Skip to main content
Log in

Accumulation of cultural capital at the intersection of socio-demographic features and productive specializations

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Cultural Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper aims at introducing a conceptual framework and assessing how features of local systems combine with high levels of cultural capital. This framework encompasses the local productive specializations and socio-demographic characteristics, as well as their interplay. A review on related concepts and contributions helps to generate three hypotheses on place-based cultural capital. The paper works under the three hypotheses and applies the framework to an original dataset based on the Italian local systems. The results show how urban areas and made-in Italy local productive systems tend to associate with high levels of cultural capital. Moreover, the interplay between local productive specializations and socio-demographic characteristics highlights the role of place specificities. Such relations should be considered in the elaboration of culture-based policies of territorial development, and in further researches over the accumulative forces of cultural capital.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: Authors’ elaboration based on ISTAT (2015)

Fig. 2

Source: Authors’ elaboration, based on ISTAT (2015)

Fig. 3

Source: Authors’ elaboration

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Following the definition of Scott (1997), the culture-based goods and services refer to marketable outputs whose competitive qualities depend on cultural capital.

  2. Translation from the original Italian text.

  3. Before 2011, the degree of self-containment was defined by a minimum threshold (more than 75%), while from 2011, the threshold is identified by a flexible value based on the algorithm of Bond and Coombes (2007).

  4. LCIAR stands for LMAs Classifications Istat Annual Report.

  5. The LCIAR contains a large set of place-based and community-based information together with data on cultural factor accumulation at LMA level. See https://www.istat.it/it/informazioni-territoriali-e-cartografiche/sistemi-locali-del-lavoro.

  6. Soil occupation measures the extension of human settlements and includes two indicators: in the urban areas, the incidence of surfaces of urban centers, inhabited nuclei and productive areas, whereas in the extra-urban territory, the population density as a proxy of settlement consistency. The form of soil occupation concerns the average area of the built areas, and their concentration in the territory.

  7. These urban areas are not clustered in any specific part of Italy; rather, they are located all over the country.

  8. By comparing either PPS or SDEM coefficients’ magnitude, we can determine for which of them a change from 0 to 1 is translated in a larger/smaller probability of a level-by-level switch in the cultural vocation scale.

  9. A link test reported in Table 5 (in “Appendix 3”) confirms that the model is correctly specified.

  10. These local systems are located in the Center-North area of Italy. Specifically, Prato borders with Florence, while Busto Arsizio together with Milan and Como is nearby the border with Switzerland.

  11. We exclude all the interactions resulting in singletons (i.e., interactions with only one 1 LMA and n − 1 zeros) since they can overstate the statistical significance of the regression coefficients and may lead to incorrect inference.

References

  • Backman, M., & Nilsson, P. (2018). The role of cultural heritage in attracting skilled individuals. Journal of Cultural Economics,42(1), 111–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bathelt, H. (2005). Cluster relations in the media industry: Exploring the ‘distanced neighbour’ paradox in Leipzig. Regional Studies,39(1), 105–127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becattini, G. (2009). Ritorno al territorio. Bologna: Il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becattini, G. (2015). Beyond geo-sectoriality: The productive chorality of places. Investigaciones Regionales,32, 31–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, H. S. (1982). Art worlds. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bellandi, M., & Santini, E. (2017). Resilience and the role of arts and culture-based activities in mature industrial districts. European Planning Studies,25(1), 88–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bianchini, F., & Parkinson, M. (Eds.). (1993). Cultural policy and urban regeneration: The Western European experience. Manchester: Manchester University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bond, S., & Coombes, M. (2007). Travel to work areas: the 2007 review. Centre for Urban and Regional Development Studies, Newcastle University

  • Boal, I., & Herrero, L. C. (2018). Where are the artists? Analysing economies of agglomeration in Castile and León, Spain. Papers in Regional Science,97(4), 995–1016.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P. (1986). The forms of capital. In J. G. Richardson (Ed.), Handbook of theory and research for the sociology of education (pp. 241–258). New York: Greenwood.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cerisola, S. (2019). A new perspective on the cultural heritage–development nexus: The role of creativity. Journal of Cultural Economics,43(1), 21–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheng, S. W. (2006). Cultural goods creation, cultural capital formation, provision of cultural services and cultural atmosphere accumulation. Journal of Cultural Economics,30(4), 263–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooke, P., & Lazzeretti, L. (Eds.). (2008). Creative cities, cultural clusters and local economic development. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Darchen, S., & Tremblay, D. G. (2013). The local governance of culture-led regeneration projects: A comparison between Montreal and Toronto. Urban Research & Practice,6(2), 140–157.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P. (1987). Classification in art. American Sociological Review,52, 440–455.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunford, M. (2006). Industrial districts, magic circles, and the restructuring of the Italian textiles and clothing chain. Economic Geography, 82(1), 27–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, G. (2001). Cultural planning: An urban Renaissance?. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Falck, O., Fritsch, M., Heblich, S., & Otto, A. (2018). Music in the air: Estimating the social return to cultural amenities. Journal of Cultural Economics,42(3), 365–391.

    Google Scholar 

  • Florida, R. (2002). Bohemia and economic geography. Journal of Economic Geography,2(1), 55–71.

    Google Scholar 

  • Florida, R. (2005). Cities and the creative class. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gailmard, S. (2014). Statistical modeling and inference for social sciences. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garofoli, G. (2002). Local development in Europe: Theoretical models and international comparisons. European Urban and Regional Studies,9(3), 225–239.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huggins, R., & Thompson, P. (2015). Culture and place-based development: A socio-economic analysis. Regional Studies,49(1), 130–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huguenin, A., & Jeannerat, H. (2017). Creating change through pilot and demonstration projects: Towards a valuation policy approach. Research Policy,46(3), 624–635.

    Google Scholar 

  • ISTAT. (2015). La nuova geografia dei sistemi locali. Roma: Istituto Nazionale di Statistica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jacobs, J. (1969). The economies of cities. New York: Vintage Books, Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kebir, L. L., & Crevoisier, O. (2008). Cultural resources and regional development: The case of the cultural legacy of watchmaking. European Planning Studies,16, 1189–1205.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landry, C., & Bianchini, F. (1995). The creative city. London: Demos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Latané, B. (1996). Dynamic social impact: The creation of culture by communication. Journal of Communication,46(4), 13–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lazzeretti, L. (2003). City of art as a High Culture local system and cultural districtualization processes: The cluster of art restoration in Florence. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research,27(3), 635–648.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leriche, F., & Daviet, S. (2010). Cultural economy: An opportunity to boost employment and regional development? Regional Studies,44(7), 807–811.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mathews, V. (2014). Incoherence and tension in culture-led redevelopment. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research,38(3), 1019–1036.

    Google Scholar 

  • Menghinello, S. (2009). Measuring the internationalization of industrial districts. In G. Becattini, M. Bellandi, & L. De Propris (Eds.), A handbook of industrial districts (pp. 394–410). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mizzau, L., & Montanari, F. (2008). Cultural districts and the challenge of authenticity: The case of Piedmont, Italy. Journal of Economic Geography,8(5), 651–673.

    Google Scholar 

  • Molotch, H. (2002). Place in product. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research,26(4), 665–688.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nuccio, M., & Ponzini, D. (2017). What does a cultural district actually do? Critically reappraising 15 years of cultural district policy in Italy. European Urban and Regional Studies,24(4), 405–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Russo, M., & Hughes, T. P. (2000). Complementary innovations and generative relationships: An ethnographic study. Economics of Innovation and New Technology,9(6), 517–558.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sacco, P. L., & Crociata, A. (2013). A conceptual regulatory framework for the design and evaluation of complex, participative cultural planning strategies. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research,37(5), 1688–1706.

    Google Scholar 

  • Santagata, W. (2002). Cultural districts, property rights and sustainable economic growth. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research,26(1), 9–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, A. J. (1997). The cultural economy of cities. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 21(2), 323–339.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, A. J. (2014). Beyond the creative city: Cognitive–cultural capitalism and the new urbanism. Regional Studies,48(4), 565–578.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sforzi, F. (Ed.). (1997). I sistemi locali del lavoro 1991. Roma: Istituto Nazionale di Statistica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shi, S., Huang, K., Ye, D., & Yu, L. (2014). Culture and regional economic development: Evidence from China. Papers in Regional Science,93(2), 281–299.

    Google Scholar 

  • Srakar, A., Čopič, V., & Verbič, M. (2018). European cultural statistics in a comparative perspective: Index of economic and social condition of culture for the EU countries. Journal of Cultural Economics,42(2), 163–199.

    Google Scholar 

  • Storper, M., & Scott, A. J. (2009). Rethinking human capital, creativity and urban growth. Journal of Economic Geography,9(2), 147–167.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thiel, J. (2017). Creative cities and the reflexivity of the urban creative economy. European Urban and Regional Studies,24(1), 21–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Throsby, D. (1999). Cultural capital. Journal of Cultural Economics,13(1–2), 3–12.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tubadji, A., Osoba, B. J., & Nijkamp, P. (2015). Culture-based development in the USA: Culture as a factor for economic welfare and social well-being at a county level. Journal of Cultural Economics,39(3), 277–303.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank the anonymous referees for helpful comments on previous versions of this paper. The authors gratefully acknowledge the comments received by attendees at RSA conference 2017 and the precious suggestions provided by Marianna Mantuano (ISTAT).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Erica Santini.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Disclosures

The findings, interpretation and conclusion expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the policies or views of institutions they represent and its member countries. Errors, misinterpretations and omissions remain the responsibility of the authors.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1

See Figs. 4 and 5.

Fig. 4
figure 4

Source: Authors’ elaboration on ISTAT dataset

Classification and spatial distribution of Made-in Italy LMAs by Prevailing Productive Specialization (PPS).

Fig. 5
figure 5

Source: Authors’ elaboration on ISTAT dataset

Classification and spatial distribution of LMAs by socio-demographic characteristics (SDEM).

Appendix 2

The observed variable for LMAs cultural vocation level \( \varvec{CV}_{i} \) is related to the corresponding latent variable \( \varvec{CV}_{i}^{\varvec{*}} \) as:

$$\varvec{CV}_{i} = \left\{ {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {1\; = \;{\text{Peripheral}}\,{\text{Areas}}} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\;\varvec{CV}_{i}^{\varvec{*}} \le \mu_{1} ,} \hfill \\ {2\; = \;{\text{Tourism}}\,{\text{Driver}}} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\;\mu_{2} \le \varvec{CV}_{i}^{\varvec{*}} \le \mu_{1} ,} \hfill \\ {3\; = \;{\text{Cultural}}\,{\text{Entrepreneurship}}} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\;\mu_{3} \le \varvec{CV}_{i}^{\varvec{*}} \le \mu_{2} ,} \hfill \\ {4\; = \;{\text{Cultural}}\,{\text{Heritage}}\;{\text{Strength}}} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\;\mu_{4} \le \varvec{CV}_{i}^{\varvec{*}} \le \mu_{3} ,} \hfill \\ {5\; = \;{\text{Great}}\;{\text{Beauty}}} \hfill & {{\text{if}}\,\varvec{CV}_{i}^{\varvec{*}} \ge \mu_{4} .} \hfill \\ \end{array} } \right.$$
(2)

\( \varvec{CV}_{i} \) is treated as a categorical variable, with \( j \) numerical values assigned to each outcome as in (2). In our ordered probit model, the categorical variable \( \varvec{CV}_{i} \) is estimated as a linear function of the control variables plus a vector of cut points. Because there are \( Z = 5 \) alternatives, we calculate \( Z - 1 = 4 \) cut points (\( \mu_{1} \) to \( \mu_{4} \), with: \( - \;\infty = \mu_{1} < \cdots < \mu_{4} = + \;\infty \)).

The underlying model consists of an equation relating the latent cultural vocation (\( \varvec{CV}_{i}^{\varvec{*}} \)) to LMA categories (LMA), their socio-demographic (SDEM) and background characteristics of the LMA, the latter represented by the vector \( {\mathbf{X}}_{i} \).

$$ \varvec{CV}_{\varvec{i}}^{\varvec{*}} = \varvec{ }\beta_{0} + \beta_{1} {\text{LMA}} + \beta_{2} {\text{SDEM}} + \beta_{3} {\mathbf{X}}_{i} + \eta_{i} + \varepsilon_{j} $$

where \( \beta_{1} , \beta_{2} \) and \( \beta_{3} \) are the unknown parameters estimated using the maximum likelihood technique, \( \eta_{i} \) are the regional fixed effects, \( \varepsilon_{j} \) is the normally distributed error term. The model does not contain a constant term as it would be exactly collinear with the cut points. We can represent the probabilities of these outcomes if we assume a particular probability distribution. The probability of observing outcome \( i \) (Eq. 2) is equal to the probability that the estimated linear function, plus random error, is within the range of the cut points estimated for the outcome:

$$ {\mathbf{Pr}}\left( {\varvec{CV}_{j} = j} \right) = {\mathbf{Pr}}(\mu_{j - 1} < \varvec{CV}_{i}^{*} \le \mu_{ij} ). $$
(3)

Assuming the errors being distributed like a standard normal distribution \( N\left( {0,1} \right), \) the ordered probit model leads to the following probability function (4), that holds for \( \varvec{CV}_{j} \left[ {2, 4} \right] \)

$$ {\mathbf{Pr}}\left( {\varvec{CV}_{j} = j} \right) =\upphi\left( {\mu_{j} - {\mathbf{X}}_{i} \beta_{i} } \right) -\upphi\left( {\mu_{j - 1} - {\mathbf{X}}_{i} \beta_{i} } \right), $$
(4)

with \( \upphi\left( . \right) \) representing the cumulative distribution function of a standard normal distribution. Equations (5) and (6) yield, respectively, the probabilities for \( j \) = 5 (Great Beauty) or \( j \) = 1 (Peripheral Areas):

$$ {\mathbf{Pr}}\left( {\varvec{CV}_{j} = 5} \right) = 1 -\upphi\left( {\mu_{4} - {\mathbf{X}}_{i} \beta_{i} } \right). $$
(5)
$$ {\mathbf{Pr}}\left( {\varvec{CV}_{j} = 1} \right) =\upphi\left( {\mu_{1} - {\mathbf{X}}_{i} \beta_{i} } \right), $$
(6)

Appendix 3

See Tables 4, 5 and 6.

Table 4 Ordered probit full estimates.
Table 5 Link test.
Table 6 Robustness checks to CV scale variations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bellandi, M., Campus, D., Carraro, A. et al. Accumulation of cultural capital at the intersection of socio-demographic features and productive specializations. J Cult Econ 44, 1–34 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-019-09348-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-019-09348-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation