})-c_{1}]q^{b}>[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}\)) and r 1 < 0 otherwise.

Moreover, assume \(J=[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}-[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}>F_{2}-F_{1}\) such that Π2 > Π1. Here also Y r < J (as \([f(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{r_{1}}>[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}\)). Therefore if Y rF 2F 1 < J, firm 1 even though earning a lower profit in the no-licensing stage, will license its technology to firm 2.

1.4 Appendix 3.4 Royalty vs Fixed-Fee

1.4.1 Firm 2’s Choice

Let us assume that Eqs. C.1 and C.7 are satisfied simultaneously such that firm 2 transfers its technology both in case of fixed-fee as well as royalty licensing. In case of fixed-fee licensing firm 2 gets (as in Eq. C.2)

$${\Pi}_{2}^{T_{2}}=2[f(2q^{a})-c_{2}]q^{a}-[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}-2F_{2}+F_{1} $$

and in case of royalty licensing it gets (as in Eq. C.8)

$${\Pi}_{2}^{r_{2}}=[f(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})-c_{2}](q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})-[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}-2F_{2}+F_{1}. $$

Let

$$ G_{2}={\Pi}_{2}^{r_{2}}-{\Pi}_{2}^{T_{2}}=[f(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})-c_{2}](q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})-2[f(2q^{a})-c_{2}]q^{a}, $$
(C.13)

where G 2 is the excess profit that firm 2 earns in case of royalty licensing than in case of fixed-fee.

If optimal r 2 = 0, then G 2 = 0 as \({\Pi }_{2}^{r_{2}}={\Pi }_{2}^{T_{2}}\) because \(q^{a}=q_{1}^{r_{2}}=q_{2}^{r_{2}}\). Firm 2 always sets optimal r 2 such that \({\Pi }_{1}^{r_{2}}={\Pi }_{1}\). When optimal r 2 = 0 then

$$ {\Pi}_{1}^{r_{2}}=[f(2q^{a})-c_{2}]q^{a}-F_{2}=[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}-F_{1}={\Pi}_{1}. $$
(C.14)

In case of fixed-fee licensing also, firm 2 sets optimal T 2 such that \({\Pi }_{1}^{T_{2}}={\Pi }_{1}\). The above equation thus implies that if optimal r 2 = 0 then optimal fixed-fee T 2 = 0 as \({\Pi }_{1}^{T_{2}}=[f(2q^{a})-c_{2}]q^{a}-F_{2}-T_{2}=[f(q^{*})-c_{1}]q_{1}^{*}-F_{1}={\Pi }_{1}\). So it can be argued that if c 2 = c 1 and F 2 = F 1 then technology will transferred but r 2 = 0 and T 2 = 0.

Hence, if c 1 > c 2 and F 1 < F 2 (as assumed in the model), then technology if transferred will be at r 2 > 0 (via royalty) or T 2 > 0 (via fixed-fee) as discussed earlier in the appendix. However (using Eq. C.5)

$$ \frac{dG_{2}}{dr_{2}}=q_{1}^{r_{2}}f^{\prime}(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})\left[\frac{dq_{2}^{r_{2}}}{d{r_{2}}}+\frac{dq_{1}^{r_{2}}}{d{r_{2}}}\right]>0 $$
(C.15)

as \(q_{1}^{r_{2}}>0,f^{\prime }(.)<0\) and \([\frac {dq_{2}^{r_{2}}}{d{r_{2}}}+\frac {dq_{2}^{r_{2}}}{d{r_{2}}}]<0\). Therefore \(G_{2}={\Pi }_{2}^{r_{2}}-{\Pi }_{2}^{T_{2}}>0\) always as optimal r 2 > 0, if firm 2 licenses its technology by per-unit royalty. Hence, firm 2 will prefer royalty licensing than licensing by fixed-fee.

Alternative proof From the Eq. C.13 \([f(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})-c_{2}](q_{1}^{r_{2}} +q_{2}^{r_{2}})\) and 2[f(2q a)−c 2]q a can be considered as the industry profit, when the unit cost of production is c 2 (for both the firms) in absence of fixed cost, if the industry output is \(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+ q_{2}^{r_{2}}\) and 2q a respectively. Moreover, \(q^{m}<q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}}<2q^{a}\) (where q m is the monopoly output produced by a firm using similar technology). As under royalty licensing (r 2 > 0) the effective unit cost of firm 1 is r 2 + c 2 for which the industry output is lower in case of royalty licensing than in case of fixed-fee.Footnote 29 If the industry output is above q m (which maximizes the industry profit), the industry profit falls if output increases. Hence, \([f(q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})-c_{2}](q_{1}^{r_{2}}+q_{2}^{r_{2}})\) must be greater than 2[f(2q a)−c 2]q a. Therefore \(G_{2}={\Pi }_{2}^{r_{2}}-{\Pi }_{2}^{T_{2}}>0\) always as optimal r 2 > 0 (and T 2 > 0). Hence, firm 2 will prefer royalty licensing than licensing by fixed-fee.

1.4.2 Firm 1’s choice

Let us assume that Eqs. C.3 and C.11 are satisfied simultaneously such that firm 1 transfers its technology both in case of fixed-fee as well as royalty licensing. In case of fixed-fee licensing firm 1 gets (as in Eq. C.4)

$${\Pi}_{1}^{T_{1}}=2[f(2q^{b})-c_{1}]q^{b}-[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}-2F_{1}+F_{2} $$

and in case of royalty licensing it gets (as in Eq. C.12)

$${\Pi}_{1}^{r_{1}}=[f(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-c_{1}](q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}-2F_{1}+F_{2}. $$

Let

$$ G_{1}={\Pi}_{1}^{r_{1}}-{\Pi}_{1}^{T_{1}}=[f(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-c_{1}](q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-2[f(2q^{b})-c_{1}]q^{b}, $$
(C.16)

where G 1 is the excess profit that firm 1 earns in case of royalty licensing than in case of fixed-fee.

If optimal r 1 = 0, then G 1 = 0 as \({\Pi }_{1}^{r_{1}}={\Pi }_{1}^{T_{1}}\) because \(q^{b}=q_{1}^{r_{1}}=q_{2}^{r_{1}}\). Firm 1 always sets optimal r 1 such that \({\Pi }_{2}^{r_{1}}={\Pi }_{2}\). When optimal r 1 = 0 then

$$ {\Pi}_{2}^{r_{1}}=[f(2q^{b})-c_{1}]q^{b}-F_{1}=[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}-F_{2}={\Pi}_{2}. $$
(C.17)

In case of fixed-fee licensing also, firm 1 sets optimal T 1 such that \({\Pi }_{2}^{T_{1}}={\Pi }_{2}\). The above equation thus implies that if optimal r 1 = 0 then optimal fixed-fee T 1 = 0 as \({\Pi }_{2}^{T_{1}}=[f(2q^{b})-c_{1}]q^{b}-F_{1}-T_{1}=[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}-F_{2}={\Pi }_{2}\).

So it can be argued that given c 1,F 2 a n d F 1 there exists a unique c 2 say \(c_{2}^{*}\) such that technology is transferred but r 1 = 0 and T 1 = 0. Hence, if \(c_{2}>c_{2}^{*}\), then technology if transferred will be at r 1 > 0 (via royalty) or T 1 > 0 (via fixed-fee) as Π2 falls if c 2 increases. On the other hand if \(c_{2}<c_{2}^{*}\), then technology may be transferred at r 1 < 0 (via royalty) or T 1 < 0 (via fixed-fee) as Π2 rises if c 2 falls. However (using Eq. C.9)

$$ \frac{dG_{1}}{d{r_{1}}}=q_{2}^{r_{1}}f^{\prime}\left( q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}}\right) \left[\frac{dq_{2}^{r_{1}}}{d{r_{1}}}+\frac{dq_{1}^{r_{1}}}{d{r_{1}}}\right]>0 $$
(C.18)

as \(q_{2}^{r_{1}}>0,f^{\prime }(.)<0\) and \([\frac {dq_{2}^{r_{1}}}{d{r_{1}}}+\frac {dq_{1}^{r_{1}}}{d{r_{1}}}]<0\). Therefore if firm 1 sets r 1 > 0, then \(G_{1}={\Pi }_{1}^{r_{1}}-{\Pi }_{1}^{T_{1}}>0\) and firm 1 will prefer royalty licensing than licensing by fixed-fee. However, if firm 1 sets r 1 < 0, then \(G_{1}={\Pi }_{1}^{r_{1}}-{\Pi }_{1}^{T_{1}}<0\) and firm 1 will prefer fixed-fee licensing than licensing by royalty. As firm 1 subsidizes (negative fixed-fee/negative royalty) if \(L=[f(q^{*})-c_{2}]q_{2}^{*}-[f(2q^{b})-c_{1}]q^{b}> F_{2}-F_{1}\), hence if L > F 2F 1 firm 1 will prefer fixed-fee licensing and royalty licensing otherwise.

Alternative proof From the Eq. C.16 \([f(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-c_{1}](q_{1}^{r_{1}} +q_{2}^{r_{1}})\) and 2[f(2q b)−c 1]q b can be considered as the industry profit, when the unit cost of production is c 1 (for both the firms) in absence of fixed cost, if the industry output is \(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}}\) and 2q b respectively. Moreover, \(q^{m}<q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}}<2q^{b}\) (where q m is the monopoly output produced by a firm using similar technology) because under royalty licensing if r 1 > 0 the effective unit cost of firm 1 is r 1 + c 1 for which the industry output is lower in case of royalty licensing than in case of fixed-fee. If the industry output is greater than q m (which maximizes the industry profit) the industry profit falls if output increases. Hence, \([f(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-c_{1}](q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})\) must be greater than 2[f(2q b)−c 1]q b. Therefore \(G_{1}={\Pi }_{1}^{r_{1}}-{\Pi }_{1}^{T_{1}}>0\) if optimal r 1 > 0 (and T 1 > 0). Hence, firm 1 will prefer royalty licensing than licensing by fixed-fee if optimal r 1 > 0 and T 1 > 0.

However, \(q^{m}<2q^{b}<q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}}\) if r 1 < 0 as the effective unit cost of firm 1 is r 1 + c 1 (< c 1) for which the industry output is greater in case of royalty licensing than in case of fixed-fee. If the industry output is above q m (which maximizes the industry profit) the industry profit falls if output increases. Hence, \([f(q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})-c_{1}](q_{1}^{r_{1}}+q_{2}^{r_{1}})\) must be lower than 2[f(2q b)−c 1]q b. Therefore \(G_{1}={\Pi }_{1}^{r_{1}}-{\Pi }_{1}^{T_{1}}<0\) if optimal r 1 < 0 (and T 1 < 0). Hence, firm 1 will prefer fixed-fee licensing than licensing by royalty if optimal r 1 < 0 and T 1 < 0.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sen, N. Technology Transfer in Oligopoly in Presence of Fixed-Cost in Production. J Ind Compet Trade 15, 383–409 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-015-0194-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-015-0194-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation