Skip to main content
Log in

Investing in the roots of your political ancestors

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We use regional data for Greece between 1975–1989 to demonstrate a disproportionate allocation of public investment funds to prefectures that exhibited stronger support for the incumbent party. Our main empirical evidence comes from an Instrumental Variables (IV) analysis that exploits the discontinuity in Greece's political landscape after a brief military junta (1967–1974) to link the parties established after 1974 with their ancestors from the same 'political family' during the pre-dictatorial era. In particular, we show that the electoral strength of political ancestors influences the allocation of public investment. Moreover, there is a strong association between the political support of ancestor and descendant parties, both of which influence the allocation of public investment in prefectures with many core supporters. We also present evidence indicating that the appointment of deputy ministers from loyal prefectures of the incumbent party plays a significant mediating role in the allocation of public investment to prefectures with a strong base of core supporters.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Public infrastructure is best described as a centrally provided local public good (i.e. public good that generates localised benefits) or as a geographically targetable private good. See Knight (2004) for more details on this.

  2. A parallel strand of the literature investigates the possibility of party favouritism in the allocation of intergovernmental transfers (and public capital) to politically aligned local authorities. To address the possibility that alignment and public funding can be entirely driven by socio-economic factors influencing both dimensions, several of these studies employ a Regression Discontinuity Design in closely contested electoral races, as pioneered by Lee (2008) (see, e.g., Brolo and Nannicini, 2012; Bracco et al., 2015; Baskaran and Hessami, 2017; Curto-Grau et al., 2018; Kammas et al., 2023).

  3. Actually, Greece was part of the European ‘democratisation wave’, along with Portugal and Spain, which struggled with dictatorships in the second half of the twentieth century (see Huntington, 1993; Torregrosa-Het al.,and, 2015).

  4. See Appendix A for a detailed description of the electoral system.

  5. Proportional Representation (PR) electoral systems allocate seats to parties based on their electoral strength and then distribute these seats to individual candidates using various formulas. More specifically, in Closed-List Proportional Representation (CLPR), it is the party that ranks the candidates (prior to the election) and after the election the seats are allocated to individual candidates according to their rank in the party list. In OLPR, parties present a set of candidates running under their label but they do not rank them prior to the election. So, voters cast a ballot for an individual candidate and the parties receive seats in proportion to the sum of votes received by all the candidates running under their label. After the election, seats are distributed to individual candidates according to the number of personal votes they received. For example, suppose that a party is allocated n seats. The top n candidates, as determined by the number of votes they personally received, are those who win the legislative seats (for more details on this, see Cheibub and Sin, 2020).

  6. The Greek political landscape has historically been characterised by interpersonal patron–client networks, which were personally linked to specific MPs, primarily benefiting them and only indirectly benefiting their political parties (see, e.g., Meynaud, 2002).

  7. Notably, ‘long-term partisan loyalty’ refers to the repeated voting in favour of a party over extended periods and should not be confused with the notion of core supporters, which typically denotes voting in favour of a party in the previous election. Previous studies on pork-barrel politics primarily examine whether national governments allocate public resources to regions that supported the incumbent party in the most recent election (see, e.g., Cadot et al., 2006; Kauder et al., 2016; Luca and Rodríguez-Pose, 2019). To our knowledge, Joanis (2011) is the only other study that focuses on the concept of ‘long-run partisan loyalty’—that is, repeated voting in favour of a party over longer periods of time—rather than solely in the previous election.

  8. In fact, these 51 prefectures correspond to a total of 56 electoral constituencies. This discrepancy arises from the fact that the two major metropolitan areas of the country, Attiki and Thessaloniki, contain five and two electoral constituencies, respectively. To align our analysis with the available data on public investment flows at the NUTS-3 level, we have merged the electoral constituencies of Attiki and Thessaloniki to correspond to one prefecture each (see Psycharis, 2008).

  9. Notably, similar electoral systems ensured total control of the parliament by all subsequent one-party governments between 1974 and 1989. In contrast, the electoral law of proportional representation passed by PASOK before the election of 1989 prevented ND from forming a government despite its 5% lead in the popular vote over PASOK (see Verney, 1990).

  10. PASOK’s success led to a decline in the vote share obtained by Georgios Mavros’ centrist party, which slumped to 11.95%, eventually resulting in its gradual disintegration from the political system within a few years (Mavrogordatos, 1984).

  11. Specifically, we forward prefecture-level electoral results up to (and including) the year of the next general election (see, e.g., Jablonski, 2014).

  12. The opposition is measured as the combined share of votes received by the two leading opposition parties, EKND and PASOK, between 1974 and 1981. For the period between 1982 and 1989, the opposition share is represented solely by the dominant opposition party, ND. This distinction arises from the presence of a dominant opposition party (ND) during 1982–1989. By contrast, between 1974 and 1981, the centrist party EKND and PASOK alternated in second and third place, with their combined strength reaching approximately 35%. Additionally, we combine the vote shares of the two parties since PASOK absorbed the majority of EKND supporters during its growing influence.

  13. NUTS, which stands for Nomenclature of Territorial Units for Statistics, is a geocode standard established by EUROSTAT, the Statistical Office of the European Union. Within this system, LAU, denoting local administrative units, functions as the fundamental building block of NUTS and encompasses the municipalities of the European Union.

  14. In 1986, Greece introduced regions as second-level administrative units, dividing the country into 13 regions. These regions operate as an intermediary administrative level between the central government and the individual prefectures.

  15. The analysis does not include the share of the population with secondary education, as it is highly correlated (≈0.9) with the tertiary education variable.

  16. Given that Greece is a popular tourist destination, ideally, we would prefer to control for the employment share in tourism instead of using the variable services, but data for the former are unavailable.

  17. It is relevant to highlight that, when employing alternative specifications in our estimates of column (6), including the instrumental variable (IV) approach described in the subsequent section, the polynomial term of the variable victory margin is positive and statistically insignificant. This result is not consistent with the ‘swing voter’ hypothesis.

  18. Note that the elections of 1961 and 1964 were the last before the military junta (1967–1974). In the 1961 election, ERE was the first party (and formed a government), whereas in the 1964 election, EK was the first party (and formed a government). We select to relate the electoral vote share of ND’s wins in the Metapolitefsi period (1974 and 1977) to its ancestor’s last electoral win (ERE in 1961) and, similarly, to relate PASOK’s first electoral wins in the Metapolitefsi period (1981 and 1985) to its ancestor’s last electoral win (EK in 1964) for consistency. In Sect. 3.2.3, we perform a robustness check by calculating the average vote shares of the ancestors from both elections before the junta period.

  19. During that period, the Hellenic Federation of Enterprises (SEV) coined the term ‘social mania’, accusing Prime Minister Konstantinos Karamanlis of implementing a radical left-wing economic policy. For more details on this episode, refer to Vima (6 March 1976).

  20. Building on the seminal study by Altonji et al. (2005), Oster (2019) assessed how large the bias due to unobservables should be in comparison to that of observables, in order to explain away the estimated effect. The ratio between the two components of the bias is denoted as δ. This exercise returns a ratio that is (above 1 and) negative, which indicates a negative correlation between observables and unobservables and implies that the coefficient increases when controls are added to the model. The exercise also indicates that for the results to become economically insignificant, the selection of unobservable factors would have to dominate the selection of the included observables and work in the opposite direction.

  21. Given that the outcome is expressed in logged per capita Drachmas, the percentage change effect is calculated by eλ − 1, with λ being the estimated coefficient on the incumbent share4) multiplied by the standard deviation of the incumbent share.

  22. Notably, according to both definitions, the strongholds include prefectures in the top quartile of the distribution of electoral strength.

  23. The reduced-form estimates are not reported as they correspond to those already reported in column (2) of Table 2.

  24. Moreover, funding from IMPs is added to this category as it is titled devolved IMPs.

  25. We have fewer observations for investment flows by type because we could not track the regional fiscal account of 1979 in the Ministry of Economy and Development. Additionally, to prevent taking the logarithm of 0 for certain investment variables, we added the value of 1 before performing the logarithmic transformation.

  26. In a precise manner, these patron–client linkages form pyramids, with powerful MPs at the apex, local party bosses in the middle and individual voters at the base (see, e.g., Mavrogordatos, 1983a). Traditionally, these networks of local bosses and middlemen were personally affiliated with the powerful MPs, and it was common practice for them to be transmitted as inheritance—or even as dowry—within the same family from one generation to the next. In such a political context, it is evident that powerful MPs were the ultimate centres of political power, and consequently, political parties were structurally built around these networks of local notables (see Meynaud, 2002, for more details on this). The absence of effective party organisation and mass membership led to the party’s parliamentary group becoming extremely powerful; this situation is often described as vouleftokratia (‘rule of the MPs’) in the relevant literature.

  27. According to several scholars, observed electoral personalism can also be understood as stemming from a ‘political culture’—a set of attitudes and social values regarding power, law, family and the state—that traces its roots back to the era of Ottoman dominance and continues to influence political behaviour in contemporary Greece. Scholars such as Legg (1969), Campbell (1983) and Diamandouros (1983) have explored this aspect in detail. Based on this theoretical framework, efforts to introduce Western democratic institutions since 1864—such as extending the voting franchise to the entire male population—encountered challenges in a society where previous experiences had fostered deep suspicion of authority outside the family and a tendency to exploit authority for familial advantage. Thus, imported political institutions were often corrupted to serve traditional patron–client relationships (see, e.g., Diamandouros, 1983).

  28. Notably, our classification considers ministers and deputy ministers that have been elected in the prefecture and also plan to be candidates in the next election.

  29. It has been argued that since 1974, the pre-junta party system, which was based on traditional interpersonal patron–client relationships, has started to undergo transformation. The emergence of new parties during Metapolitefsi saw the development of stronger organisational structures, mass memberships and another type of clientelistic network described as bureaucratic clientelism or machine politics, rather than traditional patronage (see, e.g., Lyrintzis, 1984; Mavrogordatos, 1983b, 1997; Kammas et al., 2023). This transformation of the political system is a well-established fact. However, it is relevant to note that the interpersonal, clientelistic relationships of the past did not disappear entirely. On the contrary, during the early years of Metapolitefsi, newly established political parties sought to maintain the political networks of their pre-junta ancestors, which were structured around powerful MPs, while simultaneously developing strong organisational structures (see Kammas et al., 2023, for more details).

References

  • Alogoskoufis, G., (2019). Greece and the Euro: A Mundellian Tragedy. CGK Working Paper 2019–01.

  • Altonji, J., Elder, T., & Taber, R. (2005). Selection on observed and unobserved variables: Assessing the effectiveness of catholic schools. Journal of Political Economy, 113, 151–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ames, B. (1995). Electoral strategy under open-list proportional representation. American Journal of Political Science, 39(2), 406–433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anaxagorou, C., Efthyvoulou, G., & Sarantides, V. (2020). Electoral motives and the subnational allocation of foreign aid in sub-Saharan Africa. European Economic Review, 127, 103430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azar, P. (2022). Politics as a determinant of primary school provision: The case of Uruguay. Cliometrica, 16, 333–367.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bahar, D., Ibáñez, A. M., & Roso, S. (2021). Give me your tired and your poor: Impact of a large-scale amnesty program for undocumented refugees. Journal of Development Economics, 151, 102652.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banfield, E. C. (1958). The Moral Basis of a Backward Society. Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baskaran, T., & Hessami, Z. (2017). Political alignment and intergovernmental transfers in parliamentary systems: Evidence from Germany. Public Choice, 171, 75–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Batzilis, D. (2020). The political determinants of government spending allocation and growth. Research in Economics, 74, 213–220.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bom, P., & Ligthart, J. (2014). What have we learned from three decades of research on the productivity of public capital? Journal of Economic Surveys, 28(5), 889–916.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bracco, Ε, Lockwood, Β, Porcelli, F., & Redoano, M. (2015). Intergovernmental grants as signals and the alignment effect: Theory and evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 123, 78–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brender, A., & Drazen, A. (2007). Why is economic policy different in new democracies? Affecting attitudes. NBER Working Paper No. 13457.

  • Brender, A., & Drazen, A. (2005). Political budget cycles in new versus established democracies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1271–1295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brollo, F., & Nannicini, T. (2012). Tying your enemy’s hands in close races: The politics of federal transfers in Brazil. American Political Science Review, 106(4), 742–761.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cadot, O., Roller, L.-H., & Stephan, A. (2006). Contribution to productivity or pork-barrel? The two faces of infrastructure investment. Journal of Public Economics, 90(6–7), 1133–1153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cahan, D., Doerr, L., & Potrafke, N. (2019). Government ideology and monetary policy in OECD countries. Public Choice, 181, 215–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J. K. (1983). Traditional Values and Continuities in the Greek Society. In R. Clogg (Ed.), Greece in the 1980s. Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carey, J. M., & Shugart, M. S. (1995). Incentives to cultivate a personal vote: A rank ordering of electoral formulas. Electoral Studies, 14(4), 417–439.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carreri, M., & Martinez, L. R. (2021). Economic and Political Effects of Fiscal Rules: Evidence from a Natural Experiment in Colombia. Available at SSRN.

  • Carruthers, C., & Wanamaker, M. (2015). Municipal housekeeping: The impact of women’s suffrage on public education. Journal of Human Resources, 50(4), 837–872.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castells, A., & Solé-Ollé, A. (2005). The regional allocation of infrastructure investment: The role of equity, efficiency and political factors. European Economic Review, 49, 1165–1205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheibub, J. A., & Sin, G. (2020). Preference vote and intra-party competition in open list PR systems. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 32(1), 70–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chortareas, G., Logothetis, V., & Papandreou, A. (2016). Political budget cycles and reelection prospects in Greece’s municipalities. European Journal of Political Economy, 43(C), 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chortareas, G., Logothetis, V., & Papandreou, A. (2018). Elections and opportunistic budgetary policies in Greece. Managerial and Decision Economics, 39(8), 854–862.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clogg, R. (1987). Parties and elections in Greece: The search for legitimacy. Duke University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G., & McCubbins, M. (1986). Electoral politics as a redistributive game. Journal of Politics, 48(2), 370–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Curto-Grau, M., Herranz-Loncan, A., & Sole-Olle, A. (2012). Pork-barrel politics in semi-democracies: The Spanish parliamentary roads, 1880–1914. Journal of Economic History, 72(3), 771–796.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamandouros, N. (1983). Greek Political Culture in Transition: Historical Origins, Evolution Current Trends. In R. Clogg (Ed.), Greece in the 1980s. Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Doerr, L., Dorn, F., Gaebler, S., & Potrafke, N. (2020). How new airport infrastructure promotes tourism: Evidence from a synthetic control approach in German regions. Regional Studies, 54(10), 1402–1412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elephantis, A. (1981). PASOK and the Elections of 1977: The Rise of the Populist Movement. In H. Penniman (Ed.), Greece at the Polls: The National Elections of 1974 and 1977. American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Featherstone, K., & Katsoudas, D. (1985). Change and continuity in Greek voting behavior. European Journal of Political Research, 13, 27–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golden, M., & Picci, L. (2008). Pork barrel politics in postwar Italy, 1953–1994. American Journal of Political Science, 52(2), 268–289.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hlepas, N. K. (2003). Local Government Reform in Greece. In N. Kersting & A. Vetter (Eds.), Reforming Local Government in Europe. Closing the Gap between Democracy and Efficiency (pp. 221–239). Leske and Budrich.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Huntington, S. (1993). The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century. University of Oklahoma Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jablonski, R. (2014). How aid targets votes: The impact of electoral incentives on foreign aid distribution. World Politics, 66(2), 1–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joanis, M. (2011). The road to power: Partisan loyalty and the centralized provision of local infrastructure. Public Choice, 146(1–2), 117–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalyvas, S. (2010). Irregular Warfare and Electoral Behavior: The Civil War as a Crucial Determinant. In V. Gounaris, S. Kalyvas, & J. Stefanidis (Eds.), Irregular Warfares: Macedonia, Civil War, Cyprus. Patakis Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kammas, P., Poulima, M., & Sarantides, V. (2023). Fueling the party machine: Evidence from Greece during metapolitefsi. Explorations in Economic History, 90, 101538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kammas, P., & Sarantides, V. (2016). Fiscal redistribution around elections when democracy is not “the only game in town.” Public Choice, 168(3), 279–311.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kauder, B., Potrafke, N., & Reischmann, M. (2016). Do politicians reward core supporters? Evidence from a discretionary grant program. European Journal of Political Economy, 45, 39–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kazamias, A. (1978). The politics of educational reform in Greece: Law 309/1976. Comparative Education Review, 22(1), 21–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemmerling, A., & Stephan, A. (2015). Comparative political economy of regional transport infrastructure in Europe. Journal of Comparative Economics, 43(1), 227–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kitschelt, H. (2000). Linkages between citizens and politicians in democratic polities. Comparative Political Studies, 33(6–7), 845–879.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kitsos, A., & Proestakis, A. (2021). Mediating distributive politics: Political alignment and electoral business cycle effects on municipality financing in Greece. The Annals of Regional Science, 67, 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knight, B. (2004). Parochial interests and the centralized provision of local public goods: Evidence from congressional voting on transportation projects. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 845–866.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lambrinidis, M., Psycharis, Y., & Rovolis, A. (2005). Regional allocation of public infrastructure investment: The case of Greece. Regional Studies, 39(9), 1231–1244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Legg, K. (1969). Politics in Modern Greece. Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck, A., & Weibull, J. (1987). Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition. Public Choice, 52(3), 273–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood, B., Philippopoulos, A., & Tzavalis, E. (2001). Fiscal policy and politics: Theory and evidence from Greece 1960–1997. Economic Modelling, 18, 253–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luca, D. (2022). National elections, sub-national growth: The politics of Turkey’s provincial economic dynamics under AKP rule. Journal of Economic Geography, 22(4), 829–851.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luca, D., & Rodriguez-Pose, A. (2019). Building consensus: Shifting strategies in the territorial targeting of Turkey’s public transport investment. Regional Studies, 53(11), 1591–1602.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lyrintzis, C. (1984). Political parties in post-junta Greece: A case of “bureaucratic clientelism”? West European Politics, 7(2), 99–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matakos, K., & Xefteris, D. (2016). Citizens or clients? Evidence on opportunistic voting from a natural experiment in Greece. Political Science Research and Methods, 4(3), 493–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mavrogordatos, G. (1983a). Stillborn Republic: Social Coalitions and Party Strategies in Greece, 1922–1936. University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mavrogordatos, G. (1983b). The Rise of the Green Sun: The Greek Election of 1981. King’s College, Centre for Contemporary Greek Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mavrogordatos, G. (1984). The Greek party system: A case of limited but polarized pluralism? West European Politics, 7(4), 156–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mavrogordatos, G. (1997). From traditional clientelism to machine politics: The impact of PASOK populism in Greece. South European Society and Politics, 2(3), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McGillivray, F. (2004). Privileging Industry: The Comparative Politics of Trade and Industrial Policy. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Meghir, C., Pissarides, C., Vayanos, D., & Vettas, N. (2017). The Greek Economy Before and During the Crisis-and Policy Options Going Forward. In C. Meghir, C. A. Pissarides, D. Vayanos, & N. Vettas (Eds.), Beyond Austerity: Reforming the Greek Economy (pp. 3–72). MIT Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Meynaud, J. (2002). The Political Forces in Greece (1946–1965) (2nd ed.). Savvalas.

    Google Scholar 

  • Monastiriotis, V., & Psycharis, Y. (2011). Without purpose and strategy? A spatio-functional analysis of the regional allocation of public investment in Greece. GreeSE, 49. Hellenic Observatory, London, UK.

  • Nicolacopoulos, E. (2001). The Weak Democracy Parties and Elections, 1946–1967. Patakis Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nicolacopoulos, E. (2005). Elections and voters, 1974–2004: Old cleavages and new issues. West European Politics, 28(2), 260–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oster, E. (2019). Unobservable selection and coefficient stability: Theory and validation. Journal of Business Economics and Statistics, 37, 187–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Papadopoulos, Y. (1989). Parties, the state and society in Greece: Continuity within change. West European Politics, 12, 55–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pappas, T. (2009a). Patrons against partisans. The politics of patronage in mass ideological parties. Party Politics, 15(3), 315–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pappas, T. (2009b). The Charismatic Party. Patakis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Psycharis, Y. (2008). chapter 2, Public Spending Patterns: the Regional Allocation of Public Investment in Greece. In H. Coccossis & Y. Psycharis (Eds.), Regional Analysis and Policy the Greek Experience (pp. 41–72). Physica-Verlag.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Psycharis, Y., Rodríguez-Pose, A., & Tselios, V. (2021). Ministers and distributive politics: Political influences in the regional allocation of public investment in Greece. Territory, Politics, Governance, 9(2), 276–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. D. (1993). Making Democracy Work Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodriguez-Pose, A., Psycharis, Y., & Tselios, V. (2012). Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece. Papers in Regional Science, 91(3), 543–568.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodriguez-Pose, A., Psycharis, Y., & Tselios, V. (2016a). Politics and investment: Examining the territorial allocation of public investment in Greece. Regional Studies, 50(7), 1097–1112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodriguez-Pose, A., Psycharis, Y., & Tselios, V. (2016b). Liberals, Socialists, and pork-barrel politics in Greece. Environment and Planning a: Economy and Space, 48(8), 1473–1492.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solé-Ollé, A. (2013). Inter-regional redistribution through infrastructure investment: Tactical or programmatic? Public Choice, 156(1–2), 229–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spenkuch, J., & Tillmann, P. (2018). Elite influence? Religion and the electoral success of the Nazis. American Journal of Political Science, 62(1), 19–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tatsos, N. (1998). The size of local government units, local government papers, Vol. 1, National Association of Municipalities (KEDKE), Athens, pp. 104–120.

  • Torregrosa-Hetaland, S. (2015). Did democracy bring redistribution? Insights from the Spanish tax system, 1960–90. European Review of Economic History, 19, 294–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tribin, A. (2020). Chasing votes with the public budget. European Journal of Political Economy, 63, 101875.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tziovaras, G., & Chiotis, V. (2006). The political atlas of post-dictatorial Greece 1974–2006. Livanis Publishers. (in Greek).

    Google Scholar 

  • Verney, S. (1990). Between coalition and one-party government: The Greek elections of November 1989 and April 1990. West European Politics, 13(4), 131–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors wish to thank the Co-Editor Nadine Riedel, two anonymous referees, Antonis Adam, Nikos Benos, Anastasia Litina, Franciscos Koutentakis, Panagiotis Konstantinou, Harry Pickard, Thanasis Stavrakoudis, Spyros Symeonides, Nikos Tsakiris and Dimitris Xefteris for thorough and constructive comments. This work has also benefited from comments received by conference participants at the 8th International Ioannina Meeting on Applied Economics and Finance (IMAEF) and the 19th Conference on Research on Economic Theory and Econometrics (CRETE). Any remaining errors are ours.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

All authors have contributed to data collection and digitalization, development of the conceptual framework, empirical analysis, and writing of the research article.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Vassilis Sarantides.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file 1 (PDF 626 kb)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kammas, P., Poulima, M. & Sarantides, V. Investing in the roots of your political ancestors. Int Tax Public Finance (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-024-09840-1

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-024-09840-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation