Skip to main content
Log in

Economic valuation of a contemporary art museum: correction of hypothetical bias using a certainty question

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Cultural Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Biases in contingent valuation exercises are often difficult to quantify and to correct due to the hypothetical nature of the method itself. One common problem is hypothetical bias, which in recent years has been addressed in various ways, particularly through the inclusion of a certainty question in the questionnaire. We analyse the impact of applying differing corrections based on the certainty question for double-bounded dichotomous economic valuation exercises. The empirical application is based on data gathered from four surveys conducted with various groups to obtain the value allocated to a modern art museum: the Museo Patio Herreriano de Arte Contemporáneo Español, in the city of Valladolid (Spain). Findings indicate that estimates of Willingness to Pay are significantly reduced when a higher certainty threshold is required, in other words when individuals are more certain of their choices. Furthermore, correction through recoding proved more severe than correction through exclusion.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Examples include those published by Bille Hansen (1997); Santagata and Signorello (2000); Cuccia and Signorello (2002); Sanz et al. (2003); Sanz (2004); del Saz and Montagud (2005) as well as other works reflected in the book by Navrud and Ready (2002).

  2. Vossler and Kerkvliet (2003) conducted a thorough review and classification of existing works.

  3. See Brown et al. (1996); Cummings et al. (1997) and Cummings and Taylor (1999).

  4. See Neil et al. (1994); Cummings et al. (1995); Loomis et al. (1996) and List (2001).

  5. For a thorough review of this question, see Berrens et al. (2002); Samnaliev et al. (2006) and the meta-analysis on hypothetical bias conducted by List and Gallet (2001) and Murphy et al. (2005).

  6. Cheap Talk does not seem to prove effective if short (Cummings and Taylor 1999, Poe et al. 2002; Aadland and Caplan 2003 and Brown et al. 2003) and when applied to respondents lacking experience (List 2001). Recent studies advocate applying this approach with caution, Aadland and Caplan (2006) evidencing that short and neutral cheap talk may increase bias rather than reducing it. Blumenschein et al. (2008) conclude that the effectiveness of cheap talk is low in comparison to other procedures that include different levels of certainty as a means of correcting hypothetical bias.

  7. Other authors to use qualitative scales include Blumenschein et al. (1998) and Johannesson et al. (1998).

  8. The initial recommendation to be found in NOAA (1994) posits the well-known “divide by 2” rule except when real market data are known.

  9. Champ et al. (1997) use 10 as a cut-off value, Thompson et al. (2002) use 9, Champ and Bishop (2001) 8 and Poe et al. (2002) and Vossler et al. (2003) use 7.

  10. We refer to passive use values originating from cultural heritage: option value, legacy value and existence value. See Navrud and Ready (2002) and Snowball (2008).

  11. In Spain 45.6% of museums are free (See Sect. 3.13 of the Internet address http://www.mcu.es/culturabase/cgi/um?L=0&N=&O=pcaxis&M=%2Ft11%2Fp11%2Fa2002%2F).

  12. See http://www.museopatioherreriano.org.

  13. In Spain, around two-thirds of museums are public, and the remaining third private with only 2% being a combination of the two, as is our case study. Over half of the museums in Spain are free and those which are not charge a symbolic price. The entrance fee for the Museo Patio Herreriano is three euros.

  14. In other words, in the manner used for funding public goods through aliquot contributions, deemed acceptable when valuing historical heritage and museums. See Bravi et al. (2002), Sanz (2004) and Báez (2006). The specific valuation question used in our research was: “Suppose that a special fund were to be set up to help finance the conservation and maintenance costs of the Museo Patio Herreriano and its activities. Suppose also that contributions to said special fund were to be made through a single annual donation. Bearing in mind the previously described situation, would you be willing to pay X € as a contribution to this special fund for the conservation and maintenance of the Museo Patio Herreriano?”. When affirmative answers were given, a higher amount was proposed and when a negative answer was given a lower amount was proposed.

  15. For the full algorithm see An and Ayala (1996). For its application here, we used a specific Matlab program which may be consulted in Sanz (2004).

  16. Sanz et al. (2003) perform parametric, semi parametric and non-parametric estimations in several contingent valuation exercises, findings from which proved robust and similar across the different methods.

  17. The amounts proposed in the valuation question were calculated on the basis of the annual amounts paid by the most representative Friends of the Museums associations in Spain. We consulted the annual friends quotas paid for the Museo Nacional Centro de Arte Reina Sofía (65 €), Museo Nacional de Escultura (30 €), Instituto Valenciano de Arte Moderno (36 €), Museo del Prado (70 €), etc.

  18. The full range of possible answers to questions were: (1) I already contribute through my taxes, (2) Those who are most interested in such things should pay, (3) I don’t believe in this kind of contribution, (4) I’m not interested in such issues, (5) I’d like to but at the moment I can’t, (6) I prefer to give my money to other causes. As pointed out, only answers (1) and (5) were deemed real zeros, whereas the rest were interpreted as protest responses.

  19. To obtain the adjusted data we used the Consumer Price Index drawn up by the Spanish National Statistics Institute.

  20. Champ and Bishop (2001) point out that respondents who give a positive WTP with low certainty are responsible for hypothetical bias.

  21. Loomis and Ekstrand (1998) also feel that hypothetical bias is mitigated when recoding only uncertain Yes answers.

  22. The use of scales from 1 to 10 is quite common for valuation, and in other studies which employ the same scale a cut-off point of 7 has been used (Poe et al. 2002 and Vossler et al. 2003), 8 (Champ and Bishop, 2001), 9 (Thompson et al. 2002) or 10 (Champ et al. 1997).

References

  • Aadland, D., & Caplan, A. J. (2003). Willingness to pay for curbside recycling with detection and mitigation of hypothetical bias. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 85(2), 492–502.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aadland, D., & Caplan, A. J. (2006). Cheap talk reconsidered: New evidence from CVM. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 60(4), 562–578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alberini, A., Boyle, K. J., & Welsh, M. P. (2003). Analysis of contingent valuation data with multiple bids and response options allowing respondents to express uncertainty. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 45(1), 40–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • An, M. Y. & Ayala, R. A. (1996). A simple algorithm for nonparametric estimation of distribution functions with arbitrarily grouped data. Working Paper 9602, Department of Economics, Duke University, Durham.

  • Azjen, I., Brown, T. C., & Carbajal, F. (2004). Explaining the discrepancy between intentions and actions: The case of hypothetical bias in contingent valuation. Society for Personality and Social Psychology, 30(9), 1108–1121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Báez, A. (2006). Aplicación de Técnicas de Valoración Contingente para la Evaluación del Patrimonio Histórico Urbano. El caso del Conjunto Histórico de la Ciudad de Valdivia (Chile), Tesis Doctoral, Departamento de Economía Aplicada, Universidad de Valladolid, Valladolid.

  • Berrens, R. P., Jenkins-Smith, H., Bohara, A. K., & Silva, C. L. (2002). Further investigation of voluntary contribution contingent valuation: Fair share, time of contribution, and respondent uncertainty. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 44(1), 144–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bille Hansen, T. (1997). The willingness-to-pay for the royal theatre in Copenhagen. Journal of Cultural Economics, 21(1), 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blumenschein, K., Blomquist, G., Johannensson, M., Horn, N., & Freeman, P. (2008). Eliciting willingness to pay without bias: Evidence from a field experiment. The Economic Journal, 118(1), 114–137.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blumenschein, K., Johannesson, M., Blomquist, G. C., Liljas, B., & O′Conor, R. M. (1998). Experimental results on expressed certainty and hypothetical bias in contingent valuation. Southern Economic Journal, 65(1), 169–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bravi, M., Scarpa, R., & Sirchia, G. (2002). Measuring WTP for cultural services in Italian Museums: A discrete choice contingent valuation analysis. In S. Navrud & R. C. Ready (Eds.), Valuing cultural heritage: Applying environmental valuation techniques to historic buildings, monuments and artifacts (pp. 184–199). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, T. C., Ajzen, I., & Hrubes, D. (2003). Further test of entreaties to avoid hypothetical bias in referendum contingent donations to a public good? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 46(2), 353–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, T. C., Champ, P. A., Bishop, R. C., & McCollum, D. W. (1996). Which response format reveals the truth about donations to a public good? Land Economics, 72(2), 152–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carson, R. T., Mitchell, R. C., Hanemann, W. M., Kopp, R. J., Presser, S. & Ruud, P. A. (1994). Contingent valuation and lost passive use: Damages from Exxon Valdez. Discussion paper 94-18, Resources for the Future, Washington DC.

  • Champ, P. A., & Bishop, R. C. (2001). Donation payment mechanisms and contingent valuation: An empirical study of hypothetical bias. Environmental and Resource Economics, 19(4), 383–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Champ, P. A., Bishop, R. C., Brown, T. C., & McCollum, D. W. (1997). Using donation mechanisms to value nonuse benefits from public goods. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 33(2), 151–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cuccia, T., & Signorello, G. (2002). A contingent valuation study of willingness to pay for heritage visits: Case study of noto. In I. Rizzo & R. Towse (Eds.), The economics of heritage: A study in the political economy of culture in Sicily (pp. 147–163). Cheltenham: Edwar Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummings, R. G., Elliott, S., Harrison, G. W., & Murphy, J. (1997). Are hypothetical referenda incentive compatible? Journal of Political Economy, 105(3), 609–621.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cummings, R. G., Harrison, G. W., & Rustrom, E. E. (1995). Homegrown values and hypothetical surveys: Is the dichotomous choice approach incentive-compatible? American Economic Review, 85(1), 260–266.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummings, R. G., & Taylor, L. (1999). Unbiased value estimates for environmental goods: A cheap talk design for the contingent valuation method. American Economic Review, 89(3), 649–665.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • del Saz, S., & Montagud, J. (2005). Valuing cultural heritage: The social benefits of restoring and old Arab tower. Journal of Cultural Heritage, 6(1), 69–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • EFTEC (2005). Valuation of the historic environment, Report prepared for English Heritage, London: The Heritage Lottery Fund, DCMS and the Department of Transport.

  • Ethier, R., Poe, G. L., Schulze, W. D., & Clark, J. (2000). A comparison of hypothetical phone and mail contingent valuation responses for green-pricing electricity programs. Land Economics, 76(1), 54–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, G. W. (2006). Experimental evidence on alternative environmental valuation methods. Environmental and Resource Economics, 34(1), 125–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, G. W., & Rutström, E. E. (2005). Experimental evidence on the existence of hypothetical bias in value elicitation methods. In C. R. Plott & V. L. Smith (Eds.), Handbook of experimental economics results. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johannesson, M., Liljas, B., & Johansson, P. O. (1998). An experimental comparison of dichotomous choice contingent valuation questions and real purchase decisions. Applied Economics, 30(5), 643–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, C. Z., & Mattsson, L. (1995). Discrete choice under preference uncertainty: An improved structural model for contingent valuation. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 28(2), 256–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List, J. A. (2001). Do explicit warnings eliminate the hypothetical bias in elicitation procedures? Evidence from field auctions for sportscards. American Economic Review, 91, 1498–1507.

    Google Scholar 

  • List, J. A., & Gallet, C. A. (2001). What experimental protocol influence disparities between actual and hypothetical stated values? Environmental and Resource Economics, 20(3), 241–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List, J. A., & Shogren, J. F. (1998). Calibration of the difference between actual and hypothetical valuations in a field experiment. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 37(2), 193–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loomis, J. B., Brown, T., Lucero, B., & Peterson, G. (1996). Improving validity experiments of contingent valuation methods: Results of efforts to reduce the disparity of hypothetical and actual WTP. Land Economics, 72(4), 450–461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loomis, J. B., & Ekstrand, E. R. (1998). Alternative approaches for incorporating respondent uncertainty when estimating willingness-to-pay: The case of the Mexican spotted Owl. Ecological Economics, 29(1), 29–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loomis, J. B., González-Caban, A., & Gregory, R. (1994). Substitutes and budget constraints in contingent valuation. Land Economics, 70(4), 499–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, C. (1998). A consistent method for calibrating contingent value survey data. Southern Economic Journal, 64(3), 665–681.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mourato, S. & Mazzanti, M. (2002). Economic valuation of cultural heritage: Evidence and prospects. In M. de la Torre (Ed.), Assessing the values of cultural heritage, (pp. 51–76). Los Angeles: Research Report, The Getty Conservation Institute.

  • Murphy, J. J., Allen, P. G., Stevens, T. H., & Weatherhead, D. (2005). A meta-analysis of hypothetical bias in stated preference valuation. Environmental and Resource Economics, 30(3), 313–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • National Oceanographic Atmospheric Administration. (1994). Proposed rules for valuing environmental damages. Federal Register, 59(5), 1062–1191.

    Google Scholar 

  • Navrud, S., & Ready, R. C. (Eds.). (2002). Valuing cultural heritage: Applying environmental valuation techniques to historic buildings, monuments and artifacts. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neil, H. R. (1995). The contest of the substitutes in CVM studies: Some empirical observations. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 29(3), 393–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neil, H. R., Cummings, R. G., Ganderton, P. T., Harrison, G. W., & McGuckin, T. (1994). Hypothetical surveys and real economic commitments. Land Economics, 70(2), 145–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Noonan, D. S. (2002). Contingent valuation studies in the arts and culture: An annotated bibliography. Working Paper, Cultural Policy Center, University of Chicago, Chicago.

  • Noonan, D. S. (2003). Contingent valuation and cultural resources: A meta-analytic review of the literature. Journal of Cultural Economics, 27(3–4), 159–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pearce, D. S., Mourato, S., Navrud, S., & Ready, R. C. (2002). Review of existing studies, their policy use and future research needs. In S. Navrud & R. C. Ready (Eds.), Valuing cultural heritage: Applying environmental valuation techniques to historic buildings, monuments and artifacts (pp. 257–271). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poe, G. L., Clark, J. E., Rondeau, D., & Schulze, W. D. (2002). Provision point mechanisms and field validity test of contingent valuation. Environmental and Resource Economics, 23(1), 105–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ready, R. C., Whitehead, J. C., & Blomquist, G. C. (1995). Contingent valuation when respondents are ambivalent. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 29(2), 181–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samnaliev, M., Stevens, T. H., & More, T. (2006). A comparison of alternative certainty calibration techniques in contingent valuation. Ecological Economics, 57(3), 507–519.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Santagata, W., & Signorello, G. (2000). Contingent valuation of a cultural public good and policy design: The case of “Napoli Musei Aperti”. Journal of Cultural Economics, 24(3), 181–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanz, J. A. (2004). Valoración económica del patrimonio cultural. Gijón: Trea S. L.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanz, J. A., Herrero, L. C., & Bedate, A. M. (2003). Contingent valuation and semiparametric methods: A case study of the National Museum of Sculpture in Valladolid, Spain. Journal of Cultural Economics, 27(3–4), 241–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schulze, W. D., D’Arge, R. C., & Brookshire, D. S. (1981). Valuing environmental commodities: Some recent experiments. Land Economics, 57(2), 151–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Snowball, J. D. (2008). Measuring the value of culture: Methods and examples in cultural economics. Berlin: Springer Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, E., Berger, M., Blomquist, G., & Allen, S. (2002). Valuing the arts: A contingent valuation approach. Journal of Cultural Economics, 26(2), 87–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, B. J., Throsby, C. D. & Withers, G. A. (1983). Measuring community benefits from the arts. Research Paper no 261, School of Economic and Financial Studies, Macquarie University, Sidney.

  • Throsby, C. D., & Withers, G. A. (1983). Measuring the demand for the arts as a public good: Theory and empirical results. In W. S. Hendon & J. L. Shanahan (Eds.), Economics of cultural decisions (pp. 177–191). Cambridge: Abt Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vossler, C. A., Ethier, R., Poe, G. L., & Welsh, M. P. (2003). Payment certainty in discrete choice contingent valuation responses: Results from a field validity test. Southern Economic Journal, 69(4), 886–902.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vossler, C. A., & Kerkvliet, J. (2003). A criterion validity test of the contingent valuation method: Comparing hypothetical and actual voting behavior for a public referendum. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 45(3), 631–649.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, H. (1997). Treatment of ‘Don’t-Know’ responses in contingent valuation surveys: A random valuation model. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 32(2), 219–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Welsh, M. P., & Poe, G. L. (1998). Elicitation effects in contingent valuation: Comparisons to a multiple bounded discrete choice approach. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 36(2), 170–185.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whitehead, J. C., Blomquist, G. C., Ready, R. C., & Huang, J. (1998). Construct validity of dichotomous choice contingent valuation questions. Environmental and Resource Economics, 11(1), 107–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ana María Bedate.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bedate, A.M., Herrero, L.C. & Sanz, J.Á. Economic valuation of a contemporary art museum: correction of hypothetical bias using a certainty question. J Cult Econ 33, 185–199 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-009-9098-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-009-9098-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation