Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Can public arts education replace arts subsidization?

  • Published:
Journal of Cultural Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The debate about whether the arts should be supported or not is far from new, and most governments support the arts in one way or the other. The literature considers several arguments in favor of such interventions. Public education may seem to be an action which could, in the long run, lead to possible reductions of subsidies. Surveys show that those who have been exposed to the arts when young participate more when adult. However, the “non-market” transmission from parents to children generates an external effect, which has to be taken into account to reach first-best situations. We construct an overlapping generations model in which young consumers are exposed to both public education toward the arts and to non-altruistic transmission of such a taste from their parents. We show that the first-best can be reached only if there is both public cultural education and subsidization of arts consumption. Therefore, education cannot be considered as a substitute for subsidies to arts consumption. However, as is often the case in European countries, government intervention is usually below the first-best level. Using a model calibrated on French data, we show that it is then preferable to subsidize education, while consumption, especially of the older generations, should be taxed rather than subsidized.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In 1990, governmental assistance was $900 million, while charitable contributions amounted to $650 million. See Heilbrun and Gray (1993, p. 8). Paul Mellon alone gave away some $600 million during the last 50 years. See The Art Newspaper, April 1999.

  2. On the debate about the funding by the National Endowment for the Arts, see Marquis Goldfarb (1995).

  3. See The Art Newspaper, April 1999.

  4. See The Art Newspaper, February 1999.

  5. See also Chap. 11 in Heilbrun and Gray (1993).

  6. See Le Journal des Arts, April 1999.

  7. See also Heilbrun and Gray (1993, p. 362).

  8. Bisin and Verdier (2001) were among the first to study the dynamics of cultural transmission. Their model aims at studying the stationary distribution of preference traits. We are interested in the tradeoff between arts education and arts subsidiation.

  9. The model studied by Bisin and Verdier (2001) also assumes that parents transfer their culture to their offsprings in a paternalistic way.

  10. In terms of the Stigler and Becker model, this process could also be described in two steps. “Taste for the arts” is produced by a function that depends on the consumption of arts and on human capital produced within the household (say, through learning by doing) by accumulating the effects of past tastes.

  11. As is the case for the external effects of human capital in e.g., Lucas (1988) or Azariadis and Drazen (1990).

  12. Note that there is only one good in this economy. This can be rationalized if arts production results from a linear technology that transforms the usual consumption good into art. By a suitable normalization, both goods can then be aggregated.

  13. See Appendix, sections “First-order conditions of the welfare optimum”, “Steady-state conditions for consumers’ equilibrium” and “Decentralizing the welfare optimum” for detailed calculations.

  14. No subsidy is needed only if \(\phi_{\lambda}^{\prime}=0. \) This will be so in a population in which the cultural level of the family has no action on the level of cultural appreciation of the young, i.e., if λ t  = ϕ(e t−1, a t ) instead of the formulation suggested in Eq. 1, or if there is satiation in λ at the optimal level of education, or before this level is reached.

  15. See Appendix.

  16. Therefore, the results are not general. We have an example of an economy in which b, the cultural good consumed when old, is an inferior good, and the results that will be described do not hold. But our conjecture is that if all the goods in the model are normal—as they are in the Cobb-Douglas economy—the results that we derive should hold.

  17. The theoretical results presented in the Appendix can also be expressed in terms of ratios T*/w* and e*/w*. This makes the calibration exercise easier to deal with.

  18. It is difficult to estimate the value of T/w* with more accuracy, since arts are supported at different levels (central or federal, state, local, etc.), and no global accounts are available.

  19. Parents buy books that they want to read, and do not necessarily think of their childrens’ utility when choosing. The books are of course also available for their children to read, but this is considered as paternalism, and not as altruism, and leads to external effects.

  20. Recall that, for simplicity, we assume that Ω = 1.

  21. See Maresca and Pouquet (2000).

References

  • Azariadis, C., & Drazen, A. (1990). Threshold externalities in economic development. Quarterly Journal of Economics, CV, 501–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J., & Bowen, W. G. (1965). On the performing arts: The anatomy of their economic problems. American Economic Review, 55, 8–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J., & Bowen, W. G. (1966). Performing arts: The economic dilemma. New York: The Twentieth Century Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S., & Tomes, N. (1986). Human capital and the rise and fall of families. Journal of Labor Economics, 4, S1–S39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergonzi, L., & Smith, J. (1996). Effects of arts education on participation in the arts. Santa Ana, CA: National Endowment for the Arts.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bisin, A., & Verdier, T. (2001). The economics of cultural transmission and the dynamics of preferences. Journal of Economic Theory, 97, 298–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grampp, W. D. (1989). Pricing the priceless. Art, artists and economics. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heilbrun, J., & Gray, C. M. (1993). The economics of art and culture. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, 3–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maresca, B., & Pouquet, L. (2000). Les dépenses culturelles des Français au milieu des années 1990. Département des Etudes et de la Prospective.

  • Marquis Goldfarb, A. (1995). Art lessons. Learning from the rise and fall of public art funding. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J., & Becker, G. S. (1977). De gustibus non est disputandum. American Economic Review, 67, 76–90.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to two anonymous referees for their excellent suggestions. We are grateful to David de la Croix and Louis-André Gérard-Varet for comments on previous versions. Ginsburgh gratefully acknowledges financial support from CNRS, Paris and from the Belgian Government under Contract PAI P4/01.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Luc Champarnaud.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 First-order conditions of the welfare optimum

An interior optimal solution of the welfare optimum of Sect. 3, should satisfy all the first-order conditions as well as the transversality conditions of the Lagrangian function where Ωt q t and Ωt p t are the multipliers associated with the constraints of the program. From these first-order conditions, one can derive the following conditions that should be satisfied in the stationary state of the welfare optimum:

$$ \Upomega f^{\prime}(k^{\ast}) = 1 $$
(A1)
$$ u_c^{\prime} = p^{\ast} $$
(A2)
$$ u_d^{\prime} = \Upomega p^{\ast} $$
(A3)
$$ q^{\ast}\phi_a^{\prime} = p^{\ast} $$
(A4)
$$ u_{\mu}^{\prime}\psi_b^{\prime} = \Upomega p^{\ast} $$
(A5)
$$ \Upomega q^{\ast}\phi_e^{\prime} = p^{\ast} $$
(A6)
$$ u_{\lambda}^{\prime} + u_{\mu}^{\prime}\psi_{\lambda}^{\prime} = (1 - \Upomega \phi_{\lambda}^{\prime})q^{\ast} $$
(A7)
$$ \lambda^{\ast} = \phi(e^{\ast}, \lambda^{\ast}, a^{\ast}) $$
(A8)
$$ k^{\ast} + c^{\ast} + a^{\ast} + d^{\ast} + b^{\ast} + e^{\ast} = f(k^{\ast}). $$
(A9)

In all these expressions, the derivatives are taken in the optimum. Combining (A2) and (A3), one sees that

$$ \Upomega u_c^{\prime}=u_d^{\prime} $$
(A10)

Combining (A2), (A4) leeds to \(q^{\ast} = u_c^{\prime}/\phi_a^{\prime}.\) Replacing q* by this expression in (A7), one obtains

$$ (u_{\lambda}^{\prime} + u_{\mu}^{\prime}\psi_{\lambda}^{\prime})\phi_a^{\prime} = (1 - \Upomega \phi_{\lambda}^{\prime})u_c^{\prime}. $$
(A11)

Finally, from (A3) and (A5)

$$ u_{\mu}^{\prime}\psi_b^{\prime} = u_d^{\prime}. $$
(A12)

1.2 Steady-state conditions for consumers’ equilibrium

In the steady-state, the following first-order conditions hold (for an interior solution):

$$ u_c^{\prime} = (1+r)u_d^{\prime} $$
(A13)
$$ (1-\theta^a)u_c^{\prime} = (u_{\lambda}^{\prime} + u_{\mu}^{\prime}\psi_{\lambda}^{\prime})\phi_a^{\prime} $$
(A14)
$$ (1-\theta^b)u_d^{\prime} = u_{\mu}^{\prime}\psi_b^{\prime}, $$
(A15)

and the budget constraints

$$ c = w - T^1 - (1-\theta^a)a - s $$
(A16)
$$ d = (1+r)s - T^2 - (1-\theta^b)b $$
(A17)

are satisfied.

1.3 Decentralizing the welfare optimum

We now check whether and how the first-best can be decentralized as a steady-state equilibrium solution. The steady-state resource constraints of the centralized problem are obviously satisfied in every equilibrium. With competitive producers, lump-sum transfers to consumers make it possible to reach the optimal capital stock for which, by (A1), f′(k*) = Ω−1. Therefore, it is sufficient (a) to verify that the first-best satisfies the steady-state first-order conditions (A13)–(A15) of the consumers’ problem, (b) to compute the necessary lump-sum transfers in order to satisfy the consumers’ budget constraints (A16)–(A17) and (c) to verify whether the government’s budget is in equilibrium.

  1. (a)

    By (15) and (A1), r* = Ω−1−1, and (A13) coincides with (A10). So do (A14) and (A11) iff \(\theta^a = \Upomega \phi_{\lambda}^{\prime}.\) Finally, (A15) coincides with (A12) iff θb = 0.

  2. (b)

    Setting s = k*, r = Ω−1−1, w = f(k*) − k*f′(k*) = f(k*) − Ω−1 k*, equilibrium values for the transfers can be computed as:

    $$ T^1=f(k^{\ast}) - \Upomega^{-1} k^{\ast} - (c^{\ast} + (1-\theta^a)a^{\ast} + k^{\ast}) $$
    (A18)
    $$ T^2 = \Upomega^{-1} k^{\ast} - (d^{\ast} + b^{\ast}), $$
    (A19)

    using (A16) and (A17).

  3. (c)

    Finally, adding (A18) and (A19) and using (A9), it is straightforward to check that:

    $$ T^{\ast} = T^1 + T^2 = e^{\ast} + \theta^a a^{\ast}, $$

    which shows that the government budget (8) is also in equilibrium.

1.4 Second-best in a Cobb-Douglas economyFootnote 20

1.4.1 The Marshallian demand functions and calibration

We substitute (18) and (19) in (20), and obtain

$$ u = \hbox{log} c +\beta \hbox{log} d +\alpha_1 \hbox{log} a + \alpha_2 \hbox{log} b + \alpha_3 \hbox{log} e + \alpha_4 \hbox{log} \overline{\lambda}, $$
(B1)

where

$$ \alpha_1 = \alpha \eta_1 (1+ \beta \delta_2), \alpha_2 = \beta \alpha \eta_2, \alpha_3 = \alpha \rho (1+\beta \delta_2), \alpha_4 = \alpha \delta_1 (1+\beta \delta_2). $$
(B2)

To compute the indirect utility function, we first maximize (B1) under the budget constraint (17). This leads to the following Marshallian demand functions:

$$ c = \gamma (w^{\ast} - T), $$
(B3)
$$ d = \beta \gamma (w^{\ast} - T), $$
(B4)
$$ (1-\theta^a)a = \alpha_1 \gamma (w^{\ast} - T), $$
(B5)
$$ (1-\theta^b)b = \alpha_2\gamma (w^{\ast} - T), $$
(B6)

where γ = 1/(1 + β + α1 + α2).

Using French national accounts, as well as the results of a survey on cultural expenditures of French households carried out in 1995,Footnote 21 one can compute the (inclusive taxes and subsidies) expenditure shares reproduced in Table A, which also shows the corresponding parameters to which they correspond in the Marshallian demand functions (B3)–(B6).

These are the basic parameters for the Cobb-Douglas economy, from which most of the other parameters will be deduced. See Sect. 4.3.

1.4.2 Computation of the indirect utility function

To derive the indirect utility function, we replace in (B1) c, d, a and b by their expressions in (B3)–(B6), also taking into account that, in the fixed point, \(\lambda = \overline{\lambda}\) and that the government budget constraint \(e = T - \theta^a a - \theta^b b\) has to be satisfied. This leads to the following expression of the indirect utility function:

$$ \begin{aligned} V(\theta^a, \theta^b, w^{\ast} - T) =& (1/\gamma + \beta_1) \hbox{log} (w^{\ast} - T) + (\alpha_1 + \beta_1) \hbox{log} (1-\theta^a)^{-1} + \alpha_2 \hbox{log} (1-\theta^b)^{-1} \\ &+ \beta_2 \hbox{log} \left[T - (\alpha_1 \theta^a (1-\theta^a)^{-1} +\alpha_2 \theta^b (1-\theta^b)^{-1})\gamma (w^{\ast}-T)\right]+ \hbox{const}. \end{aligned} $$

where

$$ \beta_1=\alpha_4\eta_1/(1-\delta_1), \beta_2=\alpha_3+\alpha_4\rho/(1-\delta_1). $$
(B7)

To check for the concavity properties of this function, in θa < 1, θb < 1 for any T ≥ 0, w* − T > 0, e > 0, it is convenient to make the following substitution:

$$ x^a = -\theta^a/(1-\theta^a), x^b = -\theta^b/(1-\theta^b), $$
(B8)

which leads to the following expression for the indirect utility function:

$$ \begin{aligned} V(x^a, x^b, w^{\ast} - T) =& (1/\gamma + \beta_1) \hbox{log} (w^{\ast} - T) + (\alpha_1 + \beta_1) \hbox{log} (1-x^a) + \alpha_2 \hbox{log} (1-x^b)\\ +& \beta_2 \hbox{log} \left[T + (\alpha_1 x^a +\alpha_2 x^b)\gamma (w^{\ast}-T)\right]. \end{aligned} $$

It is easy to check that this function is concave in x a, x b < 1 (which is true when to values θa, θb < 1). Therefore, its maximum is characterized by the following first-order conditions:

$$ \begin{aligned} \partial V/\partial x^a =& -(\alpha_1 + \beta_1)/(1 - x^a)\\ &+ \alpha_1 \beta_2 \gamma (w^{\ast} - T)/[T + (\alpha_1 x^a + \alpha_2 x^b)\gamma (w^{\ast}-T)] = 0, \end{aligned} $$
(B9)

and

$$ \begin{aligned} \partial V/\partial x^b =& - \alpha_2/(1 - x^b)\\ & + \alpha_2 \beta_2\gamma (w^{\ast} - T) /[T + (\alpha_1 x^a + \alpha_2 x^b)\gamma (w^{\ast}-T)] = 0. \end{aligned} $$
(B10)

In the solution, the government budget constraint eT − θa a − θb b must also hold. Replacing a and b by (B5) and (B6), and using (B8), this constraint can be rewritten as:

$$ e = T +(\alpha_1 x^a +\alpha_2 x^b)\gamma (w^{\ast}-T). $$
(B11)

1.4.3 Solving for the second-best optimum

Solving the system of three equation (B9), (B10) and (B11) in three unknowns x a, x b and e leads to:

$$ e = \beta_2 [T +\gamma (\alpha_1 +\alpha_2)(w^{\ast}-T)]/(\alpha_1 + \beta_1 + \alpha_2 + \beta_2), $$
(B12)
$$ (1-x^a)^{-1} = (1-\theta^a)= \frac{\alpha_1(\alpha_1+\beta_1+\alpha_2+\beta_2)} {(\alpha_1+\beta_1)[(\alpha_1+\alpha_2)+T/\gamma(w^{\ast}-T)]}, $$
(B13)
$$ (1-x^b)^{-1} = (1-\theta^b)= \frac{(\alpha_1+\beta_1+\alpha_2+\beta_2)} {(\alpha_1+\alpha_2)+T/\gamma(w^{\ast}-T)}. $$
(B14)

Using (B12)–(B14), it is easy to check that:

  1. (a)

    e is increasing in T since γ(α1 + α2) < 1,

  2. (b)

    θa and θb are increasing in T,

  3. (c)

    θa >  θb.

Since θb is increasing in T and equal to zero in the first-best, we necessarily have θb < 0 in the second-best. The condition θa > 0 is equivalent to (α1 β2 − β1 α2) γ (w* − T) < (α1 + β1)T. There are thus two possibilities. Either α1β2 − β1α2 ≤ 0 so that θa > 0 for all T > 0. Or α1β2 − β1α2 > 0 and then θa < 0 for small T, i.e., for T such that T < γ(α1β2 − β1α2)/[α1 + β1 + γ (α1β2 − β1α2)]w*.

1.4.4 Some first-best results

To compare first-best and second-best results, we need T*, the first-best value of the government budget. This is obtained as follows. The first-best is the maximal value of the utility, obtained by substituting λ and μ by (18) and (19) in (20) and, in the fixed-point, setting \(\overline{\lambda} = \lambda,\) so that

$$ u^{\ast} = \hbox{log} c + \beta \hbox{log} d + (\alpha_1 + \beta_1) \hbox{log} a + \alpha_2 \hbox{log} b + \beta_2 \hbox{log} e. $$

The maximum of u* subject to the golden rule resources constraint f(k*) − k* = c + a + d + b + e, leads to

$$ e^{\ast} = \beta_2w^{\ast}/(1 + \beta + \alpha_1 + \beta_1 + \alpha_2 + \beta_2), $$
(B15)
$$ a^{\ast} = (\alpha_1 + \beta_1)w^{\ast}/(1 + \beta + \alpha_1 + \beta_1 + \alpha_2 + \beta_2), $$

since f(k*)−k* = w*. Using the fact that the values of the optimal subsidy rates are θa = δ1,   θb = 0, we obtain T* = e* +  δ1 a*, and

$$ T^{\ast} = [\beta_2 + \delta_1 (\alpha_1 + \beta_1)]w^{\ast}/(1 + \beta + \alpha_1 + \beta_1 + \alpha_2 + \beta_2). $$
(B16)

1.4.5 Parameterization of the Cobb-Douglas economy

From the values in Table A, it is easy to compute β ≃ 0.5, α1 = 0.018, and α2 = 0.006. We assume that the effect on the cultural stock of consuming arts is the same when young or old, which implies η1 = η2. Using (B2), one can check that α12 = (1 + βδ2)/β = 3 and δ2 ≃ 1, which can be interpreted as “nothing is lost” in the transmission of cultural capital to oneself (when “switching” from young to old). We also assume that the effect of education (ρ) on the stock of culture of the young is equal to (1 − δ1), to represent in a parametric way, the relative effects of education and family transmission.

Table A Values of the main parameters

Since it is hard to find values for α and δ1, we shall, in the simulations, parameterize α for values ranging from 0.05 to 0.2 and δ1 for values between 0.125 and 0.50.

Now the values of all the other parameters (α3, α4, β1, β2, η1, η2, ρ) can be computed as functions of α and δ1, using (B2) and (B7).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Champarnaud, L., Ginsburgh, V. & Michel, P. Can public arts education replace arts subsidization?. J Cult Econ 32, 109–126 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-008-9060-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-008-9060-4

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation