Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The Paradigm of Knowledge-Oriented Industrial Policy

  • Published:
Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper attempts to synthesize some of the outcomes of the evolution of thinking on industrial policy in the knowledge-based economy and the related advances in policy practice. The term “knowledge-oriented industrial policy” is used in the paper to denote a new brand of public sector interventions targeting various structural aspects of the economy through transmission channels and mechanisms that hinge on the driving forces of knowledge flows and stocks and incorporating a systemic understanding of the policy rationale. The paper outlines the theoretical background, the rationale and the operational framework as well as the design of knowledge-oriented industrial policy whose nature is highlighted by drawing attention to the distinctions between “traditional” and “knowledge-oriented” approaches and instruments. A simplified taxonomy of different categories of knowledge-oriented policy instruments is also presented in the paper. The specific features and effectiveness of these policy instruments are discussed by highlighting their knowledge functions, the policy transmission channels as well as other important characteristics.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. As a word of caution, industrial policy is usually assumed to define several distinctly different policy domains including “industrial strategy definition, competition policy and regulation, technological policy, regional and territorial policies,” etc. (Bianchi and Labory 2006a, b). In a comparative perspective, what we define as “knowledge-oriented industrial policy” only refers to the domains of industrial strategy definition and, to some extent, science and technology policy.

  2. In many of his writings during the 1920s, Keynes himself advocated “regulated competition” and other elements of active government intervention in the economy (Keynes 1981).

  3. For a historic overview of the evolution of industrial policy and its theoretical background see Bianchi and Labory (2006a).

  4. Some proponents of evolutionary economics even refer to it as the “new mainstream” in economics, together with the new institutional economics (Hodgson 2007).

  5. For an extensive coverage of different strands of evolutionary economics see the special issue of Research Policy, vol. 31(8–9), 2002, honouring the 20th anniversary of the publication of the path-breaking work of Nelson and Winter (1982).

  6. For an overview of the evolution of conceptual thinking on the economics of knowledge, including the so called “codification debate” see Cowan et al. (2000) and Foray (2004). For a more recent review of this debate see Balconi et al. (2007).

  7. For a discussion of the typologies of knowledge see Cowan et al. (2000) and Johnson et al. (2002). Sometimes “social technologies” or “organizational knowledge” is treated as a separate category of collective tacit knowledge (Nelson and Sampat 2001).

  8. For example, policy interventions aimed at knowledge sharing among potential stakeholders as discussed in Section 4.

  9. Competition policy per se is outside the scope of this paper. Related issues are discussed here only to the extent that they are closely interconnected with some aspects of knowledge-oriented industrial policy.

  10. This understanding can be traced back to Hayek’s (1978) interpretation of competition as an entrepreneurial discovery process.

  11. In its turn, knowledge created endogenously (e.g. through firm-based research) may result in knowledge spillovers which, in turn, may give rise to entrepreneurial opportunities. Such knowledge spillovers tend to be greater in the presence of higher investments in knowledge and hence entrepreneurial opportunities based on exploiting such knowledge spillovers will also be greater in such environment (Acs et al. 2005).

  12. Rodrik (2004) stresses the fact that the private costs in this process may exceed the social gains which is a fundamental asymmetry of any cost discovery process resulting in under-financing of investment in new or non-traditional activities.

  13. The main difference between development entrepreneurs and entrepreneurs in frontier innovation is that the market test for the former is the cost of the local product that they achieve (as the product is in principle available from import, local producers could only compete with it through price competition) whereas for the latter, the market test is the actual acceptance of the new product by the market.

  14. In some cases such alternative approaches also provide a more effective protection. A typical examples is algorithms, which as a rule are protected through trade secret.

  15. The term “behavioural additionalities” was introduced to denote the changes in firm behaviour in response to policy intervention (in contrast to input or output additionalities, which refer to responses traceable to firms’ factor inputs or output). See Buisseret et al. (1995); Nauwelaers and Wintjes (2003). It is consistent with the above mentioned evolutionary approach to the behavioural choice aspects of innovation.

  16. The so-called “strategic research partnerships/alliances” are a specific form of cooperative relationship associated with the undertaking of a collaborative effort with a significant R&D component, which brings together stakeholders with complementary capabilities. See NSF (2001) and Wessner (2003). Strategic research partnerships do not necessarily involve a public financing component (e.g., there exist both “private–private” and “public–private research alliances”) but may be targeted by other public policy instruments (Link et al. 2002)

  17. For an overview of funding policies and details on some of these programmes see Lepori et al. (2007) and UNECE (2007a).

  18. Often there are no clear distinctions between this type of policy instruments and those supporting the generation of knowledge (mentioned above); some of the instruments could easily be classified into either of these categories.

  19. The same economic logic holds for public support to development entrepreneurs who generate innovative entrepreneurial knowledge with commercial significance about the business viability of non-traditional products, given the underlying cost structure of the economy.

  20. For a comprehensive cross-country overview of policy initiatives addressing early stage financing see UNECE (2007b).

  21. As articulated by Rodrik (2004), ‘The trick for the government is not to pick winners, but to know when it has a loser.’

  22. For a discussion of conceptual issues see Rosenau (2000), Sadka (2006) and Spackman (2002).

  23. Rodrik (2004) provides an overview of a broad range of institutional arrangements involving strategic partnerships between the public and the private sectors a nd examples of practical implementation.

  24. The effectiveness of policy is usually evaluating by comparing the inputs (public resources) with the outcome of policy and the degree to which it meets its objectives. Effectiveness is closely intertwined with the notion of efficiency which relates the inputs (resources) with the outputs of a process. See Mandl et al. (2008).

  25. For example, the difficulties in assessing the effectiveness of some knowledge-oriented policy instruments are well documented and illustrated in Boekholt et al. (2001).

  26. An exception to this would be a diversification-oriented policy in the catching up economy: supporting development entrepreneurs who invest in non-traditional in that economy sectors and products imply the selective application of policies similar to those of promoting frontier innovation.

References

  • Acs, Z., Audretsch, D., Braunerhjelm, P., and Carlsson, B., “The knowledge spillover theory of entrepreneurship,” CEPR Discussion Papers No. 5326, Centre for Economic Policy Research: London, 2005.

  • Aghion, P., Blundell, R., Griffith, R., Howitt, O., and Prantl, S., “The effects of entry on incumbent innovation and productivity,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 5323, Centre for Economic Policy Research: London, 2005.

  • Aiginger, K., “Industrial policy: a dying breed or a re-emerging phoenix,” J Ind Compet Trade, vol. 7, no. 3–4, pp. 297–323, 2007. doi:10.1007/s10842-007-0025-7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Antonelli, C., “Knowledge complementarity and fungeability: implications for regional strategy,” Regional Studies, vol. 37, no. 6–7, pp. 595–606, 2003. doi:10.1080/0034340032000108705.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, E., and Thuriaux, B., “Introduction,” in European Commission, Future directions of innovation policy in Europe, Innovation Papers No. 31, pp. 1–9, 2003.

  • Arrow, K., “Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention,” in Nelson, R. (ed.), The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity: Economic and Social Factors. NBER Special Conference Series, Vol. 13. Princeton (Princeton University Press), pp. 609–625, 1962.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aschhoff, B., Fier, A., and Löhlein, H., “Detecting behavioural additionality—an empirical study on the impact of public R&D funding on firms’ cooperative behaviour in Germany,” ZEW Discussion Paper No. 06–037, Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW): Mannheim, 2006.

  • Bailey, D. and Cowling, K., “Industrial policy and vulnerable capitalism,” International Review of Applied Economics, vol. 20, no. 5, pp. 537–553, 2006. doi:10.1080/02692170601005481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bailey, D. and Driffield, N., “Industrial policy, FDI and employment: Still ‘missing a strategy,” J Ind Compet Trade, vol. 7, no. 3–4, pp. 189–211, 2007. doi:10.1007/s10842-006-7185-8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balconi, M., Pozzali, A., and Viale, R., “The ‘codification debate’ revisited: a conceptual framework to analyze the role of tacit knowledge in economics,” Industrial and Corporate Change, vol. 16, no. 5, pp. 823–849, 2007. doi:10.1093/icc/dtm025.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bianchi, P. and Labory, S., “From ‘old’ industrial policy to ‘new’ industrial development policies,” in Bianchi, B. and Labory, S. (eds.), International Handbook on Industrial Policy. Cheltenham (Edward Elgar), pp. 3–27, 2006a.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bianchi, P. and Labory, S., “Empirical evidence on industrial policy using state aid data,” International Review of Applied Economics, vol. 20, no. 5, pp. 603–621, 2006b. doi:10.1080/02692170601005556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boekholt, P., et al., “An international review of methods to measure relative effectiveness of technology policy instruments,” Final Report, July 2001 (available at http://www.technopolis-group.com/resources/downloads/reports/261_EZ_Final_010723.pdf).

  • Boschma, R. and Lambooy, J., “Evolutionary economics and economic geography,” Journal of Evolutionary Economics, vol. 9, no. 4, pp. 411–429, 1999. doi:10.1007/s001910050089.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buisseret, T., Cameron, H., and Georghiou, L., “What difference does it make? Additionality in the public support of R&D in large firms,” International Journal of Technology Management, vol. 10, no. 4–6, pp. 587–600, 1995.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlsson, B., Jacobsson, S., Holmén, M., and Rickne, A., “Innovation systems: analytical and methodological issues,” Research Policy, vol. 31, no. 2, pp. 233–245, 2002. doi:10.1016/S0048-7333(01)00138-X.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W., Nelson, R., and Walsh, J., “Protecting their intellectual assets: appropriability conditions and why U.S. manufacturing firms patent (or not),” National Bureau of Economic Research, NBER Working Papers, No. 7552, 2000.

  • Cowan, R., David, P., and Foray, D., “The explicit economics of knowledge codification and tacitness,” Industrial and Corporate Change, vol. 9, no. 2, pp. 211–253, 2000. doi:10.1093/icc/9.2.211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowling, K. (ed.), Industrial policy in Europe. Theoretical perspectives and practical proposals. London and New York (Taylor and Francis, Routledge), 1999.

  • Cowling, K., Oughton, C., and Sugden, R., “A reorientation of industrial policy? Horizontal policies and targeting,” in Cowling, K. (ed.), Industrial policy in Europe. Theoretical perspectives and practical proposals. London (Taylor and Francis), pp. 17–31, 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., “Technological paradigms and technological trajectories. A suggested interpretation of the determinant and direction of technological change,” Research Policy, vol. 11, no. 3, pp. 147–162, 1982. doi:10.1016/0048-7333(82)90016-6.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi, G., Malerba, F., Ramello, G., and Silva, F., “Information, appropriability, and the generation of innovative knowledge four decades after Arrow and Nelson: an introduction,” Industrial and Corporate Change, vol. 15, no. 6, pp. 891–901, 2006. doi:10.1093/icc/dtl028.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dopfer, K. and Potts, J., The general theory of economic evolution. London (Taylor and Francis), 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Earl, P., “The entrepreneur as a constructor of connections,” in Koppl, R. (ed.), Austrian Economics and Entrepreneurial Studies. Advances in Austrian economics, vol. 6. Amsterdam (Elsevier Science), pp. 113–130, 2003.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Fagerberg, J., and Srholec, M., “Catching up: What are the critical factors for success?” Working Papers on Innovation Studies No. 0401, Centre for Technology, Innovation and Culture, University of Oslo, 2005.

  • Foray, D., Economics of knowledge. Cambridge (MIT), 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  • Georghiou, L., “Issues in the evaluation of innovation and technology policy,” Evaluation, vol. 4, no. 1, pp. 37–51, 1998. doi:10.1177/13563899822208374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerschenkron, A., “Economic backwardness in historical perspective—a book of essays,”. Cambridge (Belknap Press of Harvard University Press), 1962.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanusch, H. and Pyka, A., “Principles of neo-Schumpeterian economics,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 31, no. 2, pp. 275–289, 2007a. doi:10.1093/cje/bel018.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanusch, H. and Pyka, A., Elgar companion to neo-Schumpeterian economics. Cheltenham (Edward Elgar), 2007b.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann, R. and Rodrik, D., “Economic development as self-discovery,” Journal of Development Economics, vol. 72, no. 2, pp. 603–633, 2003. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(03)00124-X.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F., “Competition as a discovery procedure,” in Hayek, F. (ed.), New Studies in Philosophy, Politics, Economics, and the History of Ideas. Chicago (University of Chicago Press), pp. 179–190, 1978.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A., Development projects observed. Washington (Brookings Institution), 1967.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A., Journeys toward progress: studies of economic policy-making in Latin America. New York (Twentieth Century Fund), 1963.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A., Strategy of economic development. New Haven (Yale University Press), 1958.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G., “Evolutionary and institutional economics as the new mainstream?” Evol Institutional Econ Rev, vol. 4, no. 1, pp. 7–25, 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, B., Lorenz, E., and Lundvall, B.-Å., “Why all this fuss about codified and tacit knowledge?” Industrial and Corporate Change, vol. 11, no. 2, pp. 245–262, 2002. doi:10.1093/icc/11.2.245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J., The Collected writings of John Maynard Keynes. Volume 19. Activities 1922–1929: The return to gold and industrial policy. London (Macmillan), 1981.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirzner, I., “Entrepreneurial discovery and the competitive market process: an Austrian approach,” Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 35, no. 1, pp. 60–85, 1997.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klerkx, L., and Leeuwis, C., Establishment and embedding of innovation brokers at different innovation system levels: Insights from the Dutch agricultural sector. Technol Forecast Soc Change (in press), 2009.

  • Lambooy, J. and Boschma, R., “Evolutionary economics and regional policy,” Annals of Regional Science, vol. 35, no. 1, pp. 113–131, 2001. doi:10.1007/s001680000033.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lepori, B. et al, “Comparing the evolution of national research policies: what patterns of change?” Science and Public Policy, vol. 34, no. 6, pp. 372–388, 2007. doi:10.3152/030234207X234578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Link, A., Paton, D., and Siegel, D., “An analysis of policy initiatives to promote strategic research partnerships,” Research Policy, vol. 31, no. 8–9, pp. 1459–1466, 2002. doi:10.1016/S0048–7333(02)00075–6.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundvall, B.-Å., “National innovation systems - analytical concept and development tool,” Industry and Innovation, vol. 14, no. 1, pp. 95–119, 2007. doi:10.1080/13662710601130863.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundvall, B.-Å., Johnson, B., Andersen, E., and Dalum, B., “National systems of production, innovation and competence building,” Research Policy, vol. 31, no. 2, pp. 213–231, 2002. doi:10.1016/S0048–7333(01)00137–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mandl, U., Dierx, A., and Ilzkovitz, F.,“The effectiveness and efficiency of public spending,” Economic Papers 301, European Commission, Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs: Brussels, 2008.

  • Martin, P., Mayer, T., and Mayneris, F., “Public support to clusters: a firm level study of French “local productive systems,” CEPR Discussion Papers No. 7102, Centre for Economic Policy Research: London, 2008.

  • Metcalfe, J., “Evolutionary economics and technology policy,” Economic Journal, vol. 104, no. 425, pp. 931–944, 1994. doi:10.2307/2234988.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe, J., “Science policy and technology policy in a competitive economy,” International Journal of Social Economics, vol. 24, no. 7–8–9, pp. 723–740, 1997.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe, J. (ed.), Evolutionary economics and creative destruction. Taylor and Francis, Routledge: London and New York, 1998.

  • Moreau, F., “The role of the state in evolutionary economics,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 28, no. 6, pp. 847–874, 2004. doi:10.1093/cje/beh038.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morrison, K. and Potts, J., “Industry policy as innovation policy,” in Hearn, G. and Rooney, D. (eds.), Knowledge Policy: Challenges for the 21st Century. Cheltenham, U.K. and Northampton, MA (Edward Elgar), pp. 163–175, 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morrison, K., and Potts, J., “Toward behavioural innovation economics—heuristics and biases in choice under novelty,” School of Economics Discussion Paper No. 379, The University of Queensland School of Economics, 2009.

  • Myrdal, G., Asian drama. An inquiry into the poverty of nations. New York (Twentieth Century Fund), 1968.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myrdal, G., Economic theory and the underdeveloped regions. New York (Harper), 1971.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nauwelaers, C. and Wintjes, R., “Towards a new paradigm for innovation policy?” in Asheim, B., Isaksen, A., Nauwelers, C., and Todling, F. (eds.), Regional Innovation Policy for Small-medium Enterprises. Cheltenham, U.K. and Northampton, MA (Edward Elgar), pp. 193–220, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R., “The simple economics of basic scientific research,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 67, no. 3, pp. 297–306, 1959. doi:10.1086/258177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R., (ed.), National innovation systems. A comparative analysis. Oxford University Press: Oxford, New York, Toronto and Melbourne, 1993.

  • Nelson, R. and Winter, S., An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, MA (Harvard University Press), 1982.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R. and Sampat, B., “Making sense of institutions as a factor shaping economic performance,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, vol. 44, no. 1, pp. 31–54, 2001. doi:10.1016/S0167–2681(00)00152–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • NSF Strategic research partnerships. Proceedings from an National Science Foundation workshop. NSF 01–336, National Science Foundation: Arlington, VA: 2001.

  • OECD Government R&D funding and company behaviour: measuring behavioural additionality. STI - Science Technology Industry, OECD: Paris, 2006.

  • Pack, H. and Saggi, K., “Is there a case for industrial policy? A critical survey,” World Bank Research Observer, vol. 21, no. 2, pp. 267–297, 2006. doi:10.1093/wbro/lkl001.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pelikan, P., and Wegner, G., (eds.), The evolutionary analysis of economic policy. Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, U.K. and Northampton, MA, 2003.

  • Peneder, M., “The problem of private under-investment in innovation: a policy mind-map,” Technovation, vol. 28, no. 8, pp. 518–530, 2008.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Radosevic, S., International technology transfer and ‘catch up’ in economic development. Cheltenham, U.K. and Northampton, MA (Edward Elgar), 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D., “Industrial policy for the twenty-first century,” CEPR Discussion Papers No. 4767, Centre for Economic Policy Research: London, 2004.

  • Rodrik, D., “Goodbye Washington consensus, hello Washington confusion? A review of the World Bank’s ‘Economic growth in the 1990s: Learning from a decade of reform’,” Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 44, no. 4, pp. 973–987, 2006. doi:10.1257/jel.44.4.973.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P., “Increasing returns and long-run growth,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 94, no. 5, pp. 1002–1037, 1986. doi:10.1086/261420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P., “Endogenous technological change,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 98, no. 5, pp. S71–S102, 1990.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenau, P., (ed.), Public–private policy partnerships. MIT Press: London, 2000.

  • Sadka, E., “Public–private partnerships: A public economics perspective,” IMF Working Paper No. WP/06/77, International Monetary Fund: Washington, D.C., 2006.

  • Sattler, H., “Appropriability of product innovations: an empirical analysis for Germany,” International Journal of Technology Management, vol. 26, no. 5–6, pp. 502–516, 2003. doi:10.1504/IJTM.2003.003420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shane, S. and Venkataraman, S., “The promise of entrepreneurship as a field of research,” Academy of Management Review, vol. 25, no. 1, pp. 217–226, 2000. doi:10.2307/259271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soete, L., “From industrial to innovation policy,” J Ind Compet Trade, vol. 7, no. 3–4, pp. 273–284, 2007. doi:10.1007/s10842–007–0019–5.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spackman, M., “Public–private partnerships: lessons from the British approach,” Economic Systems, vol. 26, no. 3, pp. 283–301, 2002. doi:10.1016/S0939-3625(02)00048-1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J., “Public policy for a knowledge economy,” Keynote speech at the CEPR-DIT conference “The Knowledge Driven Economy: Analytical and Policy Implications”, London, 27 January 1999 (available at http://www.worldbank.org/html/extdr/extme/knowledge-economy.pdf), 1999.

  • Stiglitz, J., “What is the role of the state?” in Humphreys, M., Sachs, J., and Stiglitz, J. (eds.), Escaping the Resource Curse. New York (Columbia University Press), pp. 23–52, 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. and Wallsten, S., “Public–private technology partnerships: promises and pitfalls,” American Behavioral Scientist, vol. 43, no. 1, pp. 52–74, 1999. doi:10.1177/00027649921955155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Torre, A., Gozzi, J., and Schmukler, S., “Innovative experiences in access to finance: market friendly roles for the visible hand?” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4326, The World Bank: Washington, D.C., 2007.

  • UNECE, Creating a conducive environment for higher competitiveness and effective national innovation systems. Lessons learned from the experiences of UNECE countries. United Nations Economic Commission for Europe: Geneva and New York, 2007a.

  • UNECE, Financing innovative development. Comparative review of the experiences of UNECE countries in early-stage financing. United Nations Economic Commission for Europe: Geneva and New York, 2007b.

  • UNECE, Enhancing the innovative performance of firms: policy options and practical instruments. U Nations Econ Comm Eur Geneva N Y (in press), 2009.

  • Wessner, C., (ed.), Government-industry partnerships for the development of new technologies, The National Academies Press: Washington, D.C., 2003.

  • Wessner, C., (ed.), An assessment of the Small Business Innovation Research Program, National Research Council, The National Academies Press: Washington, D.C., 2007.

  • Winch, G. and Courtney, R., “The organization of innovation brokers: an international review,” Technology Analysis & Strategic Management, vol. 19, no. 6, pp. 747–763, 2007. doi:10.1080/09537320701711223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rumen Dobrinsky.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Dobrinsky, R. The Paradigm of Knowledge-Oriented Industrial Policy. J Ind Compet Trade 9, 273–305 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-009-0053-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-009-0053-6

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation