Skip to main content
Log in

Tax haven, pollution haven or both?

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies the interplay between two groups of countries, large and small, which compete sequentially on corporate taxes and environmental regulations to attract imperfectly mobile firms. We show that in general, the small countries undercut the large countries in terms of corporate taxes. The small countries choose to be both tax and pollution havens when they are less concerned about the environment than the large countries are and capital integration is low. The large countries never act as both tax havens and pollution havens. Finally, we find that higher firm mobility narrows the tax gap between the large and the small countries but does not affect the optimal environmental policy: tax competition immunizes countries against the detrimental effect of globalization on emission caps.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availibility

The data that illustrate the findings of this study and that are presented in the conclusion are available from the corresponding author upon request.

Notes

  1. There is ample evidence of cross-border pollution between US states (see Millimet (2013) for a comprehensive survey). Transboundary pollution is also well documented in Asia: Japan and South Korea regularly complain that the acid rain they suffer is caused by emissions of sulfur and nitrogen oxides from coal-burning plants in northern China (Abu Sayed, “Cross-border pollution: A growing international problem. The Daily Star, February 19, 2011.). Transboundary air pollution also occurs between European Union member states despite the emission reduction measures adopted under the Convention on Long-Range Transboundary Air Pollution (CLRTAP) and EU legislation (European Environment Agency, 2020).

  2. As in Pieretti and Zanaj (2011), Mongrain and Wilson (2018), and Niu (2019), size is represented by the number of firms initially located in each country.

  3. Countries are often involved in cooperative agreements on environmental issues since pollution is a global phenomenon (e.g., the Convention on Long-Range Transboundary Air Pollution and the Kyoto Protocol). However, signatories have a certain level of discretion and strategic room for maneuver in defining their environmental policies with respect to other groups of countries (see the empirical evidence mentioned above).

  4. One way to interpret this asymmetric initial endowment of firms is to consider that the large countries are initially more industrialized than the small countries are.

  5. An example of this type of environmental regulation is the EU ETS. This is a "cap and trade" scheme in the European Union where the right to emit specified pollutants in a geographic area is capped. Firms are then allowed to trade emission rights within that area to comply with the cap.

  6. See Stavins et al. (2014) for more details about environmental agreements.

  7. The same approach has been used by Arguedas (2008) and in a different setting by Lombardini-Riipinen (2005).

  8. Incineration plants for waste disposal are a representative example of end-of-pipe technologies. In contrast, cleaner approaches such as using environmentally friendly materials (Frondel et al. 2007; Mantovani et al. 2017) reduce the environmental impact of production by fully or partially replacing polluting technologies.

  9. Firms are perfectly mobile when they stay within the same group of countries but relocating from an i-type country to a j-type country costs them k.

  10. This is the standard arbitrage condition in tax competition models that ensures the net return of capital is equal in all jurisdictions: \(\rho _{i}=f(k_{i})-t_{i}=\rho \;\forall i\)

  11. Note that x, which represents a neutral attitude to staying put and relocating, also corresponds to the proportion of firms willing to relocate abroad.

  12. This payoff function is similar to Conrad (2005). In contrast with Conrad, we assume absentee non-resident ownership of firms.

  13. Introducing the disutility of pollution as a convex function of the pollution level in the payoff function is in line with the standard literature on environmental economics. See for instance Baksi (2014); Bárcena-Ruiz (2006); Ulph (1996) and Falk and Mendelsohn (1993) for quadratic functions.

  14. Policy-makers’ concerns about pollution may be driven by pure or impure altruism. The environment can be considered a public good to be protected (Andreoni 1990). Alternatively, emissions reduction can be seen as a reputational driver (Benabou and Tirole 2006) or be motivated by moral concerns (Frey 1999).

  15. Most papers in the theoretical and the empirical literature show that taxes are strategic complements. For a recent survey on whether taxes are strategic complements or strategic substitutes, see, for instance, Vrijburg and de Mooij (2016).

  16. Since within each group, the countries are symmetric and emission caps are harmonized, \(G_{i}\) represents the payoff of a representative country in group i.

  17. This happens when mobility costs are neither too low nor too high: \(\tilde{ k }<k<{\check{k}}\).

  18. In the standard model of tax competition in contrast, any increase in the number of competing jurisdictions reduces the stock of capital per jurisdiction as the aggregated stock of capital is fixed.

  19. Note that increasing the number of countries unsurprisingly makes tax competition fiercer, just as in the standard model of tax competition, but the mechanism at work is different.

  20. Note that \(\frac{\partial (t_{L}^{*}-t_{S}^{*})}{\partial \gamma _{i}}=\frac{6}{5}\frac{\partial (\alpha _{L}^{*}-\alpha _{S}^{*})}{\partial \gamma _{i}}\), \(\frac{\partial (t_{L}^{*}-t_{S}^{*})}{\partial \phi _{i}}=-\frac{1}{6}\frac{\partial (\alpha _{L}^{*}-\alpha _{S}^{*})}{\partial \phi _{i}}\)

  21. Calculations available from authors on request.

  22. The fact that the timing of the final game does not matter much in our model is in line with Yamagishi (2019)’s findings in a different standard model of tax competition than ours. Yamagishi (2019) investigates the optimality of the tax competition equilibrium with respect to a centralized solution. He shows that the capital taxes and environmental regulation chosen at the equilibrium are comparable in terms of efficiency (compared to a centralized solution) whatever the timing of the game.

  23. The threshold mobility cost for tax equality is zero: \({\tilde{k}}=0\) (see Appendix 8.4).

  24. Remember that we have set \(\mu =1\).

  25. The same can be done for OECD and non-OECD countries.

References

  • Abe, K., & Zhao, L. (2005). Endogenous international joint ventures and the environment. Journal of International Economics, 67(1), 221–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm-glow giving. The Economic Journal, 100(401), 464–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arguedas, C. (2008). To comply or not to comply? pollution standard setting under costly monitoring and sanctionin. Environmental and Resource Economicsl, 41(2), 155–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arguedas, C., & Rousseau, S. (2012). Learning about compliance under asymmetric information. Resource and energy economics, 34(1), 55–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asen, E. (2019). Corporate tax rates around the world, 2019. Fiscal Fact.

  • Baksi, S. (2014). Regional versus multilateral trade liberalization, environmental taxation, and welfare. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne d’économique, 47(1), 232–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. E., & Krugman, P. (2004). Agglomeration, integration and tax harmonisation. European Economic Review, 48(1), 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz, J. C. (2006). Environmental taxes and first-mover advantages. Environmental and Resource Economics, 35(1), 19–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benabou, R., & Tirole, J. (2006). Belief in a just world and redistributive politics. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(2), 699–746.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bénassy-Quéré, A., Gobalraja, N., & Trannoy, A. (2007). Tax and public input competition. Economic Policy, 22(50), 386–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Böhringer, C., Fischer, C., & Rosendahl, K. E. (2014). Cost-effective unilateral climate policy design: Size matters. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 67(3), 318–339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bucovetsky, S. (1991). Asymmetric tax competition. Journal of Urban Economics, 30(2), 167–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cai, H., & Treisman, D. (2005). Does competition for capital discipline governments? decentralization, globalization, and public policy. American Economic Review, 95(3), 817–830.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, X., Huang, B., & Lin, C.-T. (2019). Environmental awareness and environmental kuznets curve. Economic Modelling, 77, 2–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crivelli, E., De Mooij, R. A., & Keen, M. M. (2016). Base erosion, profit shifting and developing countries. FinanzArchiv/Public Finance Analysis, 268–301.

  • Davies, R. B., & Naughton, H. T. (2014). Cooperation in environmental policy: A spatial approach. International Tax and Public Finance, 21(5), 923–954.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Mooij, R. A., Ederveen, S., et al. (2006). What a difference does it make? understanding the empirical literature on taxation and international capital flows. Directorate General Economic and Financial Affairs (DG ECFIN), European Commission: Technical report.

    Google Scholar 

  • Devereux, M. P., Lockwood, B., & Redoano, M. (2008). Do countries compete over corporate tax rates? Journal of Public Economics, 92(5–6), 1210–1235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dou, J., & Han, X. (2019). How does the industry mobility affect pollution industry transfer in China: Empirical test on pollution haven hypothesis and porter hypothesis. Journal of Cleaner Production, 217, 105–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichner, T., & Pethig, R. (2018). Competition in emissions standards and capital taxes with local pollution. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 68, 191–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichner, T., & Pethig, R. (2019). Strategic pollution control and capital tax competition. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 94, 27–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Exbrayat, N., & Geys, B. (2014). Trade integration and corporate income tax differentials. International Tax and Public Finance, 21(2), 298–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk, I., & Mendelsohn, R. (1993). The economics of controlling stock pollutants: An efficient strategy for greenhouse gases. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 25(1), 76–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L. P., & Heckemeyer, J. H. (2011). Fdi and taxation: A meta-study. Journal of Economic Surveys, 25(2), 233–272.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson, P. G., List, J. A., & Millimet, D. L. (2004). Chasing the smokestack: Strategic policymaking with multiple instruments. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 34(4), 387–410.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S. (1999). Morality and rationality in environmental policy. Journal of Consumer Policy, 22(4), 395–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frondel, M., Horbach, J., & Rennings, K. (2007). End-of-pipe or cleaner production? An empirical comparison of environmental innovation decisions across Oecd countries. Business Strategy and the Environment, 16(8), 571–584.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haufler, A., & Wooton, I. (2010). Competition for firms in an oligopolistic industry: The impact of economic integration. Journal of International Economics, 80(2), 239–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ikefuji, M., Itaya, J.-I., & Okamura, M. (2016). Optimal emission tax with endogenous location choice of duopolistic firms. Environmental and Resource Economics, 65(2), 463–485.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Justman, M., Thisse, J.-F., & Van Ypersele, T. (2005). Fiscal competition and regional differentiation. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 35(6), 848–861.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kayalica, M. Ö., & Lahiri, S. (2005). Strategic environmental policies in the presence of foreign direct investment. Environmental and Resource Economics, 30(1), 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keen, M. & Konrad, K. A. (2013). The theory of international tax competition and coordination. In Handbook of Public Economics, volume 5, pages 257–328. Elsevier.

  • Kellenberg, D. K. (2009). An empirical investigation of the pollution haven effect with strategic environment and trade policy. Journal of International Economics, 78(2), 242–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kheder, S. B., & Zugravu, N. (2012). Environmental regulation and french firms location abroad: An economic geography model in an international comparative study. Ecological Economics, 77, 48–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kirkpatrick, C., & Shimamoto, K. (2008). The effect of environmental regulation on the locational choice of Japanese foreign direct investment. Applied Economics, 40(11), 1399–1409.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koźluk, T. & Timiliotis, C. (2016). Do environmental policies affect global value chains? OECD Working Paper.

  • Lombardini-Riipinen, C. (2005). Optimal tax policy under environmental quality competition. Environmental and Resource Economics, 32(3), 317–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mantovani, A., Tarola, O., & Vergari, C. (2017). End-of-pipe or cleaner production? how to go green in presence of income inequality and pro-environmental behavior. Journal of Cleaner Production, 160, 71–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markusen, J. R., Morey, E. R., & Olewiler, N. D. (1993). Environmental policy when market structure and plant locations are endogenous. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 24(1), 69–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Millimet, D. L. (2013). Environmental federalism: a survey of the empirical literature. Case Western Reserve Law Review, 64, 1669.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mongrain, S., & Wilson, J. D. (2018). Tax competition with heterogeneous capital mobility. Journal of Public Economics, 167, 177–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Motta, M., & Thisse, J.-F. (1994). Does environmental dumping lead to delocation? European Economic Review, 38(3–4), 563–576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naegele, H., & Zaklan, A. (2019). Does the EU ETS cause carbon leakage in European manufacturing? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 93, 125–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niu, B. J. (2019). Equilibria and location choice in corporate tax regimes. Public Finance Review, 47(2), 433–458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. E., & Schwab, R. M. (1988). Economic competition among jurisdictions: Efficiency enhancing or distortion inducing? Journal of Public Economics, 35(3), 333–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ogawa, H., & Wildasin, D. E. (2009). Think locally, act locally: Spillovers, spillbacks, and efficient decentralized policymaking. American Economic Review, 99(4), 1206–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Overesch, M., & Rincke, J. (2011). What drives corporate tax rates down? A reassessment of globalization, tax competition, and dynamic adjustment to shocks. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 113(3), 579–602.

    Google Scholar 

  • Petrakis, E., & Xepapadeas, A. (2003). Location decisions of a polluting firm and the time consistency of environmental policy. Resource and Energy Economics, 25(2), 197–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pieretti, P., & Zanaj, S. (2011). On tax competition, public goods provision and jurisdictions’ size. Journal of International Economics, 84(1), 124–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Redoano, M. (2014). Tax competition among European countries. does the EU matter? European Journal of Political Economy, 34, 353–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanna-Randaccio, F., & Sestini, R. (2012). The impact of unilateral climate policy with endogenous plant location and market size asymmetry. Review of International Economics, 20(3), 580–599.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanna-Randaccio, F., Sestini, R., & Tarola, O. (2017). Unilateral climate policy and foreign direct investment with firm and country heterogeneity. Environmental and Resource Economics, 67(2), 379–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sarkodie, S. A., & Strezov, V. (2019). A review on environmental kuznets curve hypothesis using bibliometric and meta-analysis. Science of the Total Environment, 649, 128–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shahbaz, M., Nasreen, S., Abbas, F., & Anis, O. (2015). Does foreign direct investment impede environmental quality in high-, middle-, and low-income countries? Energy Economics, 51, 275–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stavins, R., Zou, J., Brewer, T., Conte Grand, M., den Elzen, M., Finus, M., et al. (2014). International cooperation: Agreements and instruments. Climate change, 7(5), 1001–1082.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ulph, A. (1996). Environmental policy and international trade when governments and producers act strategically. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 30(3), 265–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ulph, A., & Valentini, L. (2001). Is environmental dumping greater when plants are footloose? Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 103(4), 673–688.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Unteroberdoerster, O. (2001). Trade and transboundary pollution: Spatial separation reconsidered. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 41(3), 269–285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vrijburg, H., & de Mooij, R. A. (2016). Tax rates as strategic substitutes. International Tax and Public Finance, 23(1), 2–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J. D. (1991). Tax competition with interregional differences in factor endowments. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 21(3), 423–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yamagishi, A. (2019). Transboundary pollution, tax competition and the efficiency of uncoordinated environmental regulation. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue Canadienne d’économique, 52(3), 1165–1194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yuan, F., Wei, Y. D., Gao, J., & Chen, W. (2019). Water crisis, environmental regulations and location dynamics of pollution-intensive industries in China: A study of the taihu lake watershed. Journal of Cleaner Production, 216, 311–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to the editor and two anonymous referees for their helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Emmanuelle Taugourdeau.

Ethics declarations

Conflicts of interest

No conflict of interest to disclose. The views and opinions expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the authors’ institutions.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Number of firms in each country

The number of firms in country m of group i can be described as follows, in terms of the flow of firms between the two groups of countries and the taxes within each group:

$$\begin{aligned} \text {Number of firms in }m_{i}=\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} \left. \begin{array}{ll} s_{i}(1-x_{m_{i}})\; &{} if\;x_{m_{i}}>0\ \\ &{} \\ s_{i}\left( 1-\frac{\sum ^{N_{j}}x_{m_{j}}}{N_{j}}\right) \; &{} if\;x_{m_{j}}>0 \\ &{} \end{array} \right\} \; if \; t_{m_{i}}=t_{m_{i}^{\prime }} &{} \\ &{} \\ \left. \begin{array}{ll} N_{i}s_{i}\; &{} if\;x_{m_{i}}>0 \\ &{} \\ s_{i}\left( 1-\sum ^{N_{j}}x_{m_{j}}\right) \; &{} if\;x_{m_{j}}>0 \\ &{} \end{array} \right\} \; if \; t_{m_{i}}<t_{m_{i}^{\prime }}\;\forall \;m^{\prime }i &{} \\ &{} \\ \left. \begin{array}{ll} 0 \; &{} \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \forall x_{m_i}, x_{m_j} \end{array} \right. \quad \quad if\;t_{m_{i}}>t_{m_{i}^{\prime }}&\end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(20)

Note that if \(x_{m_{i}}>0\) then \(x_{m_{j}}=0\) and conversely.

1.2 Tax competition subgame

Maximizing \(G_{L}(\alpha _{L},t_{L},\alpha _{S},t_{S})\) and \(G_{S}(\alpha _{L},t_{L},\alpha _{S},t_{S})\) w.r.t \(t_{L}\) and \(t_{S}\) in the tax competition subgame yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dG_{i}}{dt_{i}}=\frac{dR_{i}}{dt_{i}}-\frac{de_{i}}{dt_{i}}=0, \; i=S,L \end{aligned}$$

with

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dR_{L}}{dt_{L}}= & {} \frac{N_Ls_{L}-N_is_i x}{N_L}- \frac{s_iN_i}{kN_{L}} t_{L}=\overbrace{s_L}^{\text {tax level effect}}-\overbrace{\frac{s_{i}N_{i}}{ N_L}\left( x+\frac{t_{L}}{k}\right) }^{\text {tax base effect}} \\ \frac{dR_{S}}{dt_{S}}= & {} \frac{N_Ss_{S}+N_is_i x}{N_S}-\left( \frac{ s_{i}N_{i}}{kN_{S}}\right) t_{S} =s_S+\frac{s_{i}N_{i}}{N_S}\left( x- \frac{ t_{S}}{k}\right) \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{de_{L}}{dt_{L}}= & {} \frac{q}{2k}\frac{s_iN_i}{ N_{L}} (N_L\alpha _S^2\phi _L-\alpha _L^2(\gamma _L+(N_L-1)\phi _L)) \\ \frac{de_{S}}{dt_{S}}= & {} \frac{q}{2k}\frac{s_iN_i}{ N_{S}} (N_S\alpha _L^2\phi _S-\alpha _S^2(\gamma _S+(N_S-1)\phi _S)) \end{aligned}$$

for \(i=L\) when \(x>0\), and \(i=S\) when \(x<0\).

The tax reaction functions are given by:

For \(i=L\) when \(x>0\) and \(i=S\) for \(x<0\):

$$\begin{aligned} t_L(t_S)= \frac{1}{4}\left( \frac{2 k N_L s_L}{N_i s_i}+q(\alpha _L^2 N_L \phi _L-\alpha _S^2 N_L \phi _L+\alpha _L^2 \gamma _L -\alpha _L^2 \phi _L+2 \alpha _L -2 \alpha _S) +2 t_S\right) \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} t_S(t_L)=\frac{1}{4}\left( \frac{2 k N_S s_S}{ N_i s_i} +q(- \alpha _S^2 N_S \phi _S+\alpha _S^2 N_S \phi _S+\alpha _S^2 \gamma _S -\alpha _S^2 \phi _S-2 \alpha _L +2 \alpha _S) +2 t_L\right) \end{aligned}$$

then the slope of the two tax reaction functions is \(\frac{1}{2}\).

1.3 Emission caps

Substituting \(t_{1}^{*}(\alpha _{1},\alpha _{2})\) and \(t_{2}^{*}(\alpha _{1},\alpha _{2})\) into the payoff functions \(G_{1}\) and \(G_{2}\) gives

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dG_{i}}{d\alpha _{i}}=\frac{\partial G_{i}}{\partial \alpha _{i}}+ \overbrace{\frac{\partial G_{i}}{\partial t_{i}^{*}(\alpha _{1},\alpha _{2})}}^{=0}\frac{\partial t_{i}^{*}(\alpha _{1},\alpha _{2})}{\partial \alpha _{i}}+\frac{\partial G_{i}}{\partial t_{j}^{*}(\alpha _{1},\alpha _{2})}\frac{\partial t_{j}^{*}(\alpha _{1},\alpha _{2})}{\partial \alpha _{i}}=0 \end{aligned}$$

Let us set \(\Gamma _i=(\phi _i+N_j\gamma _j+(N_i-1)\phi _i)\). The previous equation reduces to:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d G_{i}}{d \alpha _{i}}= & {} \frac{q(\alpha _i \Gamma _i-1) \left( qN_L s_L \left( 2(\alpha _j-\alpha _i)+\alpha _i^2 \Gamma _i-\alpha _j^2\Gamma _j\right) -2 k(2 N_i s_i+N_j s_j)\right) }{9 k N_i} \\= & {} \frac{q(\alpha _i \Gamma _i-1) \left( qN_L s_L \Gamma _i \alpha _i^2-2q N_L s_L \alpha _i+qN_Ls_L \alpha _j \left( 2-\alpha _j\Gamma _j\right) -2 k(2 N_i s_i+N_j s_j)\right) }{9 k N_i}=0 \end{aligned}$$

with three solutions:

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _{i1}= & {} \frac{1}{\Gamma _i}=\frac{-b}{2a} \quad with \quad \overline{ \alpha } _i>\alpha _{i1}>{\underline{\alpha }}_i \\ \alpha _{i2}= & {} \frac{-b+\sqrt{\Delta }}{2a}>{\overline{\alpha }}_i \\ \alpha _{i3}= & {} \frac{-b-\sqrt{\Delta }}{2a}>{\overline{\alpha }}_i \end{aligned}$$

with

$$\begin{aligned} a= & {} qN_L s_L \Gamma _i>0 \\ b= & {} -2q N_L s_L<0 \\ c= & {} qN_L s_L\alpha _j(2-\alpha _j \Gamma _j)-2k(N_js_j+2N_is_i) \\ \Delta= & {} b^2-4ac \end{aligned}$$

The second-order condition (i.e maximum) leads to:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d^2G_{i}}{d\alpha _{i}^2}=\frac{q}{9kN_i}\left( a^{\prime } \alpha _i^2-b^{\prime }\alpha _i+c^{\prime }\right) \\ \end{aligned}$$

with

$$\begin{aligned} a^{\prime }= & {} 3q N_L s_L \Gamma _i^2=3 a \Gamma _i>0 \\ b^{\prime }= & {} -6 q N_L s_L \Gamma _i= 3 b \Gamma _i<0 \\ c^{\prime }= & {} qN_L s_L\alpha _j(2-\alpha _j \Gamma _j)\Gamma _i-2k(N_js_j+2N_is_i)\Gamma _i+2qN_Ls_L=c \Gamma _i+2qN_L s_L \\ \end{aligned}$$

which has two solutions for \(\frac{d^2G_{i}}{d\alpha _{i}^2}=0\)

$$\begin{aligned} {\overline{\alpha }}_i= & {} \frac{-b^{\prime }+\sqrt{\Delta ^{\prime }}}{2a^{\prime }} \\ {\underline{\alpha }}_i= & {} \frac{-b^{\prime }-\sqrt{\Delta ^{\prime }}}{2a^{\prime }} \end{aligned}$$

with \(\Delta ^{\prime }=b^2-4a^{\prime }c^{\prime }\).

We can verify that \(\Delta ^{\prime }>0\;\iff \;c^{\prime }<\frac{b^{\prime }{}^2}{4a^{\prime }}=qN_Ls_L\) which reduces to:

\(k>\frac{q N_Ls_L}{2(2N_is_i+N_js_j)}\frac{\alpha _j(2-\alpha _j\Gamma _j) \Gamma _i-1}{\Gamma _i}\).

We can immediately deduce from () that \(\frac{-b^{\prime }}{ 2a^{\prime }}=\frac{-b}{2a}\) while \(\Delta ^{\prime }<9\Gamma _i \Delta\). Then \(\frac{\sqrt{\Delta ^{\prime }}}{2a^{\prime }}<\frac{\sqrt{\Delta }}{2a}\) and \(\alpha _{i2}>{\overline{\alpha }}_i\) and \(\alpha _{i3}<{\underline{\alpha }}_i\). Since \(a^{\prime }>0\), we know that \(\frac{d^2G_{i}}{d\alpha _{i}^2}<0\) for any \(\alpha _i \in [ {\underline{\alpha }}_i,{\overline{\alpha }}_i]\), which is not the case of \(\alpha _{i2}\) and \(\alpha _{i3}\).

Then the concavity condition excludes solutions 2 and 3, which are minima, and solution \(\alpha _{i1}\) is the only maximum: \(\alpha _i=\frac{1}{ \Gamma _i}\) for \(k>\dfrac{qN_Ls_L(\Gamma _i-\Gamma _j)}{ 2\Gamma _i \Gamma _j(2N_is_i+N_js_j) }\) which is the concavity condition at the equilibrium.

1.4 Equilibrium configurations

Table 1 Sets of equilibria depending on the level of capital integration and the ranking of pollution concern gaps for \(k>k_{Max}\) and \(k>k_{Min}\) with \(\Delta _{i}=\gamma _{i}-\phi _{i}\)

Let us recall the values of \(k_{Max}\) and \(k_{Min}\), with: \(k_{Max}\equiv \frac{qN_{S}s_{S}(\Delta _{S}-\Delta _{L})}{2\Gamma _{S}\Gamma _{L}(2N_{L}s_{L}+4N_{S}s_{S})}\)

\(k_{Min}\equiv \frac{qN_{L}s_{L}(\Delta _{L}-\Delta _{S})}{2\Gamma _{S}\Gamma _{L}(2N_{S}s_{S}+4N_{L}s_{L})}\).

The values of the threshold mobility costs are:

For \(i=L\) when \(x>0\) and \(i=S\) when \(x<0\):

\({\tilde{k}}\equiv \frac{5qN_is_i(\Delta _L-\Delta _S)}{2 \Gamma _L \Gamma _S \left( N_Ls_L-N_Ss_S\right) }\), and \(t_{1}^{*}-t_{2}^{*}>0 \iff k> {\tilde{k}}\).

\({\bar{k}}\equiv \frac{qs_{i}N_i (\Delta _S-\Delta _L)}{2 \Gamma _L \Gamma _S \left( N_Ls_L-N_Ss_S\right) }\), and \(x^{*}>0\iff k>{\bar{k}}\) when \(i=L\) and \(x^{*}<0\iff k<{\bar{k}}\) when \(i=S\)

\({\hat{k}}=\frac{qN_is_{i}(\Delta _L-\Delta _{S})}{ \Gamma _L \Gamma _S(N_Ls_L-N_Ss_S)}\) and \(N_L\times n_{L}^{*}>N_S \times n_{S}^{*}\iff k>{\hat{k}}\).

Recall that \(n_L\) is the number of firms in each large country, i.e. \(n_L=s_L(1-x)\) when \(x>0\) and \(n_L=s_L-xs_S\frac{N_S}{N_L}\) when \(x<0\),

and \(n_S\) is the number of firms in each small country, i.e. \(n_S=s_S+s_L x \frac{N_L}{N_S}\) when \(x>0\) and \(n_S=s_S(1+ x)\) when \(x<0\).

Finally, to compare the total payoffs, we determine \(N_{L}^{*}G_{L}^{*}-N_{S}^{*}G_{S}^{*}\):

$$\begin{aligned}&N_{L}^{*}G_{L}^{*}-N_{S}^{*}G_{S}^{*}=\frac{ (N_{L}s_{L}+N_{S}s_{S})}{6\Gamma _{L}^{2}\Gamma _{S}^{2}N_{i}s_{i}}\times \nonumber \\&\left( 2k\Gamma _{L}^{2}\Gamma _{S}^{2}(N_{L}s_{L}-N_{S}s_{S})-3qN_{L}s_{L}(\Gamma _{L}^{2}N_{L}\phi _{L}-\Gamma _{S}^{2}N_{S}\phi _{S})\right) -2qN_{L}s_{L}\Gamma _{S}\Gamma _{L}(\Gamma _{L}-\Gamma _{S}) \end{aligned}$$
(21)

It holds that:

\({\check{k}}\equiv \frac{qN_is_{i}}{N_Ls_L-N_Ss_S}\left( \frac{ \Delta _L-\Delta _S}{\Gamma _L\Gamma _S}-\frac{3(N_L\phi _L\Gamma _L^2-N_S\phi _S \Gamma _S^2)}{ 2\Gamma _L^2\Gamma _S^2}\right)\) and \(N_LG_{L}^{*}-N_SG_{S}^{*}>0\Longleftrightarrow k>{\check{k}}\).

Note that:

\({\tilde{k}}>0\Leftrightarrow \Delta _L>\Delta _S\).

\({\bar{k}}>0\Leftrightarrow \Delta _L>\Delta _S\)

\({\hat{k}}>0\Leftrightarrow \Delta _L<\Delta _S\)

The sign of \({\check{k}}\) is much more complicated to determine and depends on the ranking of \(\Gamma _L\) \(\Gamma _S\), \(\Delta _L\), \(\Delta _S\) and on the ranking of \(\phi _S\) and \(\phi _S\)

Let us rank the threshold values \({\hat{k}},{\check{k}}\) and \({\tilde{k}}\), when positive:

$$\begin{aligned} {\tilde{k}}-{\check{k}}\equiv & {} \frac{3qN_is_{i}}{2} \frac{\Gamma _L\Gamma _S( \Gamma _L-\Gamma _S)+(N_L \Gamma _L^2 \phi _L-N_S \Gamma _S^2 \phi _S)}{ \Gamma _L^2\Gamma _S^2(N_Ls_L-N_Ss_S) }> 0 \\\Leftrightarrow & {} N_S \Gamma _S^2 \phi _S+\Gamma _S^2\Gamma _L<N_L \Gamma _L^2 \phi _L+\Gamma _S\Gamma _L^2 \\\Leftrightarrow & {} N_S \Gamma _S^2 \phi _S-N_L \Gamma _L^2 \phi _L<\Gamma _L\Gamma _S (\Delta _L-\Delta _S) \\&\\ {\hat{k}}-{\check{k}}\equiv & {} \frac{3}{2}s_{i}N_i q\frac{N_S \Gamma _S^2 \phi _S-N_L \Gamma _L^2 \phi _L}{\Gamma _L^2\Gamma _S^2(N_Ls_L-N_Ss_S) } \gtreqqless 0\Leftrightarrow N_S \Gamma _S^2 \phi _S>N_L \Gamma _L^2 \phi _L \\&\\ {\tilde{k}}-{\hat{k}}= & {} 3qs_{i}N_i\frac{(\Gamma _{L}-\Gamma _{S})}{2 \Gamma _L \Gamma _S\left( N_L s_{L}-N_S s_S\right) }\gtreqqless 0\Leftrightarrow \Delta _{S}\lesseqqgtr \Delta _{L} \\&\\ {\bar{k}}-{\check{k}}\equiv & {} -\frac{3}{2}s_{i}N_i q\frac{N_S \Gamma _S^2 \phi _S-N_L \Gamma _L^2 \phi _L}{\Gamma _L^2\Gamma _S^2(N_Ls_L-N_Ss_S) } \gtreqqless 0\Leftrightarrow N_S \Gamma _S^2 \phi _S<N_L \Gamma _L^2 \phi _L \\ \end{aligned}$$

So whenever

(i) \(\Delta _S>\Delta _L\), it follows \({\bar{k}}>0\), \({\hat{k}}<0\) and \({\tilde{k}} <0\)

(ii) \(\Delta _L>\Delta _S\), it holds that \({\tilde{k}}>{\hat{k}}>0\) and \({\bar{k}} <0.\)

Moreover, we know that \(k_{Max }<0\) for \(\Delta _L>\Delta _S\) and \(k_{Min}<0\) for \(\Delta _S>\Delta _L\). Let us check the ranking of \(k_{Max }\) and \({\bar{k}}\) when \(\Delta _S>\Delta _L\) and the ranking of \(k_{Min}\) and \({\hat{k}}\) when \(\Delta _L>\Delta _S\):

  • Let us compare \({\bar{k}}\) and \(k_{Max}\):

    $$\begin{aligned} {\bar{k}}-k_{Max }=\frac{q(N_Ss_S+N_Ls_L)(N_Ss_S+2N_Ls_L)}{ 4(2N_Ss_S+N_Ls_L)(N_Ls_L-N_Ss_S)}\frac{ (\Delta _S-\Delta _L)}{\Gamma _L \Gamma _S} \end{aligned}$$

    Then \({\bar{k}}>k_{Max}\) when \(\Delta _S>\Delta _L\).

  • Now let us compare \({\hat{k}}\) and \(k_{Min}\) when \(\Delta _L>\Delta _S\), which implies \(x<0\):

    $$\begin{aligned} {\hat{k}}-k_{Min}=\frac{q(3N_Ss_S+N_Ls_L)3N_Ls_L}{ 4(2N_Ss_S+N_Ls_L)(N_Ls_L-N_Ss_S)}\frac{ (\Delta _L-\Delta _S)}{\Gamma _L \Gamma _S} \end{aligned}$$

    Then \({\hat{k}}>k_{Min}\) when \(\Delta _L>\Delta _S\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Madiès, T., Tarola, O. & Taugourdeau, E. Tax haven, pollution haven or both?. Int Tax Public Finance 29, 1527–1560 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-022-09745-x

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-022-09745-x

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation