Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Bounded rationality and social interaction in negotiating a climate agreement

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

An agreement on climate change mitigation hinges on large-scale international cooperation. Rational agents are supposed to consider the cost and benefits of cooperation, which then determine their negotiation positions. Behavioral economics provides experimental evidence that decision-making in negotiation-like situations is influenced by systematic cognitive biases and social interaction. In this paper, we examine the impact of bounded rationality and social preferences on bargaining in international climate negotiations and illustrate how particular deviations from full rationality affect the incentives to cooperate. Of special interest are fairness preferences for burden-sharing rules and behavioral responses to different framings of climate change and policy, as well as implications of these for communication about climate change. The analysis will further address different levels of representation, including individual citizens, politicians, experts, and (professional) negotiators. The consequences of the most prominent nonstandard preferences and biases for negotiating a climate treaty are assessed, and specific strategies to foster cooperation are suggested.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For an overview of theories of multilateral environmental agreements, including behavioral approaches, see van den Bergh and Castells (2004).

  2. In contrast to public goods games where subjects contribute money or effort, in common-pool resource dilemmas players exploit a resource. In game-theoretic terms, both games represent a social dilemma.

  3. Reputation systems in general are used to facilitate interaction of negotiating parties, such as buyers and sellers in e-commerce, such as on e-bay.

  4. The Montreal Protocol is an international environmental agreement on the protection of the ozone layer through the phasing-out of ozone-damaging gases.

  5. There are a number of other reasons why the Montreal Protocol was successfully negotiated fairly quickly: a strong connection between ozone depletion and health, notably the risk of cancer; readily available substitutes for damaging gases; and a relatively small sector of the economy which facilitated a transition. Therefore, a comparison between the Montreal and Kyoto Protocols cannot offer strong conclusions about the effectiveness of incentives to participate.

  6. Rose and Kverndokk (1999) provide an overview of equity criteria to evaluate the distributional consequences of climate policy.

  7. A reviewer suggested that “symbolic politics” is somewhat related (Sears 2001). It stresses the influence of political symbols on political decisions. Examples are political language, the opposition between right and left wing, religious connotations, and family values. Such symbols often elicit emotional rather than rational responses, which in fact gives support to our focus on bounded rationality here.

  8. One might also mention here Cline (2007) who can be seen as close to Stern, both in approach and in conclusions.

References

  • Albin, C. (1993). The role of fairness in negotiation. Negotiation Journal, 9(3), 223–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm-glow giving. Economic Journal, 100, 464–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashraf, N., Karlan, D., & Yin, W. (2006). Tying Odysseus to the mast: Evidence from a commitment savings product in the Philippines. Quarterly Journal of Economics., 121(2), 673–697.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Babiker, M. (2001). Subglobal climate-change actions and carbon leakage: The implication of international capital flows. Energy Economics, 23(2), 121–139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baland, J.-M., & Platteau, J.-P. (1999). The ambiguous impact of inequality on local resource management. World Development, 27(5), 773–788.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (1994). Self-enforcing international environmental agreements. Oxford Economic Papers, 46, 878–894.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (2001). Towards a better climate treaty. World Economics, 3(2), 35–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (2005). Environment and statecraft: The strategy of environmental treaty-making. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (2007). Why cooperate? The incentive to supply global public goods. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S., & McIlveen, R. (2009). Negotiating the next climate change treaty. London: Policy Exchange.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S., & Stavins, R. (2003). Increasing participation and compliance in international climate change agreements. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 3(4), 349–376.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S., & Toman, M. (2010). Contrasting future paths for an evolving global climate regime. Global Policy, 1, 64–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumeister, R., Bratslavsky, E., Finkenauer, C., & Vohs, K. (2001). Bad is stronger than good. Review of General Psychology, 5(4), 323–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bazerman, M., & Neale, M. (1992). Negotiation rationality. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bosetti, V., Carraro, C., & Tavoni, M. (2009). Climate change mitigation strategies in fast-growing countries: The benefits of early action. Energy Economics, 31(2), 144–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Botzen, W. J. W., Bouwer, L., & van den Bergh, J. C. J. M. (2010). Dependence of flood risk perceptions on socio-economic and objective risk factors. Water Resources Research, 48(1), 43–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Botzen, W., & van den Bergh, J. (2009). Bounded rationality, climate risks, and insurance: Is there a market for natural disasters? Land Economics, 85(2), 265–278.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S., & Choi, J. K. (2003). The co-evolution of love and hate. In P. Van Parijs (Ed.), Cultural diversity versus economic solidarity. Proceedings of the seventh Francqui colloquium, Brussels, 28 February–1 March 2003 (pp. 81–97). Brussels: De Boec.

  • Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (2004). Persistent parochialism: Trust and exclusion in ethnic networks. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 55(1), 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowman, D., Minehart, D., & Rabin, M. (1999). Loss aversion in a consumption-savings model. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 38, 155–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. J. (1992). Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation (or anything else) in sizable groups. Ethology and Sociobiology, 13(3), 171–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brekke, K. A., & Johansson-Stenman, O. (2008). The behavioural economics of climate change. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 24(2), 280–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brewer, M. (1999). The psychology of prejudice: Ingroup love or outgroup hate? Journal of Social Issues, 55(3), 429–444.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bryan, G., Karlan, D., & Nelson, S. (2010). Commitment devices. Annual Review of Economics, 2, 671–698.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1984). Politics without romance: A sketch of positive public choice theory and its normative implications. In J. Buchanan & R. Tollison (Eds.), The theory of public choice-II. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cardenas, J. C., Stranlund, J. K., & Willis, C. E. (2002). Economic inequality and burden-sharing in the provision of local environmental quality. Ecological Economics, 40(3), 379–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, J. P. (2004). When in Rome: Conformity and the provision of public goods. Journal of Socioeconomics, 33(4), 395–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carraro, C., & Siniscalco, D. (1993). Strategies for the international protection of the environment. Journal of Public Economics, 52(3), 309–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charness, G., & Dufwenberg, M. (2006). Promises and partnership. Econometrica, 74(6), 1579–1601.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi, J. K., & Bowles, S. (2007). The coevolution of parochial altruism and war. Science, 318(5850), 636–640.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Cline, W. R. (2007). Comments on the Stern review. In Yale symposium on the Stern review, chapter 6. http://www.ycsg.yale.edu/climate/forms/FullText.pdf.

  • Colinsk, J. (1996). Why bounded rationality? Journal of Economic Literature, 34(2), 669–700.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. (1992). Political institutions and pollution control. Review of Economics and Statistics, 74(3), 412–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dannenberg, A., Sturm, B., & Vogt, C. (2010). Do equity preferences matter for climate negotiations? An experimental investigation. Environmental & Resource Economics, 47(1), 91–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doukas, J. A., & Petmezas, D. (2007). Acquisitions, overconfident managers and self-attribution bias. European Financial Management, 13(3), 531–577.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunlap, R., & McCright, A. (2011). Organized climate change denial. In D. Schlosberg, J. Dryzek, & R. Norgaard (Eds.), Oxford handbook of climate change and society (pp. 144–160). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (2007). Explaining social behavior. More nuts and bolts for the social sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fahr, R., & Irlenbusch, B. (2008). Who follows the crowd—Groups or individuals? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 80, 200–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falk, A., Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2005). Driving forces behind informal sanctions. Econometrica, 73(6), 2017–2030.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Falkinger, J., Fehr, E., Gächter, S., & Winter-Ebmer, R. (2000). A simple mechanism for the efficient provision of public goods-experimental evidence. American Economic Review, 90(1), 247–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2002). Why social preferences matter-the impact of non-selfish motives on competition, cooperation and incentives. Economic Journal, 112, C1–C33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2003). The nature of human altruism. Nature, 425, 785–791.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2002). Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature, 415, 137–140.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., Hoff, K., & Kshetramade, M. (2008). Spite and development. The American Economic Review, 98(2), 494–499.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics., 114(3), 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Festinger, L. (1957). A theory of cognitive dissonance. Evanston, IL: Row, Peterson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Finus, M. (2001). Game theory and international environmental cooperation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., & Fehr, E. (2001). Are people conditional cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Economic Letters, 71(3), 397–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fischhoff, B., Slovic, P., & Lichtenstein, S. (1982). Lay foibles and expert fables in judgments about risk. American Statistician, 36, 240–255.

    Google Scholar 

  • Folmer, H., Van Mouche, P., & Ragland, S. (1993). Interconnected games and international environmental problems. Environmental and Resources Economics, 3(4), 313–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fowler, J. (2006). Altruism and turnout. Journal of Politics, 68(3), 674–683.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frederick, S., Loewenstein, G., & O’Donoghue, T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40(2), 351–401.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaser, M., & Weber, M. (2007). Overconfidence and trading volume. Geneva Risk and Insurance Review, 32(1), 1–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gowdy, J. (2008). Behavioral economics and climate change policy. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 68(3–4), 632–644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grothmann, T., & Patt, A. (2005). Adaptive capacity and human cognition: The process of individual adaptation to climate change. Global Environmental Change, 15, 199–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gsottbauer, E., & van den Bergh, J. C. J. M. (2010). Environmental policy theory given bounded rationality and other-regarding preferences. Environmental & Resource Economics, 49(2), 263–304.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, W. D. (1964). The genetical theory of social behavior. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 7, 1–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, J. A. (1979). Individual discount rates and the purchase and utilization of energy-using durables. Bell Journal of Economics, 10, 33–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heitzig, J., Lessmann, K., & Zou, Y. (2011). Self-enforcing strategies to deter free-riding in the climate change mitigation game and other repeated public good games. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 108(38), 15739–15744.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Hilbe, C., & Sigmund, K. (2010). Incentives and opportunism: From the carrot to the stick. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 277(1693), 2427–2433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Howarth, R. B., & Norgaard, R. B. (1993). Intergenerational transfers and the social discount rate. Environmental & Resource Economics, 3(4), 337–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IPCC. (2001). Climate change 2001: Impacts, adaptation and vulnerability. Contribution of working group II to the third assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Retrieved 15 November, 2011.

  • Johnson, D. (2004). Overconfidence and war: The havoc and glory of positive illusions. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, D., & Tierney, D. (2003). Essence of victory: Winning and losing in international crises. Security Studies, 13(2), 350–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones, B. (1999). Bounded rationality. Annual Review of Political Science, 2, 297–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahan, D. M., Braman, D., Gastil, J., Slovic, P., & Mertz, C. K. (2007). Culture and identity protective cognition: Explaining the white-male effect in risk perception. Journal of Empirical Legal Studies, 4(3), 465–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Lovallo, D. (1993). Timid choices and bold forecasts: A cognitive perspective on risk taking. Management Science, 39(1), 17–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Renshon, J. (2006). Why Hawks win. Foreign Policy, 158, 34–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185(4157), 1124–1131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koopmans, R., & Rebers, S. (2009). Collective action in culturally similar and dissimilar groups: An experiment on parochialism, conditional cooperation, and their linkages. Evolution and Human Behavior, 30(3), 201–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuik, O., & Gerlagh, R. (2003). Trade liberalization and carbon leakage. The Energy Journal, 24(3), 97–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lange, A. (2006). The impact of equity-preferences on the stability of international environmental agreements. Environmental & Resource Economics, 34(2), 247–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leiserowitz, A. (2005). American risk perceptions: Is climate change dangerous? Risk Analysis, 2(6), 1433–1442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leiserowitz, A. (2006). Climate change risk perception and policy preferences: The role of affect, imagery, and values. Climatic Change, 77(1), 45–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (1992). Anomalies in intertemporal choice: Evidence and an interpretation. Quarterly Journal of Economics., 107(2), 573–597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maier-Rigaud, F. P., Martinsson, P., & Staffiero, G. (2010). Ostracism and the provision of a public good-experimental evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 73(3), 387–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCright, A., & Dunlap, R. (2011). Cool dudes: The denial of climate change among conservative white males in the United States. Global Environmental Change, 21(4), 1163–1172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McFadden, D. (1999). Rationality for economists? Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 19(1–3), 73–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metcalf, G. E. (1994). Economics and rational conservation policy. Energy Policy, 22(10), 819–825.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milinski, M., Semmann, D., & Krambeck, H.-J. (2002). Reputation helps solve the “tragedy of the commons”. Nature, 415, 424–426.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milinski, M., Semmann, D., Krambeck, H. J., & Marotzke, J. (2006). Stabilizing the Earth’s climate is not a losing game: Supporting evidence from public goods experiments. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 103(11), 3994–3998.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Milinski, M., Sommerfeld, R. D., Krambeck, H. J., Reed, F. A., & Marotzke, J. (2008). The collective-risk social dilemma and the prevention of simulated dangerous climate change. Proceedings of the National Academy of Science USA, 105(7), 2291–2294.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, K. (2009). The limitations of heuristics for political elites. Political Psychology, 30(6), 863–893.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morton, T., Rabinovich, A., Marshall, D., & Bretschneider, P. (2011). The future that (or may not) come: How framing changes responses to uncertainty in climate change communications. Global Environmental Change, 21(1), 103–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (1989). Public choice II. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R., & Winter, S. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nentjes, A., & Klaassen, G. (2004). On the quality of compliance mechanisms in the Kyoto Protocol. Energy Policy, 32(4), 531–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. D. (1992). The “DICE” model: Background and structure of a dynamic integrated climate-economy model of the economics of global warming. Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1009.

  • Nordhaus, W. D. (2008). A question of balance: Weighing the options on global warming policies. New Haven, London: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nowak, M. A., & Sigmund, R. D. (2005). Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature, 437, 1291–1298.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (1999). Incentives for procrastinators. Quarterly Journal of Economics., 114(3), 769–816.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., Walker, J., & Gardner, R. (1992). Convenants with and without a sword: Self-governance is possible. American Political Science Review, 86(2), 404–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paltsev, S. (2001). The Kyoto Protocol: Regional and sectoral contributions to the carbon leakage. The Energy Journal, 22(4), 53–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patt, A. G., & Schröter, D. (2008). Perceptions of climate risk in Mozambique: Implications for the success of adaptation and coping strategies. Global Environmental Change, 18, 458–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rand, D. G., Dreber, A., Ellingsen, T., Fudenberg, D., & Nowak, M. A. (2009). Positive interactions promote public cooperation. Science, 325(5945), 1272–1275.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Rege, M., & Telle, K. (2004). The impact of social approval and framing on cooperation in public good situations. Journal of Public Economics, 88(7–8), 1625–1644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reuben, E., & Riedl, A. (2009). Enforcement of contribution norms in public good games with heterogeneous populations. Cesifo Working Paper No. 2725.

  • Roberts, J. T., & Parks, B. C. (2007). A climate of injustice: Global inequality, North-South politics, and climate policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

  • Rockenbach, B., & Milinski, M. (2006). The efficient interaction of indirect reciprocity and costly punishment. Nature, 444, 718–723.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Rose, A., & Kverndokk, S. (1999). Equity in environmental policy with an application to global warming. In J. C. J. M. van den Bergh (Ed.), The handbook on environmental and resource economics (pp. 352–379). Camberley: Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd.

  • Saijo, T., & Nakamura, H. (1995). The spite dilemma in voluntary contribution mechanism experiments. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 39(1), 535–560.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sears, D. O. (1993). Symbolic politics: A socio-psychological theory. In S. Lyengar & W. J. McGuire (Eds.), Explorations in political psychology (pp. 113–149). Durham, NC: Duke University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sefton, M., Shupp, R., & Walker, J. M. (2007). The effects of rewards and sanctions in provision of public goods. Economic Inquiry, 45(4), 671–690.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shefrin, H. (2010). How psychological pitfalls generated the global financial crisis. Working Paper: Santa Clara University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shogren, J., & Taylor, L. (2008). On behavioral-environmental economics. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 29(1), 26–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics., 69(1), 99–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. (1985). Human nature in politics: The dialogue of psychology with political science. The American Political Science Review, 79(2), 293–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slovic, P., Finucane, M. L., Peters, E., & MacGregor, D. G. (2002). The affect heuristic. In T. Gilovich, D. Griffin, & D. Kahneman (Eds.), Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment (pp. 397–420). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Sommerfeld, R. D., Krambeck, H. J., Semmann, D., & Milinski, M. (2007). Gossip as an alternative for direct observation in games of indirect reciprocity. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 104(44), 17435–17440.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Soroka, S. N. (2006). Good news and bad news: Asymmetric responses to economic information. The Journal of Politics, 68(2), 372–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spence, A., & Pidgeon, N. (2010). Framing and communicating climate change: The effects of distance and outcome frame manipulations. Global Environmental Change, 20(4), 656–667.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stern, N. (2007). The economics of climate change: The Stern Review. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stoll-Kleemann, S., O′Riordan, T., & Jaeger, C. (2001). The psychology of denial concerning climate mitigation measures: Evidence from Swiss focus groups. Global Environmental Change, 11(2), 107–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suedfeld, P., & Tetlock, P. (1991) Psychological advice about political decision making: Heuristics, biases, and cognitive defects. In P. Suedfeld, P. Tetlock (Eds.), Psychology and social policy. Washington, DC: Hemisphere.

  • Tajfel, H., & Turner, J. C. (1979). An integrative theory of intergroup conflict. In W. Austin & S. Worchel (Eds.), The social psychology of intergroup relations (pp. 33–47). Monterey, CA: Brooks/Cole.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tavoni, A., Dannenberg, A., Kallis, G., & Löschel, A. (2011). Inequality, communication, and the avoidance of disastrous climate change in a public goods game. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 108(29), 11825–11829.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Tetlock, P. (2005). Expert political judgment: How good is it? How can we know?. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297–323.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trivers, R. L. (1971). The evolution of reciprocal altruism. Quarterly Review of Biology, 46, 35–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Underdal, A. (1998). Explaining compliance and defection: Three models. European Journal of International Relations, 4(1), 5–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van den Bergh, J. C. J. M., & Castells, N. (2004). International coordination of environmental policies and multilateral environmental agreements. In K. J. Button & D. A. Hensher (Eds.), Handbook of transport and the environment (pp. 515–528). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Evera, S. (1999). Causes of war: Power and the roots of conflict. Ithaca, NY: Cornell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Varian, H. (1974). Equity, envy and efficiency. Journal of Economic Theory, 9, 63–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K. (1989). Prospective reference theory: Toward an explanation of the paradoxes. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 2(3), 235–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viscusi, W. K., & Zeckhauser, R. (2006). The perception and valuation of the risks of climate change: A rational and behavioral blend. Climatic Change, 77, 151–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wade-Benzoni, K. A., Hernandez, M., Medvec, V., & Messick, D. (2008). In fairness to future generations: The role of egocentrism, uncertainty, power, and stewardship in judgments of intergenerational allocations. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 44, 233–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1981). The economies of organization: The transaction cost approach. American Journal of Sociology, 87(3), 548–577.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Younas, J. (2008). Motivation for bilateral aid allocation: Altruism or trade benefits. European Journal of Political Economy, 24(3), 661–674.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful to Wouter Botzen and three anonymous reviewers for useful comments on the paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Elisabeth Gsottbauer.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Gsottbauer, E., van den Bergh, J.C.J.M. Bounded rationality and social interaction in negotiating a climate agreement. Int Environ Agreements 13, 225–249 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10784-012-9182-1

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10784-012-9182-1

Keywords

Navigation