Skip to main content
Log in

Does past experience affect future behavior? Evidence from estate tax avoidance behavior

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Unlike most other taxes that are levied on most individuals or corporations, the estate tax is levied on a small number of very large estates. This divides taxpayers sharply into two groups—those who have experience of having paid it before and those who don’t. Given the nature and the rate of the estate tax, the experience of having paid it is probably neither negligible nor forgettable. In this paper, using data from the Survey of Consumer Finances and a regression discontinuity design, I find evidence that the experience of paying the estate tax in the past increases the probability that the individual is currently engaged in estate tax avoidance behavior for their children. I also find that the experience has an impact on the probability (extensive margin), but not on the amount (intensive margin).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For a survey of literature on tax avoidance and its consequences, see Slemrod and Yitzhaki (2002) and Saez et al. (2012).

  2. See Gale et al. (2001) for various research topics on estate taxation.

  3. There is another advantage for gifts. As I mention in Sect. 2, even though the statutory tax rate is the same, gifts face a lower effective tax rate than estates.

  4. Gale et al. (2001) and Kopczuk (2013) survey related literature.

  5. See, for example, Altonji et al. (1997), Bernheim et al. (1985), Cox (1987; 1990) and Cox and Rank (1992) among others. Laferrre and Wolff (2006) and Arrondel and Masson (2006) survey theoretical and empirical literature, respectively.

  6. See McCaffery and Slemrod (2006) for a collection of interesting studies in the field. And Madrian (2014) and Chetty (2015) survey recent papers and issues in this field.

  7. It was $10,000 in 1998 and indexed for inflation since then.

  8. Some of the material in this subsection is drawn from Choi (2014).

  9. In the public-use data, the year is rounded to the nearest 5.

  10. Although the SCF 2010 is newly available, the SCF 2007 is the latest one when I started this project.

  11. Available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/econresdata/scf/files/bulletin.macro.txt

  12. I get qualitatively similar results when I use the entire 4418 individuals.

  13. See Menchik (1988), Wilhelm (1996), Dunn and Phillips (1997), Laferrre and Arrondel (1998), and McGarry (2001).

  14. I exclude wealth variables such as liquid assets and net worth from this comparison, because wealth accumulation behavior can be affected by the past estate tax experience.

  15. A referee suggests that due to the normal delays in arranging for the distribution of estates, the cutoff for estate tax could be a little lower than $675,000, say, for example, $650,000 in 2000. In fact, if I use a cutoff of $650,000 in the graphical analysis, the cutoff still matters for inter vivos transfer behavior. In the following regression analysis, where I use the entire dataset, not just those who received an inheritance in 2000, I assume that the individual had paid the estate tax before if the ratio between the estimated size of the parent’s estate at death and the exemption level for the estate tax exceeds 1. Using 0.9, instead of 1, as the cutoff still gives the same results, while the results are no longer significant if I use 0.8 as the cutoff. This suggests that the referee’s comment is valid, i.e., there are some delays in the distribution of estate and, thus, the correct cutoff might be a little lower than the tax threshold and the difference could be about 10 %.

  16. Other control variables include total amount of inheritances (in 2006 dollars), income, liquid assets, age, retirement status, marital status, education, and the number of children.

  17. If I use a fake threshold of 0.8 instead of 1 as a placebo test, the variable loses statistical significance. If I use 0.9, the result is still significant. This could reflect the fact that due to normal delays in arranging for the distribution of estate, the actual cutoff could be a little lower. (see footnote 15 for details.) For values above 1, I need a fake threshold higher than 1.5 for the variable to lose significance. This is probably because of a small sample size just above the threshold.

  18. I thank an anonymous referee for this point.

References

  • Altonji, J. G., Hayashi, F., & Kotlikoff, L. J. (1997). Parental altruism and inter vivos transfers: Theory and evidence. Journal of Political Economy, 105(6), 1121–1166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrondel, L., & Laferrere, A. (2001). Taxation and wealth transmission in France. Journal of Public Economics, 79(1), 3–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrondel, L., & Masson, A. (2006). Altruism, exchange or indirect reciprocity: What do the data on family transfers show? Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity, 2, 971–1053.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auten, G., & Joulfaian, D. (1996). Charitable contributions and intergenerational transfers. Journal of Public Economics, 59(1), 55–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auten, G., & Joulfaian, D. (2001). Bequest taxes and capital gains realizations. Journal of Public Economics, 81(2), 213–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach, A., Burman, L., & Siegel, J. (1998). Capital gains taxation and tax avoidance: New evidence from panel data. NBER Working Paper No. 6399

  • Bernheim, B. D., Lemke, R. J., & Scholz, J. K. (2004). Do estate and gift taxes affect the timing of private transfers? Journal of Public Economics, 88(12), 2617–2634.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, B. D., Shleifer, A., & Summers, L. H. (1985). The strategic bequest motive. The Journal of Political Economy, 93(6), 1045–1076.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chetty, R. (2015). Behavioral economics and public policy: A pragmatic perspective. NBER Working Paper No. 20928

  • Chetty, R., Friedman, J., & Saez, E. (2013). Using differences in knowledge across neighborhoods to uncover the impacts of the EITC on earnings. American Economic Review, 103(7), 2683–2721.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chetty, R., Looney, A., & Kroft, K. (2009). Salience and taxation: Theory and evidence. American Economic Review, 99(4), 1145–1177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chetty, R., & Saez, E. (2013). Teaching the tax code: Earnings responses to an experiment with EITC recipients. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 5(1), 1–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Choi, S. (2014) Reference-dependent preferences and charitable giving. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2430688.

  • Choi, J. J., Laibson, D., Madrian, B. C., & Metrick, A. (2004). For better or for worse: Default effects and 401 (k) savings behavior. In Perspectives on the economics of aging (pp. 81–126). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • Cox, D. (1987). Motives for private income transfers. The Journal of Political Economy, 95(3), 508–546.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, D. (1990). Intergenerational transfers and liquidity constraints. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104, 187–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, D., & Rank, M. R. (1992). Inter vivos transfers and intergenerational exchange. Review of Economics and Statistics, 74, 305–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunn, T. A., & Phillips, J. W. (1997). Do parents divide resources equally among children? Evidence from the AHEAD survey. Aging Studies Program Paper No. 5, Syracuse University.

  • Finkelstein, A. (2009). E-ZTAX: Tax salience and tax rates. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(3), 969–1010.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gale, W. G., Hines, J. R, Jr., & Slemrod, J. (Eds.). (2001). Rethinking estate and gift taxation. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joulfaian, D. (2004). Gift taxes and lifetime transfers: Time series evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 88(9–10), 1917–1929.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joulfaian, D. (2005). Choosing between gifts and bequests: How taxes affect the timing of wealth transfers. Journal of Public Economics, 89(11–12), 2069–2091.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joulfaian, D. (2013). The federal estate tax: History, law, and economics. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1579829.

  • Joulfaian, D., & McGarry, K. (2004). Estate and gift tax incentives and inter vivos giving. National Tax Journal, 57(2), 429–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kopczuk, W. (2013). Taxation of intergenerational transfers and wealth. In A. Auerbach, R. Chetty, M. Feldstein, & E. Saez (Eds.), Handbook of public economics (Vol. 5, pp. 329–390). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Laferrre, A. & Arrondel, L. (1998). Bequest motives and estate taxation in France. In ISPE conference on bequests and wealth taxation. University of Lie‘ge, Belgium.

  • Laferrre, A., & Wolff, F. C. (2006). Microeconomic models of family transfers. Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity, 2, 889–969.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusardi, A., & Mitchell, O. S. (2007). Baby boomer retirement security: The roles of planning, financial literacy, and housing wealth. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(1), 205–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Madrian, B. C. (2014). Applying insights from behavioral economics to policy design. NBER Working Paper No. 20318

  • McCaffery, E. J., & Slemrod, J. (Eds.). (2006). Behavioral public finance. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGarry, K. (2001). The cost of equality: Unequal bequests and tax avoidance. Journal of Public Economics, 79(1), 179–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menchik, P. L. (1988). Unequal estate division: Is it altruism, reverse bequests, or simply noise. In D. Kessler & A. Masson (Eds.), Modelling the accumulation and distribution of wealth (pp. 105–116). New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poterba, J. (2001). Estate and gift taxes and incentives for inter vivos giving in the US. Journal of Public Economics, 79(1), 237–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saez, E., Slemrod, J. B., & Giertz, S. H. (2012). The elasticity of taxable income with respect to marginal tax rates: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 50, 3–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slemrod, J., & Yitzhaki, S. (2002). Tax avoidance, evasion, and administration. In A. J. Auerbach & M. Feldstein (Eds.), Handbook of Public Economics (Vol. 3, pp. 1423–1470). Amsterdam; London, New York: Elsevier Science; North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilhelm, M. O. (1996). Bequest behavior and the effect of heirs’ earnings: Testing the altruistic model of bequests. American Economic Review, 86(4), 874–892.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I thank Alan Blinder, Henry Farber, Junghun Kim, John Londregan, Harvey Rosen, Heonjae Song and seminar participants at Princeton University, Korea Institute of Public Finance, and University of Seoul for helpful comments. I also thank Robert Chirinko (the editor) and two anonymous referees for their valuable suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sungmun Choi.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Choi, S. Does past experience affect future behavior? Evidence from estate tax avoidance behavior. Int Tax Public Finance 24, 416–431 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-016-9425-0

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-016-9425-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation