Skip to main content
Log in

Decentralization with porous borders: public production in a federation with tax competition and spillovers

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We analyze the strategic interaction of regional and federal governments using a model that includes fiscal externalities in the form of inter-regional capital tax competition and technical externalities in the form of inter-regional spillovers. The federal government aims to correct for these inefficiencies using a transfer system. If the regional governments are policy leaders (such that federal policy is set conditional on regional choices), they will internalize both fiscal and technical externalities but free-ride on the transfer system. Efficiency can be achieved by introducing a second transfer scheme that is independent of regional public production. If the federal government sets its policy first and can commit itself to it, the outcome is efficient only if matching grants are used that are financed outside of the transfer system.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Abstracting from inter-regional spillovers, decentralization can enhance or hinder efficiency depending on the context. Arzaghi and Henderson (2005) measure the determinants and the demand for decentralization in different contexts. From a political economy point of view, the principal (voters) can control the performance of the agent (government) better if the latter is local, which can lead to a better government performance and increased happiness (Voigt and Blume 2012).

  2. Spillovers can consist of public goods produced in one jurisdiction “spilling out” to other jurisdictions (e.g., flood protection measures that also protect jurisdictions located downriver), or the population of other jurisdictions “spilling into” a jurisdiction to consume a public good (e.g., visiting a subsidized opera house or sports stadium).

  3. See Wilson and Wildasin (2004), Fuest et al. (2005) and Keen and Konrad (2013) for comprehensive surveys on capital taxation.

  4. There are economic and political arguments for an inability to commit on behalf of the central government. If the central government is benevolent and interested in maximizing total welfare, it might change from its pre-specified policy if inefficiencies from local policy decisions are too large (Wildasin 1999). Political motives include reputation effects and the incentives to win votes by giving transfers to poorer regions (see Oates 2005).

  5. Some of the literature labels the lack of commitment inability as a “soft budget constraint” (see Qian and Roland 1998; Goodspeed 2002; Kornai et al. 2003). A soft budget constraint implies that the central government is expected to increase subsidies in response to regional government taxes as it allocates these grants in order to equalize marginal utilities of public good consumption across the federation. See Kornai et al. (2003) for a more in-depth discussion of soft budget constraints.

  6. Bondarev et al. (2017) examine the choice between different types of public goods, some of which may convey negative externalities to other regions; however, they abstract from tax competition and thus from fiscal externalities.

  7. For an analysis focusing on both spillovers and congestion, see Kuhlmey and Hintermann (2019).

  8. Capital is interpreted as physical capital (i.e., factories) and not as financial investments, which would require a different type of model (in which the level of regional production would not depend on the level of capital). Generally speaking, capital is interpreted as anything generating real output that is mobile across regions; see Keen and Konrad (2013) for a discussion. We further refrain from modeling mobility costs of capital.

  9. An alternative interpretation of \(L_i\) would be land. The relevant assumption about this factor is immobility across regions and that it does not serve as a regional tax base.

  10. This means that the marginal rate of transformation between the private and the public good is equal to one.

  11. Whether the individual transfers add to zero or some other value is immaterial, as long as this value is fixed. The crucial point is that \(\sum _i ds_i=0\) such that increasing the transfer to one region requires a reduction in the transfers for other regions; for a more general treatment with positive (but fixed) transfers, see Breuille et al. (2010).

  12. With a perfectly competitive product market, condition (7) is always satisfied with identity. To see this, substitute (1) and (2) into the LHS of (7), and substitute (3), (4) and (12) into the RHS, to get \(\sum _N w_i + t_i k_i + R k_i = \sum _N w_i + t_i k_i R \bar{k}_i\). Since the sum of the employed capital (\(k_i\)) has to equal the sum of available capital (\(\bar{k}_i\)), the equilibrium condition (7) is always satisfied and can be ignored. Wilson (1987) modifies the model and analyzes trade in two goods; for a modification with trade costs, see Becker and Runkel (2012).

  13. With a fixed capital supply (zero elasticity of supply), impacts of taxes are entirely felt by the aggregated suppliers of capital (= all households) as R will respond to changes in t. Papers relaxing the assumption of fixed capital supply include Ogawa and Wildasin (2009) and Eichner and Runkel (2012).

  14. It is never a dominant strategy for region i to raise its tax until \(R = 0\), and we abstract from the possibility that capital could be in excess supply, as in Bucovetsky (1991).

  15. If regions are not symmetric, the presence of a federal government affects the equilibrium outcome due to the (nonzero) transfer that will co-determine consumption and production. However, the functional forms of the optimality conditions would remain the same. In the social optimum, this is due to the fact that our benevolent federal government simply takes the place of the social planner in Bjorvatn and Schjelderup (2002). For the Nash equilibrium, any federal transfer is considered as given by the regional governments and thus drops out of the first-order conditions.

  16. Because we focus on interior solutions, we abstract from the complementary slackness conditions. The second-order conditions are negative and therefore consistent with a welfare maximum.

  17. Bjorvatn and Schjelderup (2002) and Koethenbuerger (2004) use a quasi-linear utility function defined by \(U_{i}(c_{i}, G_{i})= c_{i} + \mathrm{ln}\left( [t_{i} k_{i} + s_{i}] + \beta \sum _{m\ne i}^n \left[ t_{m} k_{m} + s_{m}\right] \right) \). Using this in (14) and solving leads to the Pareto-optimal tax \(t^\mathrm{PO} = 1/k\), which is independent of \(\beta \) and n. However, this is due to the fact that the marginal utility of income is constant with quasi-linear preferences, which is obviously a special case.

  18. Akai and Sato (2008) provide a comparison of expenditure and tax optimization in a decentralized leadership game. Our setting, as well as that in Koethenbuerger (2004), Breuille et al. (2010) and Silva (2016) relate to their scenario B, in which \(t_i\) is decided ex ante and \(g_i\) adjusts ex post. They find that a decentralized leadership system in which taxes are the strategic choice variable leads to revenue sharing due to local government’s free-riding on tax collection efforts of others, in line with Koethenbuerger (2004) and our own results. In contrast, when \(g_i\) is the choice variable, cost sharing of expenditures leads to excessive expansion, i.e., over-provision. The intuition is that choosing \(g_i\) leads to cost sharing of own expenditure with all other local governments (hence a common pool problem). Ex post per capita transfers to regional governments are increasing in its expenditure and decreasing when other regions spend more. As the ex post tax burden of each regional government depends only on the economy-wide resource constraint, not on its own ex ante spending decisions. Akai and Sato (2008) demonstrate that this fosters overspending ex ante. See Wildasin (1988) for a further discussion on how the choice of strategic variable can influence the Nash equilibrium. In this paper, we focus on regions setting \(t_i\).

  19. We would like to note that the equalization of public consumption is not the goal but a by-product of utility maximization. Transfers are chosen with the aim to maximize social welfare, and under symmetry, equalized public consumption is implied.

  20. In symmetry, taxes are equal and consequently capital such that \(s^\mathrm{NE}\) is zero.

  21. We refer to Bloch and Zenginobuz  (2015, Proposition 3). The equilibrium tax rate in their model depends nonlinearly on the spillover parameter, as is the case here. Furthermore, the equilibrium tax rate decreases if mobility increases, which is conceptually similar to the tax in the Nash equilibrium defined by (22)–(23). Here, the tax decreases if capital is “more mobile”, meaning that \(|f''|\) is smaller (the more linear the production function, the greater is the elasticity of regional capital demand with respect to the tax rate, \(\epsilon \)).

  22. If spillovers were asymmetric in the sense that \(\beta _{ij}\ne \beta _{ji}\) and/or \(\beta _{ij}\ne \beta _{im}\), for \(i \ne j\), \(i\ne m\), the spillover parameters would not cancel. In this case, the best-response function would depend on the region in question, and on the associated vector of spillover parameters.

  23. With a self-financing transfer system and symmetry, it must be that \(s_i=0 \, \forall \, i\) in equilibrium. In order to supply the efficient amount of the public good, the regions have to set the tax rate to \(t^\mathrm{PO}\).

  24. Given that all federal inputs are fixed in this model, this could be substituted by a federal tax on capital or labor without loss of generality.

  25. For \(\beta =1\), both sides of the reaction functions are zero, and again, as with a net transfer system (4.1.1), any federal transfer will lead to the same outcome since all regions consume the “pure” public good.

  26. Conversely, we can state that with ex ante identical regions, any non-symmetric outcome will not be efficient as the federal government can only tailor \(s_i\) to individual regions, but not T. This means that the MRS cannot be equalized across regions if regional tax rates differ. However, non-symmetric tax rates by ex ante identical regions will not constitute a Nash equilibrium in the first stage of the game and thus can be ruled out.

  27. For simplicity, we have modeled the grant as a lump-sum transfer above. In the Nash equilibrium, regional governments take the money amount of the transfer as given, regardless of how this amount is determined. In the decentralized leadership setting, the grant is chosen such that public consumption is equalized across regions (\(G_i=G_j\)). Again, the form of the grant is immaterial.

  28. Ogawa (2006) uses a region-specific tax \(T_i\), but one that is not self-financing and therefore does not correspond to the income-redistributing net transfer considered above (note that he does not discuss the issue of commitment). The result is the same under symmetry, as all regions pay the same tax, but the outcome would differ with asymmetric regions. Since both the population and the total amount of capital are held fixed, T could also be specified as a tax on labor, or as a residence-based tax on capital \(\bar{k_i}\).

References

  • Akai, N., & Sato, M. (2008). Too big or too small? A synthetic view of the commitment problem of interregional transfers. Journal of Urban Economics, 64(3), 551–559.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arzaghi, M., & Henderson, J. V. (2005). Why countries are fiscally decentralizing. Journal of Public Economics, 89(7), 1157–1189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, J., & Runkel, M. (2012). Even small trade costs restore efficiency in tax competition. Journal of Urban Economics, 72(2–3), 191–195.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bjorvatn, K., & Schjelderup, G. (2002). Tax competition and international public goods. International Tax and Public Finance, 9(2), 111–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloch, F., & Zenginobuz, U. (2007). The effect of spillovers on the provision of local public goods. Review of Economic Design, 11(3), 199–216.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloch, F., & Zenginobuz, Ü. (2015). Oates’ decentralization theorem with imperfect household mobility. International Tax and Public Finance, 22(3), 353–375.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blöchliger, H., & Kim, J. (2016). Fiscal federalism 2016 making decentralisation work: Making decentralisation work. Paris: OECD Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boadway, R. (2004). The theory and practice of equalization. CESifo Economic Studies, 50(1), 211–254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boadway, R., & Tremblay, J.-F. (2012). Reassessment of the Tiebout model. Journal of Public Economics, 96(11–12), 1063–1078.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bondarev, A., Hintermann, B., Krysiak, F., & Winkler, R. (2017). The intricacy of adapting to climate change: Flood protection as a local public goods game. CESifo Working Paper No. 6382.

  • Breuille, M.-L., Madies, T., & Taugourdeau, E. (2010). Gross versus net equalization scheme in a federation with decentralized leadership. Journal of Urban Economics, 68(2), 205–214.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brülhart, M., Bucovetsky, S., & Schmidheiny, K. (2015). Chapter 17–Taxes in cities. In G. Duranton, J. V. Henderson, & W. C. Strange (Eds.), Handbook of regional and urban economics (Vol. 5, pp. 1123–1196). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bucovetsky, S. (1991). Asymmetric tax competition. Journal of Urban Economics, 30(2), 167–181.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caplan, A. J., Cornes, R. C., & Silva, E. C. (2000). Pure public goods and income redistribution in a federation with decentralized leadership and imperfect labor mobility. Journal of Public Economics, 77(2), 265–284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahlby, B. (1996). Fiscal externalities and the design of intergovernmental grants. International Tax and Public Finance, 3(3), 397–412.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahlby, B., & Wilson, L. S. (1994). Fiscal capacity, tax effort, and optimal equalization grants. Canadian Journal of Economics, 27(3), 657–672.

    Google Scholar 

  • DePeter, J. A., & Myers, G. M. (1994). Strategic capital tax competition: A pecuniary externality and a corrective device. Journal of Urban Economics, 36(1), 66–78.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichner, T., & Runkel, M. (2012). Interjurisdictional spillovers, decentralized policymaking, and the elasticity of capital supply. American Economic Review, 102(5), 2349–2357.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fell, H., & Kaffine, D. T. (2014). Can decentralized planning really achieve first-best in the presence of environmental spillovers? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 68(1), 46–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuest, C., Huber, B., & Mintz, J. (2005). Capital mobility and tax competition. Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics, 1(1), 1–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodspeed, T. J. (2002). Bailouts in a federation. International Tax and Public Finance, 9(4), 409–421.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayashi, M., & Boadway, R. (2001). An empirical analysis of intergovernmental tax interaction: The case of business income taxes in Canada. Canadian Journal of Economics, 34(2), 481–503.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoyt, W. H. (1991). Property taxation, Nash equilibrium, and market power. Journal of Urban Economics, 30(1), 123–131.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keen, M., & Konrad, K. A. (2013). The theory of international tax competition and coordination. Handbook of Public Economics, 5, 257.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keen, M. J., & Kotsogiannis, C. (2002). Does federalism lead to excessively high taxes? American Economic Review, 92(1), 363–370.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koethenbuerger, M. (2004). Tax competition in a fiscal union with decentralized leadership. Journal of Urban Economics, 55(3), 498–513.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kornai, J., Maskin, E., & Roland, G. (2003). Understanding the soft budget constraint. Journal of Economic Literature, 41(4), 1095–1136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuhlmey, F., & Hintermann, B. (2019). The welfare costs of Tiebout sorting with true public goods. International Tax and Public Finance, 26(5), 1166–1210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood, B. (1999). Inter-regional insurance. Journal of Public Economics, 72(1), 1–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. E. (1999). An essay on fiscal federalism. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(3), 1120–1149.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. E. (2005). Toward a second-generation theory of fiscal federalism. International Tax and Public Finance, 12(4), 349–373.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates, W. E., & Schwab, R. M. (1988). Economic competition among jurisdictions: Efficiency enhancing or distortion inducing? Journal of Public Economics, 35(3), 333–354.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ogawa, H. (2006). Tax competition, spillovers, and subsidies. The Annals of Regional Science, 40(4), 849–858.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ogawa, H., & Wildasin, D. E. (2009). Think locally, act locally: Spillovers, spillbacks, and efficient decentralized policymaking. American Economic Review, 99(4), 1206–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pinto, S. M. (2007). Tax competition in the presence of interjurisdictional externalities: The case of crime prevention. Journal of Regional Science, 47(5), 897–913.

    Google Scholar 

  • Qian, Y., & Roland, G. (1998). Federalism and the soft budget constraint. American Economic Review, 88(5), 1143–1162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silva, E. C. (2016). Tax competition and federal equalization schemes with decentralized leadership. International Tax and Public Finance, 24(1), 1–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silva, E. C., & Caplan, A. J. (1997). Transboundary pollution control in federal systems. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 34(2), 173–186.

    Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, S., & Blume, L. (2012). The economic effects of federalism and decentralization—A cross-country assessment. Public Choice, 151(1–2), 229–254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Warr, P. G. (1983). The private provision of a public good is independent of the distribution of income. Economics Letters, 13(2), 207–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wellisch, D. (1994). Interregional spillovers in the presence of perfect and imperfect household mobility. Journal of Public Economics, 55(2), 167–184.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin, D. (1989). Interjurisdictional capital mobility: Fiscal externality and a corrective subsidy. Journal of Urban Economics, 5(2), 193–212.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin, D. E. (1988). Nash equilibria in models of fiscal competition. Journal of Public Economics, 35(2), 229–240.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin, D. E. (1999). Externalities and bailouts: Hard and soft budget constraints in intergovernmental fiscal relations. Singapore: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, A. (1966). The optimal provision of public goods in a system of local government. Journal of Political Economy, 74(1), 18–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J. D. (1985). Optimal property taxation in the presence of interregional capital mobility. Journal of Urban Economics, 18(1), 73–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J. D. (1986). A theory of interregional tax competition. Journal of Urban Economics, 19(3), 296–315.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J. D. (1987). Trade, capital mobility, and tax competition. Journal of Political Economy, 95(4), 835–856.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J. D. (1999). Theories of tax competition. National Tax Journal, 52(2), 269–304.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J. D., & Wildasin, D. E. (2004). Capital tax competition: Bane or boon? Journal of Public Economics, 88(6), 1065–1091.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zodrow, G. R., & Mieszkowski, P. (1986). Pigou, Tiebout, property taxation, and the underprovision of local public goods. Journal of Urban Economics, 19(3), 356–370.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This research has been supported by the Swiss National Science Foundation under Grant No. CRSII1-154404 (Sinergia).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Beat Hintermann.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Benchmark cases

The solution to the maximization problem (13) can be found by substituting the definition for \(G_{i}\) into the utility function and form the Lagrangian:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{\{c_{1\ldots n}\}, \{g_{1\ldots n}\}} L= & {} U_{i} \left( c_{i}, g_{i} + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n g_{m}\right) + \sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1 \\ j\ne i \end{array}}^n U_{j} \left( c_{j}, g_{j} + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne j \end{array}}^n g_{m} \right) \\&- \lambda \sum _{i=1}^n \left( f(k_{i}) - c_{i} - g_{i}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Taking the derivatives w.r.t. to \(c_i\) and \(g_i\) (which produces 2n first-order conditions) and rearranging them leads to the following n optimality conditions:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial U_{i}}{\partial c_{i}} = \frac{\partial U_{i}}{\partial G_{i}} \frac{\partial G_{i}}{\partial g_{i}} + \sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1 \\ j\ne i \end{array}}^n \frac{\partial U_{j}}{\partial G_{j}} \frac{\partial G_{j}}{\partial g_{i}} \quad \forall \,\, i . \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

At the optimum, the change in the marginal utility of private consumption has to equal the change in the marginal utility of public good consumption for each region. Imposing symmetry, defining the marginal rate of substitution between public and private consumption as \(\mathrm{MRS}_i \equiv {\frac{\partial U_{i}}{\partial G_{i}}}/{\frac{\partial U_{i}}{\partial c_{i}}}\) and suppressing the subscript yields expression (14). Finally, substituting \(\partial U/\partial c=1/c\) and \(\partial U/\partial G=1/G\) and equating with (14) leads to the optimal tax given by (16).

The Nash equilibrium is derived by rearranging the first-order condition from (20) to:

$$\begin{aligned} \hbox {MRS}_{i} \equiv \frac{\frac{\partial U}{\partial G_{i}}}{\frac{\partial U}{\partial c_{i}}}=- \frac{\frac{\partial c_{i}}{\partial t_{i}}}{\frac{\partial G_{i}}{\partial t_{i}}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

The marginal effect of taxes on consumption (income) is:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial c_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} = - f^{\prime }{}^{\prime }{}(k_{i}) \frac{\partial k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} k_{i} + \frac{\partial R}{\partial t_{i}}{\bar{k}}_{i}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

The effect on income is separated into the effect on wage income (first term) and capital income (second term), both of which are negative. Increasing taxes increases public consumption at the cost of private consumption. The derivative of public good consumption with respect to the tax rate is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial G_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} = k_i + t_i \frac{\partial k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} +\beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1 \\ j\ne i \end{array}}^n\frac{\partial t_{j} k_{j} }{\partial t_{i}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)

The first term is the mechanical increase in tax revenue if the tax rate is marginally raised, holding capital fixed. The second term is negative and captures the outflow of capital to other regions in response to a marginal tax increase in region i. This negative cost is however dampened by positive spillovers from other regions (third term). Substituting (A.3) and (A.4) into (A.2) yields:

$$\begin{aligned} \hbox {MRS}^\mathrm{NE}_{i} = \frac{f^{\prime }{}^{\prime }{}(k_{i}) \frac{\partial k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} k_{i} - \frac{\partial R}{\partial t_{i}}{\bar{k}}_{i}}{k_{i} + \frac{\partial k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} t_{i} +\beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1 \\ j\ne i \end{array}}^n \frac{\partial k_{j}}{\partial t_{i}} t_{j}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)

Imposing symmetry and using the capital market clearing conditions (10), we obtain the MRS which defines the Nash equilibrium in (21).

1.2 Decentralized leadership

1.2.1 Net single transfer system: Proof of Proposition 1

The optimality condition from solving (30) is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial U_{i}}{\partial G_{i}} \frac{\partial G_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} = - \frac{\partial U_{i}}{\partial c_{i}} \frac{\partial c_{i}}{\partial t_{i}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.6)

The marginal change in private consumption is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial c_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} = - f^{\prime }{}^{\prime }{}(k_{i}) \frac{\partial k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} k_{i} + \frac{\partial R}{\partial t_{i}}{\bar{k}}_{i} =-k, \end{aligned}$$
(A.7)

where the last equality follows from substituting (10).

The marginal change in public consumption for region i is

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial G_{i}}{\partial t_{i}}&= \frac{\partial t_{i} k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} + \frac{\partial s_{i}}{\partial t_i} +\beta (n-1) \left( \frac{\partial t_{m} k_{m} }{\partial t_{i}} + \frac{\partial s_{m}}{\partial t_{i}} \right) \nonumber \\&= \frac{\partial t_{i} k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} +\beta (n-1) \frac{\partial t_{m} k_{m} }{\partial t_{i}} + (1-\beta ) \left( \frac{n-1}{n}\right) \left( \frac{\partial t_{m} k_{m}}{\partial t_{i}} - \frac{\partial t_{i} k_{i} }{\partial t_{i}}\right) \nonumber \\&= \frac{1+\beta (n-1)}{n} \left( \frac{\partial t_{i} k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} + (n-1) \frac{ \partial t_{m} k_{m} }{\partial t_{i}}\right) \nonumber \\&= \frac{1+(n-1) \beta }{n}k, \end{aligned}$$
(A.8)

where we used (29) (second line), collected terms (third line) and substituted the capital market clearing conditions (10) (fourth line). The change in mobile capital in region i and regions \(m\ne i\) as a response to the change in \(t_{i}\) cancels out in equilibrium due to the federal transfer setting:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial t_{i} k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} + (n-1) \frac{\partial t_{m} k_{m}}{\partial t_{i}} = k + \frac{n-1}{n} \frac{1}{f''(k)} t - \frac{n-1}{n} \frac{1}{f''(k)} t = k\, . \end{aligned}$$

What remains is the additional positive tax revenue effect to region i given by k. Expression (31) follows directly from substituting (A.8) and (A.7) into (A.6) \(\square \)

1.2.2 Net transfer system including private income redistribution

In stage 2, the maximization problem of the federal government is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{\{G_{1\ldots n}\}, \{s_{1\ldots n}\}, \{\tau _{1\ldots n}\}, \{g_{1\ldots n}\}, \{c_{1\ldots n}\}} \quad \sum _{i=1}^n U_{i} (c_{i}, G_{i}) \qquad&\text {s.t.} \qquad G_{i}=g_{i} + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n g_{m} \nonumber \\&\sum _{i=1}^n s_{i} = 0 \nonumber \\&\sum _{i=1}^{n} \tau _i = 0\nonumber \\&g_{i} = t_{i} k_{i} + s_{i} \nonumber \\&c_{i}= f(k_{i}) -\frac{\partial f(k_{i})}{\partial k_{i}} k_{i} + \bar{k_{i}} R + \tau _i. \end{aligned}$$
(A.9)

Substituting the regional governments’ and households’ budget constraints, the Lagrangian and the first-order conditions can be written as

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{\{s_{1\ldots n}\}, \{\tau _{1\ldots n}\}}&\quad L= \sum _{i=1}^n U_{i} \bigg (f(k_{i}) -\frac{\partial f(k_{i})}{\partial k_{i}} k_{i} + \bar{k_{i}} R + \tau _i , t_{i} k_{i} + s_{i} + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n t_{m} k_{m} + s_{m} \bigg ) \nonumber \\&\quad \qquad + \lambda \sum _{i=1}^n s_{i} + \mu \sum _{i=1}^{n} \tau _i \end{aligned}$$
(A.10)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial L}{\partial s_{i}} = \frac{\partial U}{\partial G_{i}} + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n \frac{\partial U}{\partial G_{m}} + \lambda = 0 \quad \forall i \end{aligned}$$
(A.11)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial L}{\partial \tau _i} = \frac{\partial U}{\partial c_{i}} + \mu = 0 \quad \forall i \end{aligned}$$
(A.12)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial L}{\partial \lambda } = \sum _{i=1}^n s_{i} = 0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.13)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial L}{\partial \mu } = \sum _{i=1}^n \tau _{i} = 0 . \end{aligned}$$
(A.14)

Using (A.11) for regions i and \(j\ne i\), combining and imposing symmetry yields (33). Equation (34) is derived in the same manner using (A.12) for regions i and j. Finally, the reaction function for private consumption transfers can be found using (34) and the federal budget constraint (A.14):

$$\begin{aligned}&f(k_{i}) -\frac{\partial f(k_{i})}{\partial k_{i}} k_{i} + \bar{k_{i}} R + \tau _i = f(k_{j}) -\frac{\partial f(k_{j})}{\partial k_{j}} k_{j} + \bar{k_{j}} R + \tau _j \end{aligned}$$
(A.15)
$$\begin{aligned}&\tau _i = - (n-1) \tau _j \quad \text {or} \quad \tau _j = - \frac{1}{n-1} \tau _i . \end{aligned}$$
(A.16)

Using (A.14) and (9) in (A.15) and differentiating with respect to \(t_i\) yields:

$$\begin{aligned}&f^{\prime }{}^{\prime }{}(k_{i}) \frac{\partial k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} (\bar{k}_{i} - k_{i}) - {\bar{k}}_{i} + \frac{\partial \tau _i}{\partial t_i} = f^{\prime }{}^{\prime }{}(k_{j}) \frac{\partial k_{j}}{\partial t_{i}} (\bar{k}_{j} - k_{j}) - \frac{1}{n-1} \frac{\partial \tau _i}{\partial t_i} \end{aligned}$$

Substituting (10) and solving for \(\frac{\partial \tau _i}{\partial t_i}\) and using it in (A.16) as well yields the reaction function (35).

Proof of Proposition 2

In the first stage, regional governments solve:

$$\begin{aligned}&\max _{G_i,g_i, c_i, t_{i}} \quad U(c_{i}, G_i) \quad \text {s.t.} \quad&G_{i}= g_i + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n g_m \\&g_i= t_{i} k_{i} + s_{i} \\&c_i = f(k_{i}) - f'(k_{i}) k_{i} +\bar{k_{i}} R - \tau _i \\&\text {with} \quad s_i=s_i(t_i, t_j); \quad s_j= s_j(t_i, t_j); \tau _i=\tau _i(t_i, t_j). \end{aligned}$$

Solving the model results in the same optimality condition as in the Nash equilibrium, given by (A.2). The change in private consumption is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial c_{i}}{\partial t_{i}}&= - f^{\prime }{}^{\prime }{}(k_{i}) \frac{\partial k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} k_{i} + \frac{\partial R}{\partial t_{i}}{\bar{k}}_{i} - \frac{\partial \tau _i}{\partial t_i} = - \frac{1}{n} k, \end{aligned}$$
(A.17)

where the last equality follows from substituting (10) and (35). The change in public consumption with respect to \(t_i\) is equivalent to (A.8). Using (A.17) and (A.8) in (A.2) leads to (36). \(\square \)

1.2.3 Gross transfer system(s)

The federal government chooses both T and the region-specific transfers \(s_i\) to maximize total welfare. After substituting the budget constraints, the Lagrangian can be written as:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{\{s_{1\ldots n}\},T } \quad L= & {} \sum _{i=1}^n U_{i} \left( f(k_{i}) -\frac{\partial f(k_{i})}{\partial k_{i}} k_{i} + \bar{k_{i}} R - T ; \,\, t_{i} k_{i} + s_{i} + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n t_{m} k_{m} + s_{m} \right) \\&+ \,\,\lambda \left( \sum _{i=1}^n s_{i} - n T \right) \end{aligned}$$

where \(\lambda \) is the Lagrangian multiplier of the federal budget constraint. The first-order conditions are given by:

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial L}{\partial s_{i}} = \frac{\partial U}{\partial G_{i}} + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n \frac{\partial U}{\partial G_{m}} + \lambda = 0 \quad \forall i \end{aligned}$$
(A.18)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial L}{\partial T} = - \sum _{\begin{array}{c} i=1 \end{array}}^n \frac{\partial U}{\partial c_{i}} - \lambda n = 0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.19)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial L}{\partial \lambda } = \sum _{i=1}^n s_{i} - n T = 0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.20)

Using (A.18) for i and \(j \ne i\), combining and imposing symmetry yields (37). Combining (A.18) and (A.19) yields (38).

Taking the partial derivative of the first-order conditions with respect to \(t_i\) (which is a parameter from the point of view of the central government) gives

$$\begin{aligned}&\big (1 + \beta (n-1)\big ) U_{GG} \frac{\partial G_i}{\partial t_{i}} = 0 \quad \forall i \end{aligned}$$
(A.21)
$$\begin{aligned}&- U_{CC} \frac{\partial c_i}{\partial t_{i}} = 0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.22)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial s_{i} }{\partial t_i} = n \frac{\partial T }{\partial t_i} - (n-1) \frac{\partial s_{j} }{\partial t_i}, \end{aligned}$$
(A.23)

where \(U_{GG} \equiv \frac{\partial ^2 U}{\partial G_{i}^2}\) and \(U_{CC} \equiv \frac{\partial ^2 U}{\partial c_{i}^2}\). Equation (A.21) can be rewritten such that \(\frac{\partial G_i}{\partial t_{i}} = \frac{\partial G_j}{\partial t_{i}}\) (differentiating (37) with respect to \(t_i\) would be an alternative to derive the same expression):

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial t_i k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} + \frac{\partial s_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} +\beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1 \\ j\ne i \end{array}}^n \bigg (\frac{\partial \ t_{j} k_{j} }{\partial t_{i}} + \frac{\partial s_{j}}{\partial t_{i}}\bigg ) = \frac{\partial t_j k_{j}}{\partial t_{i}} + \frac{\partial s_{j}}{\partial t_{i}} + \beta \bigg ( \frac{\partial t_i k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} + \frac{\partial s_{i}}{\partial t_{i}}\bigg ) + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne j \end{array}}^n \bigg (\frac{\partial \ t_{m} k_{m} }{\partial t_{i}} + \frac{\partial s_{m}}{\partial t_{i}}\bigg ) \\&\frac{\partial t_i k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} + \frac{\partial s_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} +\beta (n-1) \bigg (\frac{\partial \ t_{j} k_{j} }{\partial t_{i}} + \frac{\partial s_{j}}{\partial t_{i}}\bigg ) = \big (1+\beta (n-2)\big ) \bigg (\frac{\partial t_j k_{j}}{\partial t_{i}} + \frac{\partial s_{j}}{\partial t_{i}}\bigg ) + \beta \bigg ( \frac{\partial t_i k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} + \frac{\partial s_{i}}{\partial t_{i}}\bigg ) \\&(1-\beta ) \bigg (\frac{\partial t_i k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} + \frac{\partial s_{i}}{\partial t_{i}}\bigg ) = (1-\beta ) \bigg (\frac{\partial t_j k_{j}}{\partial t_{i}} + \frac{\partial s_{j}}{\partial t_{i}}\bigg ), \end{aligned}$$

where symmetry is applied in the second line. Substituting (A.23), we get:

$$\begin{aligned} (1-\beta ) \frac{\partial s_{j}}{\partial t_{i}} = (1-\beta ) \bigg ( n \frac{\partial T }{\partial t_i} - (n-1) \frac{\partial s_{j} }{\partial t_i} + \frac{\partial t_i k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} - \frac{\partial t_j k_{j}}{\partial t_{i}}\bigg ). \end{aligned}$$

Solving for \(\frac{\partial s_{i} }{\partial t_i}\) and \(\frac{\partial s_{j}}{\partial t_{i}}\), results in the reaction functions

$$\begin{aligned}&(1-\beta ) \frac{\partial s_{i} }{\partial t_i} = (1-\beta ) \left( \frac{n-1}{n} \bigg ( \frac{\partial t_j k_{j}}{\partial t_{i}} - \frac{\partial t_i k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} \bigg ) + \frac{\partial T }{\partial t_i} \right) \\&(1-\beta ) \frac{\partial s_{j}}{\partial t_{i}} = (1-\beta ) \left( \frac{\partial T }{\partial t_i} + \frac{1}{n} \bigg ( \frac{\partial t_i k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} - \frac{\partial t_j k_{j}}{\partial t_{i}}\bigg ) \right) \, , \end{aligned}$$

which simplifies to (39) for \(\beta <1\).

In stage 1, the regional governments maximize regional utility incorporating the reaction of the federal policy to their tax increase:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{G_i, g_i, c_i, t_{i}} \quad U(c_{i}, G_{i}) \qquad \text {s.t.} \qquad&G_{i}= g_i + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n g_m \\&g_i = t_{i} k_{i} + s_{i} \\&c_i = f(k_{i}) - f'(k_{i}) k_{i} +\bar{k_{i}} R - T \\&t_i \ge 0\\ \text {with} \qquad \qquad&s_i=s_i(t_i, t_j); \quad s_j= s_j(t_i, t_j); \quad T=T(t_i, t_j). \end{aligned}$$

Corollary 1

In stage 2, the maximization problem of the federal government using a gross transfer system as defined by part i, is:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{\{G_{1\ldots n}\}, \{s_{1\ldots n}\}, \{T_{1\ldots n}\}, \{g_{1\ldots n}\}, \{c_{1\ldots n}\}} \quad \sum _{i=1}^n U_{i} (c_{i}, G_{i}) \qquad \text {s.t.} \qquad&G_{i}=g_{i} + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n g_{m} \nonumber \\&\sum _{i=1}^n s_{i} = \sum _{i=1}^{n} T_i \nonumber \\&g_{i} = t_{i} k_{i} + s_{i} \nonumber \\&c_{i}= f(k_{i}) -\frac{\partial f(k_{i})}{\partial k_{i}} k_{i} + \bar{k_{i}} R - T_i. \end{aligned}$$
(A.24)

The Lagrangian and the FOCs are:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{\{s_{1\ldots n}\}, \{T_{1\ldots n}\}} \quad L&= \sum _{i=1}^n U_{i} \bigg (f(k_{i}) -\frac{\partial f(k_{i})}{\partial k_{i}} k_{i} + \bar{k_{i}} R - T_i , t_{i} k_{i} + s_{i} \nonumber \\&\quad + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n t_{m} k_{m} + s_{m} \bigg ) + \lambda \left( \sum _{i=1}^n s_{i} - \sum _{i=1}^{n} T_i \right) \end{aligned}$$
(A.25)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial L}{\partial s_{i}}&= \frac{\partial U}{\partial G_{i}} + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n \frac{\partial U}{\partial G_{m}} + \lambda = 0 \quad \forall i \end{aligned}$$
(A.26)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial L}{\partial T_i}&= - \frac{\partial U}{\partial c_{i}} - \lambda = 0 \quad \forall i \end{aligned}$$
(A.27)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial L}{\partial \lambda }&= \sum _{i=1}^n s_{i} - \sum _{i=1}^{n} T_i = 0 . \end{aligned}$$
(A.28)

Combining will lead to the same optimality conditions as in Sect. 4.1.2, i.e., (33) and (34).

The problem for part ii, after substituting the budget constraints, is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{\{s_{1\ldots n}\}, \{\tau _{1\ldots n}\},T } \quad L&= U_{i} \left( f(k_{i}) -\frac{\partial f(k_{i})}{\partial k_{i}} k_{i} + \bar{k_{i}} R + \tau _i -T, t_{i} k_{i} + s_{i} + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n t_{m} k_{m} + s_{m}\right) \nonumber \\&\quad + \sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1 \\ j\ne i \end{array}}^n U_{j} \left( f(k_{j}) -\frac{\partial f(k_{j})}{\partial k_{j}} k_{j} + \bar{k_{j}} R + \tau _j -T, t_{j} k_{j} + s_{j} + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne j \end{array}}^n t_{m} k_{m} + s_{m} \right) \nonumber \\&\quad + \lambda \left( \sum _{i=1}^n s_{i} - nT\right) + \mu \left( \sum _{i=1}^{n} \tau _i\right) \end{aligned}$$
(A.29)

The first-order conditions are given by:

$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial L}{\partial s_{i}} = \frac{\partial U}{\partial G_{i}} + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n \frac{\partial U}{\partial G_{m}} + \lambda = 0 \quad \forall i \end{aligned}$$
(A.30)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial L}{\partial T} = - \sum _{\begin{array}{c} i=1 \end{array}}^n \frac{\partial U}{\partial c_{i}} - \lambda n = 0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.31)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial L}{\partial \tau _i} = \frac{\partial U}{\partial c_{i}} + \mu = 0 \quad \forall i \end{aligned}$$
(A.32)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial L}{\partial \lambda } = \sum _{i=1}^n s_{i} - n T = 0 \end{aligned}$$
(A.33)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial L}{\partial \mu } =\sum _{i=1}^{n} \tau _i = 0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.34)

Combining leads to:

$$\begin{aligned}&U^{\prime }{}(G_{i}) = U ^{\prime }{}(G_{j})&\Rightarrow G_{i} = G_{j}&\forall \,\, i, \, j, \end{aligned}$$
(A.35)
$$\begin{aligned}&U^{\prime }{}(c_{i}) = U ^{\prime }{}(c_{j})&\Rightarrow c_{i} = c_{j}&\forall \,\, i, \, j , \end{aligned}$$
(A.36)
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\frac{\partial U}{\partial G_{i}}}{\frac{\partial U}{\partial c_{i}}} \equiv MRS_i = \frac{1}{1 + (n-1) \beta } \ \end{aligned}$$
(A.37)

in symmetry. Using (A.30) for region i and j results in (A.35). Likewise, using (A.32) for i and j leads to (A.36). Combining (A.30) with (A.31) establishes (A.37).

The federal government chooses transfers \(s_i\) and \(\tau _i\) such that the marginal utilities of private and public consumption across regions are equalized, which implies equal private and public good consumption across regions in symmetry. These two conditions suffice to establish an efficient solution as demonstrated in 4.1.2. The same is true if we concentrate on the first-order condition for T instead. Given that this problem has one redundant instrument and that regions are ex ante symmetric, the regional tax rates \(t_i=t_j=t\) are not identified in this equilibrium. If regional taxes are doubled, then the transfers would simply be cut in half, leaving public and private consumption unchanged as defined by (A.35)-(A.37). Without loss of generality, we can therefore set \(t_i\) to zero for all regions, or to any other value.

1.3 Centralized leadership

Starting in stage 2, the regional governments’ problem is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{G_i, g_i, c_i, t_{i}} U_i&\left( c_{i}, G_i\right) \\ \qquad \text {s. t. } \,\,&g_{i} = \frac{t_{i}k_{i}}{1-\alpha } \\&c_{i}= f(k_{i}) -\frac{\partial f(k_{i})}{\partial k_{i}} k_{i} + \bar{k_{i}} R - T\\&G_i = g_{i} + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n g_{m}. \end{aligned}$$

The optimality condition from combining the first-order conditions results in (A.2). When regional governments maximize regional utility, the marginal effect of taxes on consumption (income) is equivalent to the effect in the Nash game:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial c_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} = - f^{\prime }{}^{\prime }{}(k_{i}) \frac{\partial k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} k_{i} + \frac{\partial R}{\partial t_{i}}{\bar{k}}_{i}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.38)

The marginal effect of taxes on public consumption is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial G_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} = \frac{1}{1-\alpha } \bigg (k_i + t_i \frac{\partial k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} +\beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n\frac{\partial t_{m} k_{m} }{\partial t_{i}} \bigg ). \end{aligned}$$
(A.39)

Using (A.38) and (A.39) in the MRS (A.2) gives

$$\begin{aligned} MRS_{i}^\mathrm{CE} = \frac{f^{\prime }{}^{\prime }{}(k_{i}) \frac{\partial k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} k_{i} - \frac{\partial R}{\partial t_{i}}{\bar{k}}_{i}}{\frac{1}{1-\alpha } [k_{i} + \frac{\partial k_{i}}{\partial t_{i}} t_{i}] + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n \frac{\partial k_{m}}{\partial t_{i}} t_{m}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.40)

In symmetry and incorporating the reaction of the capital market given by (10), (A.40) becomes the optimality condition for the regions’ problem:

$$\begin{aligned} MRS^\mathrm{CE} = \frac{1-\alpha }{1 + (1-\beta ) (\frac{n-1}{n}) \frac{1}{f''(k)} \frac{t}{k}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.41)

In stage 1, substituting all budget constraints (households, regional and federal governments) and the definition for \(G_i\), the federal government chooses \(\alpha \) to maximize

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{\begin{array}{c} \alpha \end{array}} \, \sum _{i=1}^n&U_i\left( f(k_{i}) -\frac{\partial f(k_{i})}{\partial k_{i}} k_{i} + \bar{k_{i}} R - \frac{\alpha }{n} \sum _{i=1}^n g_{i} ; \, \, \frac{t_{i}k_{i}}{1-\alpha } + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m\ne i \end{array}}^n \frac{t_{m}k_{m}}{1-\alpha } \right) , \end{aligned}$$
(A.42)

which is

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial U_{i}}{\partial c_{i}} \sum _{\begin{array}{c} i=1 \end{array}}^n \bigg ( -\frac{1}{n} \frac{t_{i}k_{i}}{1 -\alpha } - \frac{\alpha }{n} \frac{t_{i}k_{i}}{(1 -\alpha )^2} \bigg ) + \frac{\partial U_{i}}{\partial G_{i}} \bigg (\frac{t_{i}k_{i}}{(1-\alpha )^2} + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1 \\ j\ne i \end{array}}^n \frac{t_{j}k_{j}}{(1-\alpha )^2}\bigg ) \\&\quad + \sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1 \\ j\ne i \end{array}}^n \frac{\partial U_{j}}{\partial c_{j}} \sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1 \end{array}}^n \bigg ( -\frac{1}{n} \frac{t_{j}k_{j}}{1-\alpha } - \frac{\alpha }{n} \frac{t_{j}k_{j}}{(1-\alpha )^2}\bigg )+ \sum _{\begin{array}{c} j=1 \\ j\ne i \end{array}}^n \frac{\partial U_{j}}{\partial G_{j}} \frac{t_{j}k_{j}}{(1-\alpha )^2} \\&\quad + \beta \sum _{\begin{array}{c} m=1 \\ m \ne j \end{array}}^n \frac{t_{m}k_{m}}{(1-\alpha )^2} = 0. \\ \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$

Multiplying by \(\frac{1}{(1-\alpha )^2}\), simplifying, imposing symmetry and collecting terms gives us in symmetry:

$$\begin{aligned} MRS^\mathrm{CE} = \frac{1}{1 + (n-1) \beta } = MRS^\mathrm{PO} \, . \end{aligned}$$
(A.43)

which is equivalent to the social optimum in (14).

Proof of Proposition 4

(i) When treating \(s_i\) as a lump-sum transfer rather than a matching grant, the transfer drops out of regions’ first-order conditions, and the resulting equilibrium is characterized by expression (21) and thus identical to the Nash equilibrium.

(ii) In order to induce Pareto-efficiency, the federal government sets the matching rate \(\alpha \) such that (A.41) and (A.43) are equalized:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1-\alpha }{1 + (1-\beta ) (\frac{n-1}{n}) \frac{1}{f''(k)} \frac{t}{k}} = \frac{1}{1+(n-1) \beta }. \end{aligned}$$

Solving for \(\alpha \) results in

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha ^\mathrm{CE}&= \frac{n-1}{n}\cdot \frac{ n \beta + (1-\beta ) \frac{1}{-f''(k)} \frac{t}{k} }{ 1 + (n-1)\beta } \nonumber \\&= \frac{ (n-1) \beta + (1-\beta ) \epsilon }{ 1 + (n-1)\beta }, \end{aligned}$$
(A.44)

with \(\epsilon \equiv \frac{n-1}{n}\frac{1}{-f''(k_i) }\frac{t}{k}\)

(iii) The derivative of the matching rate w.r.t. the spillover parameter is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \alpha ^\mathrm{CE}}{\partial \beta } = \frac{(n-1)(1 + \frac{1}{f''(k)} \frac{t}{k})}{(1 + ( n - 1) \beta )^2 }. \end{aligned}$$
(A.45)

Provided that \(n>1\), it follows that for \(\frac{1}{|f''(k)|} \frac{t}{k} < 1\), \(\partial \alpha ^\mathrm{CE}/\partial \beta >0\), and vice versa. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Armbruster, S., Hintermann, B. Decentralization with porous borders: public production in a federation with tax competition and spillovers. Int Tax Public Finance 27, 606–642 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-019-09572-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-019-09572-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation