Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Public education spending in a globalized world:

Is there a shift in priorities across educational stages?

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies the effect of globalization on public expenditures allocated to different stages of education. First, we derive theoretically that globalization’s influence on education expenditures depends on the type of government. For benevolent governments, the model suggests that expenditures for higher education will increase and expenditures for basic education will decline with deepening economic integration. For Leviathan governments, on the other hand, the effects of globalization on public education spending cannot be unambiguously predicted. In the second part of the paper, we empirically analyze globalization’s influence on primary, secondary, and tertiary education expenditures with panel data covering 104 countries over the 1992–2006 period. The results indicate that globalization has led in both industrialized and developing countries to more spending for secondary and tertiary and to less spending for primary education.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Note that the underlying driving force behind globalization are technological advances in transportation, communication, and the processing of information that are only weakly influenced by policy-makers (James 2002). Cohen (1996) refers to political-driven versus technology-driven globalization as the “liberal” and “realist” models. In addition, he mentions two other perspectives emphasizing the role of the domestic political process and the importance of political culture and belief systems.

  2. In a previous version of our paper (Baskaran and Hessami 2010), we used a slightly different set of control variables, which resulted in a panel with 121 countries. The smaller number of countries in this paper is due to the use of gross enrollment rates instead of the population shares of the age groups that are relevant for a particular type of education (primary, secondary, or tertiary) as the control for the “theoretical demand” for that type of education, and the inclusion of the number of internet users per 100 persons as a control for technological change. Despite these differences, the results and conclusions are similar.

  3. We are grateful to an anonymous referee for pointing this out.

  4. Wälde (2000) explains the negative relationship between the share of primary education expenditures and income inequality by deriving that a higher share of secondary and tertiary expenditures provides incentives for the development of technologies. These technologies in turn lead to a replacement of unskilled by skilled labor that gives rise to a higher extent of income inequality.

  5. Note that Birdsall (1996) challenges the prevalent view that public resources for education in developing countries should be reallocated from higher to lower levels of education. Her main argument is that the available measures for social rates of returns to education do not capture all relevant dimensions.

  6. Education is generally regarded as a means for social development, democratic empowerment and the advancement of well-being and economic development of societies. The term “commodification” of education refers to the fact that education is increasingly understood as an economic factor, while students are looked upon primarily as consumers of education serving as human capital for the labor market.

  7. Andersson and Konrad (2003a) further extend this paper and analyze the welfare implications of the availability of private insurance in a world with costless mobility of the highly-educated and risky investments in education.

  8. On the other hand, Poutvaara (2000) shows that tax competition may also encourage investment in education as mobility insures individuals against region-specific shocks to the returns to education.

  9. Assuming that the production factors are supplied endogenously would lead to an alternative tax base effect. We ignore this effect in order to keep the model tractable.

  10. This result would change, of course, if the government maximized aggregate utility and not aggregate income. However, utility is unobservable in reality, and most governments claim to be interested in maximizing GDP. Therefore, this result probably describes real-world policy choices in well-run countries (i.e. countries whose governments are close to being benevolent) arguably well.

  11. While the model would in no case predict that expenditures for lower education increase if returns for low-skilled labor decline, this might be possible in reality if high-skilled individuals benefit sufficiently from lower education; see the discussion in Sect. 3.1.

  12. The Edstats database provides data on primary, secondary and tertiary education expenditures as a share of total education expenditures. We construct the data for expenditures on the three educational stages as a share of GDP by multiplying expenditures on the three educational stages as a share of total education expenditures by total education expenditures as a share of GDP. The data for total education expenditures as a share of GDP is from the Edstats database as well.

  13. We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this explanation.

  14. That is, when explaining primary education expenditures, we control for gross primary enrollment. When explaining secondary education expenditures, we control for gross primary and gross secondary enrollment. And when explaining tertiary education expenditures, we control for gross primary, gross secondary, and gross tertiary enrollment. As noted by an anonymous referee, it is important to control for gross enrollment in prior stages of education since prior enrollment rates affect how fast the government can increase expenditures for later stages. For example, the government will find it easier to increase spending for tertiary education if gross primary and gross secondary enrollment rates are already high.

  15. The ideology variable is derived from the DPI dataset. Whereas this dataset distinguishes between right, center, left, and other governments, we use, for compactness, a 0–1 classification. We code observations with governments that are explicitly identified as left-wing as 1 and all other observations as 0.

  16. The index is 1 when citizens have the highest and 7 when they have the lowest amount of political rights.

  17. Since fixed effects are included in (13), each of the countries in the sample has at least two non-missing observations during the time frame of the analysis.

  18. Any classification of countries as industrialized or developing is of course arbitrary. We classify only countries that were members of the OECD at some point during the sample period as industrialized. Therefore, the term developing as used in this paper should not be understood as being synonymous with, for example, the Least Developed Countries (LDC). It should rather be understood as encompassing all countries except the most wealthy.

  19. To see why, note that the complete specification of a model with country fixed effects and interactions of a continuous control variable with a dummy variable is: y it =α i +β 1 d i +β 2 x it +β 3 d i x it +ϵ it , with d i ∈{0,1} (we omit other control variables for brevity). Thus, β 2 is the marginal effect of x when d i =0 whereas β 2+β 3 is the marginal effect when d i =1. This expression is equivalent to y it =α i +β 1 d i +β 2(d i x it +(1−d i )x it )+β 3 d i x it +ϵ it , which can be rewritten as y it =α i +β 1 d i +β 2(1−d i )x it +(β 2+β 3)d i x it +ϵ it , or y it =z i +γc i x it +δd i x it +ϵ it , with z i =α i +β 1 d i , c i =(1−d i ),γ=β 2,δ=(β 2+β 3). This last expression has the same structure as (13). Since it is equivalent to the complete specification, the same is true for (13).

  20. The specification of these models is largely identical to that described in (13). The only difference is that for each spending category, all three enrollment shares are simultaneously included since relative spending is analyzed. Full results are available upon request.

  21. Note that this result is in line with the existing evidence for globalization’s aggravating influence on income inequality (Bergh and Nilsson 2010). In a similar vein, Hessami (2011) provides evidence that globalization has increased the well-being of high-income earners more than that of low-income earners.

References

  • Aizenman, J., & Jinjarak, Y. (2009). Globalisation and developing countries—a shrinking tax base? Journal of Development Studies, 45(5), 653–671.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersson, F., & Konrad, K. A. (2003a). Globalization and risky human-capital investment. International Tax and Public Finance, 10, 211–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersson, F., & Konrad, K. A. (2003b). Human capital investment and globalization in extortionary states. Journal of Public Economics, 87(7–8), 1539–1555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ansell, B. W. (2008). Traders, teachers, and tyrants: democracy, globalization, and public investment in education. International Organization, 62(2), 289–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Avelino, G., Brown, D. S., & Hunter, W. (2005). The effects of capital mobility, trade openness, and democracy on social spending in Latin America, 1980–1999. American Journal of Political Science, 49(3), 625–641.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartel, A. P., & Lichtenberg, F. R. (1987). The comparative advantage of educated workers in implementing new technology. Review of Economics and Statistics, 69, 1–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartel, A. P., & Lichtenberg, F. R. (1991). Technical change, learning, and wages. NBER Working Paper 2732.

  • Baskaran, T., & Hessami, Z. (2010). Globalization and the composition of public education expenditures: a dynamic panel analysis. Department of Economics, University of Konstanz Working Paper No. 2010-03.

  • Beck, T., Clarke, G., Groff, A., Keefer, P., & Walsh, P. (2001). New tools in comparative political economy: the database of political institutions. World Bank Economic Review, 15(1), 165–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergh, A., & Nilsson, T. (2010). Do liberalization and globalization increase income inequality? European Journal of Political Economy, 26(4), 488–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Birdsall, N. (1996). Public spending on higher education in developing countries: too much or too little? Economics of Education Review, 15(4), 407–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanden, J., & Machin, S. (2004). Educational inequality and the expansion of UK higher education. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 51(2), 230–249.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (2000). GMM estimation with persistent panel data: an application to production functions. Econometric Reviews, 19(3), 321–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braumoeller, B. F. (2004). Hypothesis testing and multiplicative interaction terms. International Organization, 58(4), 807–820.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carnoy, M. (1992). The case for investing in basic education. New York: UNICEF.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, B. (1996). Phoenix risen: the resurrection of global finance. World Politics, 48(2), 268–296.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Docquier, F., & Marfouk, A. (2006). International migration by educational attainment, 1990–2000. In C. Ozden & M. Schiff (Eds.), International migration, remittances, and brain drain. Washington: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A. (2006). Does globalization affect growth? Evidence from a new index of globalization. Applied Economics, 38(10), 1091–1110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A., Sturm, J. E., & Ursprung, H. W. (2008). The impact of globalization on the composition of government expenditures: evidence from panel data. Public Choice, 134(3–4), 263–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egger, P., & Radulescu, D. M. (2009). The influence of labour taxes on the migration of skilled workers. World Economy, 32(9), 1365–1379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R. C., & Hanson, G. H. (1999). The impact of outsourcing and high-technology capital on wages: estimates for the United States, 1979–1990. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 907–940.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldberg, P. K., & Pavenik, N. (2007). Distributional effects of globalization in developing countries. Journal of Economic Literature, 45(1), 39–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, A. (1999). Education and globalization in Europe and East Asia: convergent and divergent trends. Journal of Education Policy, 14(1), 55–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grogger, J., & Hanson, G. H. (2011). Income maximization and the selection and sorting of international migrants. Journal of Development Economics, 95(1), 42–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, W. L., & Weisbrod, B. A. (1969). Benefits, costs, and finance of public. Chicago: Markham Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanushek, E. A., & Woessmann, L. (2006). Does educational tracking affect performance and inequality? Differences-in-differences evidence across countries. Economic Journal, 116(510), C63–C76.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haupt, A., & Janeba, E. (2009). Education, redistribution, and the threat of Brain drain. International Tax and Public Finance, 16(1), 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hessami, Z. (2011). Globalization’s winners and losers: evidence from life satisfaction data, 1975–2001. Economics Letters, 112(3), 250–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hines, J. R., & Summers, L. H. (2009). How globalization affects tax design. In J. R. Brown & J. M. Poterba (Eds.), Tax policy and the economy (pp. 123–157). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • James, J. (2002). Information technology, transaction costs and patterns of globalization in developing countries. Review of Social Economy, 60(4), 507–519.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. R., & Obstfeld, M. (2005). International economics: theory and policy. New York: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lassibille, G., & Rasera, B. (1998). UNESCO technical reference manual: statistical information system on expenditure in education (SISEE).

  • Lockheed, M. E., & Verspoor, A. (1991). Improving primary education in developing countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McNeely, C. L. (1995). Prescribing national education policies: the role of international organizations. Comparative Education Review, 39(4), 483–507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naidoo, R., & Jamieson, I. (2005). Knowledge in the marketplace: the global commodification of teaching and learning in higher education. In P. Ninnes & M. HellstTn (Eds.), Internationalizing higher education: critical explorations of pedagogy and policy (pp. 37–51). Dordrecht: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nickell, S. J. (1981). Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica, 49(6), 1417–1426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poutvaara, P. (2000). Education, mobility of labour and tax competition. International Tax and Public Finance, 7, 699–719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poutvaara, P. (2001). Alternative tax constitutions and risky education in a federation. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 31, 355–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poutvaara, P. (2008). Public education in an integrated Europe: studying to migrate and teaching to stay? The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 110(3), 591–608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poutvaara, P., & Kanniainen, V. (2000). Why invest in your neighbor? Social contract on educational investment. International Tax and Public Finance, 7(4), 547–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Psacharopoulos, G. (1985). Returns to education: a further international update and implications. The Journal of Human Resources, 20(4), 583–604.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1997). Trade, social insurance, and the limits to globalization. NBER working paper No. 5905.

  • Roodman, D. (2009a). How to do xtabond2: an introduction to “difference” and “system” GMM in Stata. Stata Journal, 9(1), 86–136.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roodman, D. (2009b). A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71(1), 135–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schulze, G. G., & Ursprung, H. W. (1999). Globalisation of the economy and the nation state. The World Economy, 22(3), 295–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwarz, P. (2007). Does capital mobility reduce the corporate-labor tax ratio? Public Choice, 130(3–4), 363–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shelton, C. (2007). The size and composition of government expenditure. Journal of Public Economics, 91(11–12), 2230–2260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spring, J. (2008). Research on globalization and education. Review of Educational Research, 78(2), 330–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Windmeijer, F. (2005). A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. Journal of Econometrics, 126(1), 25–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wälde, K. (2000). Egalitarian and Elitist education systems as the basis for international differences in wage inequality. European Journal of Political Economy, 16(3), 445–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zodrow, G., & Mieszkowski, P. (1986). Pigou, Tiebout, property taxation, and the underprovision of local public goods. Journal of Urban Economics, 19(3), 356–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors thank the editor-in-chief of this journal Dhammika Dharmapala, two anonymous referees, Heinrich W. Ursprung, Guenther G. Schulze, and participants of the 2010 Royal Economic Society Meeting in Guildford, the 2010 IIPF Meeting in Uppsala, the 2010 Public Choice Society Meeting in Monterey, the 2009 CESifo Political Economy Workshop in Dresden, and of seminars at the University of Basle and the University of Gothenburg for helpful comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Zohal Hessami.

Appendix

Appendix

In this appendix Tables 5 and 6 are presented.

Table 5 Summary statistics, definitions, and data sources
Table 6 Countries included in the sample

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Baskaran, T., Hessami, Z. Public education spending in a globalized world:. Int Tax Public Finance 19, 677–707 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-011-9202-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-011-9202-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation