Skip to main content
Log in

Cultural goods creation, cultural capital formation, provision of cultural services and cultural atmosphere accumulation

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Cultural Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The cultural atmosphere in a society is accumulated over time through the consumption of cultural services and is diminished through depreciation. Using cultural capital (e.g., cultural heritage, paintings, music scores), cultural services are provided by the cultural-services industry (e.g., museums, opera houses); cultural capital is enlarged by new cultural goods created by individuals. Individuals’ utilities are positively affected by the cultural services they consume, by the cultural goods they create and by the cultural atmosphere and the cultural capital accumulated in society. In a laissez-faire economy, individuals tend to ignore the positive external effects of their cultural-services consumption and creation of cultural goods on other individuals via accumulating cultural atmosphere and cultural capital. Consequently, suboptimally little cultural atmosphere and cultural capital will be accumulated. The efficient intertemporal allocation can be restored by introducing an appropriate subsidy that not only stimulates consumers’ demand for cultural services and the creation of new cultural goods but also enhances the accumulation of cultural atmosphere and cultural capital.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For empirical investigations see, e.g., UNESCO (1998), Part one.

  2. The notion of “artist” is used here as a synonym for “creator of new cultural goods”.

  3. The cultural and technical skills of an individual can be interpreted as creativity in the sense of Throsby (2001, ch. 6).

  4. For convenience of referring to each term of (16) in text, the second line in (16) repeats the first line by assigning [1] = \({\dot{\mu}_g /\left({\delta +\alpha _g} \right)U_r Y_r}\), [2] = (n c U g /U y Y r )/(δ + α g ), etc. This procedure will also be applied in the subsequent equations.

  5. It would also be important, in the first place, to secure the existence of such an equilibrium. We conjecture that an equilibrium can be shown to exist, but a rigorous existence proof is beyond the scope of the present paper.

  6. One may cast into doubt the realism of the remaining Lindahl markets. Yet we defend our procedure on the grounds that in order not to blur the analysis by trying to deal with too many complex allocation problems simultaneously, we have to reduce complexity.

  7. τ k > 0 is a sales subsidy and τ sK <  0 [τ sK  > 0] is a subsidy [tax] on the purchase of cultural services.

References

  • Baumol, W., & Bowen, W. (1966). Performing ArtsThe Economic Dilemma. New York: The Twentieth Century Fund.

  • Blümel, W., Pethig, R., & von dem Hagen, O. (1986). The theory of public goods: A survey of recent issues. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 142, 241–309.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1998). Accounting for tastes. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

  • Coleman, J. (1990). Foundation of social theory. Cambridge: Belknap Press.

  • Frey, B. (2003). Public support. In R. Towse, (Ed.), A handbook of cultural economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

  • Fullerton, D. (1992). On justifications for public support of the arts, Journal of Cultural Economics, 16, 67–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heller, W., & Starrett, D. (1976). On the nature of externalities. In S. Lin (Ed.), Theory and measurement of economic externalities. New York: Academic Press.

  • Lindahl, E. (1919). Die Gerechtigkeit der Besteuerung. Lund, Swenden: Gleerupa Universitats-Boekhandeln.

  • Netzer, D. (1978). The subsidized muse. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Pethig, R., & Cheng, S. -W. (2002). Cultural capital and the consumption of cultural services. Schmollers Jahrbuch, 122, 445–468.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robbins, L. (Ed.), (1963). Art and the States. In Politics and Economics. New York: St. Martin’s Press.

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36, 387–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Throsby, D. (1999). Cultural capital. Journal of Cultural Economics, 23, 3–12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Throsby, D. (2001). Economics and culture. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Ulibarri, C. (2000). Rational philanthropy and cultural capital. Journal of Cultural Ecnomics, 24, 135–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UNESCO (1998). First World Culture Report. UNESCO, Paris.

Download references

Acknowledgements

Helpful comments by Rüdiger Pethig and three anonymous referees are gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sao-Wen Cheng.

Appendices

Appendix A: Derivation of the marginal conditions of Eq. (14)

The FOCs of Eq. (14) are as follows

$$\frac{\partial H}{\partial g_c}=n_c U_{g_c}-n_c\lambda_{gc}=0,$$
(A.1)
$$\frac{\partial H}{\partial g_s}=n_s\lambda _s S_g -n_s \lambda_{gs}=0,$$
(A.2)
$$\frac{\partial H}{\partial k_c}=n_c U_{k_c}+n_c \lambda _v V_{k_c} -n_c\lambda_k =0,$$
(A.3)
$$\frac{\partial H}{\partial r_s }=n_s\lambda _s S_r -n_s \lambda_r =0,$$
(A.4)
$$\frac{\partial H}{\partial r_v }=n_c\lambda _v V_r -n_c \lambda _r =0,$$
(A.5)
$$\frac{\partial H}{\partial r_y}=\lambda_y Y_r -\lambda_r =0,$$
(A.6)
$$\frac{\partial H}{\partial s_c}=n_c U_s +n_c\mu _k -n_c\lambda_{sc} =0,$$
(A.7)
$$\frac{\partial H}{\partial s_s}=-n_s \lambda_s +n_c n_s \lambda _{sc} =0,$$
(A.8)
$$\frac{\partial H}{\partial v_c }=n_c U_v +n_c \mu_g -n_c \lambda _v =0,$$
(A.9)
$$\frac{\partial H}{\partial y}=-\lambda_y +\lambda_c =0,$$
(A.10)
$$\frac{\partial H}{\partial y_c}=n_c U_y -n_c \lambda_c =0,$$
(A.11)
$$\dot{\mu}_g =\delta \mu_g -\frac{\partial H}{\partial g}= \delta\mu _g+\alpha _g \mu_g -n_c\lambda_{gc}-n_s \lambda_{gs} ,$$
(A.12)
$$\dot{\mu}_k =\delta\mu_k -\frac{\partial H}{\partial k}=\delta \mu_k+\alpha_k \mu_k -n_c \lambda_k .$$
(A.13)

Appendix B

Derivation of Eq. (15)

Taking (A.5): λ v = λ r /V r , (A.6): λ r = λ y Y r , (A.10): λ y = λ c and (A.11): λ c U y into account, (A.9): U v + μ g −λ v = 0 can be rearranged to μ g = (U y Y r )/V r U v , or, equivalently as (15): μ g /(U y Y r ) = 1/V r U v /(U y Y r ).

Derivation of Eq. (16)

Setting (A.9): μ g = (U y Y r )/V r U v , (A.1): λ gc U g_c , (A.2): λ gs = λ s S g , (A.4) and (A.6): λ s U y Y r /S r into (A.12): \({\dot {\mu}_g =\left({\delta +\alpha _g}\right)\mu _g -n_c \lambda _{gc}-n_s\lambda_{gs}}\), after some rearrangements in terms to get

$$ \dot {\mu }_g =\left( {\delta +\alpha _g } \right)\left( {\frac{1}{V_r }-\frac{U_v }{U_y Y_r }} \right)-n_c \frac{U_g }{U_y Y_r }-n_s \frac{S_g }{S_r}, $$

or, equivalently, Eq. (16).

Appendix C: Derivation of the marginal conditions of Eq. (25)

$$\frac{\partial H^C}{\partial g_c}=U_g-\beta_c p_{gc}=0,$$
(C.1)
$$ \frac{\partial H^C}{\partial k_c}=U_k +\beta_{vc} V_k-\beta_c p_{kc} =0, $$
(C.2)
$$ \frac{\partial H^C}{\partial r_v}=\beta_{vc}V_r -\beta _c p_r=0, $$
(C.3)
$$ \frac{\partial H^C}{\partial s_c}=U_s +\beta_S -\beta_c p_{sc}=0, $$
(C.4)
$$ \frac{\partial H^C}{\partial s_{cK}}=-\beta_S +\beta_c p_{sK}=0, $$
(C.5)
$$ \frac{\partial H^C}{\partial v_c}=U_v -\beta_{vc}+\beta_c p_v=0, $$
(C.6)
$$ \frac{\partial H^C}{\partial y_c}=U_y-\beta_c p_y =0. $$
(C.7)

Appendix D: Derivation of the marginal conditions of Eq. (27)

$$\frac{\partial H^Y}{\partial y}=p_y -\beta_y=0,$$
(D.1)
$$\frac{\partial H^Y}{\partial r_y}=-p_r +\beta_y Y_r=0.$$
(D.2)

Appendix E: Derivation of the marginal conditions of Eq. (29)

$$\frac{\partial H^S}{\partial g_s}=-p_{gs}+\beta _{sj}S_g=0,$$
(E.1)
$$\frac{\partial H^S}{\partial r_s}=-p_r+\beta _{sj}S_r=0,$$
(E.2)
$$\frac{\partial H^S}{\partial s_s }=p_s-\beta_{sj}=0.$$
(E.3)

Appendix F: Derivation of the marginal conditions of Eq. (31)

$$\frac{\partial H^G}{\partial g_G }=p_g -\beta _G =0,$$
(F.1)
$$\frac{\partial H^G}{\partial v_G }=-p_v +\varphi _g =0,$$
(F.2)
$$ \dot {\varphi }_g =\delta \varphi _g -\frac{\partial H^G}{\partial g}=\left( {\delta +\alpha _g } \right)\varphi _g -\beta _G =\left( {\delta +\alpha _g } \right)p_v -p_g . $$
(F.3)

Appendix G: Derivation of the marginal conditions of Eq. (33)

$$\frac{\partial H^K}{\partial k_K}=p_k-\beta_K =0,$$
(G.1)
$$\frac{\partial H^K}{\partial s_K}=-p_{sK}+\varphi_k =0,$$
(G.2)
$$ \dot{\varphi}_k =\delta\varphi_k-\frac{\partial H^K}{\partial k}=\left({\delta +\alpha _k}\right)\varphi_k-\beta_K =\left( {\delta +\alpha _k} \right)p_{sK}-p_k. $$
(G.3)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Cheng, SW. Cultural goods creation, cultural capital formation, provision of cultural services and cultural atmosphere accumulation. J Cult Econ 30, 263–286 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-006-9023-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-006-9023-6

Keywords

Jel Code

Navigation