Skip to main content
Log in

Supply and demand structure for international offset permits under the Copenhagen Pledges

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

    We’re sorry, something doesn't seem to be working properly.

    Please try refreshing the page. If that doesn't work, please contact support so we can address the problem.

Abstract

International carbon offsets from developing countries and emerging economies, such as permits from the clean development mechanism, could potentially play an important role for cost containment in domestic greenhouse gas regulation by industrialised countries. Assuming that major emitters such as the EU, the USA, Canada, Japan, Australia and New Zealand implement the “Copenhagen Pledges” and seek cost containment, the potential demand for offset permits is estimated to be 627–667 MtCO2e per year. To describe the supply structure, marginal abatement cost curves for developing countries and emerging economies are derived. Developing countries and emerging economies could supply 627–667 MtCO2e p.a. at costs of approximately EUR 10 (in 2004 EUR), neglecting transaction costs and country-specific risks. The highest potentials for the generation of carbon offsets are present in China, India and the rest of Asia.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Hahn and Richards (2010) provide a comprehensive overview of offset programs in environmental regulation. Tietenberg (2006) summarizes the use of offset permits in emissions trading programs.

  2. These targets contain the 20 % reduction of greenhouse gas emissions, a 20 % increase in energy efficiency, and a 20 % share of renewables in total energy consumption by 2020.

  3. Since the full extent of designs of possible emissions trading systems is not yet known, the costs in Fig. 1 are calculated under the assumption that the trading scheme is applied to all sectors (industry, agriculture, services) of the economy, except for the EU. The regulation design might yield different prices if, for instance, only industrial sectors were covered by an ETS. As it is not clear which design might eventually be implemented in the different regions, we decided to use the actual policy design for the EU and a uniform carbon price for all economic sectors in the other regions.

  4. The APA was a comprehensive proposal for GHG regulation in the USA in 2010 by the Senators Kerry and Lieberman.

  5. The CDM Pipeline can be accessed at http://www.cdmpipeline.org/.

Abbreviations

AAUs:

Assigned amount units

APA:

American power act

BAU:

Business as usual

CAIT:

Climate analysis indicators tool

CDM:

Clean development mechanism

CERs:

Certified emission reductions (permits generated in the CDM)

CGE:

Computable general equilibrium (model)

CO2e:

Carbon dioxide equivalent

COP15:

15th conference of the parties (Copenhagen climate change summit 2009)

EPA:

US Environmental Protection Agency

EU:

European Union

EU ETS:

European emissions trading scheme

EUR:

Euro (Currency)

GHG:

Greenhouse gases

GTAP:

Global trade analysis project

JI:

Joint implementation

LULUCF:

Land use, land-use change and forestry

Mt:

Megatonnes

NAMA:

Nationally appropriate mitigation action

NZ ETS:

New Zealand emissions trading scheme

PACE:

Policy analysis based on computable equilibrium

PoAs:

Programs of activities

REDD:

Reducing emissions from deforestation and degradation

RGGI:

Regional greenhouse gas initiative

ROW:

Rest of the world

UNFCCC:

United Nations framework convention on climate change

USA:

United States of America

WCI:

Western climate initiative

References

  • Australian Treasury (2008). Australian’s low pollution future: The economics of climate change mitigation.

  • Baron, R., Buchner, B., & Ellis, J. (2009). Sectoral approaches and the carbon market. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W. J., & Oates, W. E. (1971). The use of standards and prices for protection of the environment. The Swedish Journal of Economics, 73(1), 42–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Böhringer, C., & Löschel, A. (2008). Climate policy-induced investments in developing countries: The implications of investment risks. The World Economy, 31(3), 367–392.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Böhringer, C., Löschel, A., Moslener, U., & Rutherford, T. F. (2009). EU climate policy up to 2020: An economic impact assessment. Energy Economics, 31, 295–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Capoor, K., & Ambrosi, P. (2008). States and trands of the world carbon market 2008. Washington D.C.: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Criqui, P., Mima, S., & Viguier, L. (1999). Marginal abatement costs of CO emission reductions, geographical flexibility and concrete ceilings: An assessment using the POLES model. Energy Policy, 27, 585–601.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellerman, D. A., Convery, F. J., & De Pertuis, C. (2010). Pricing carbonthe European Union emissions trading scheme. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Elzen den, M., Lucas, P., & Vuuren, D. V. (2005). Abatement costs of post-Kyoto climate regimes. Energy Policy, 33(16), 2138–2151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • EPA (2010). In EPA analysis of the American power act in the 111th congress, Environmental Protection Agency, Washington DC.

  • Frankel, J. (2008). Global environment and trade policy. In J. Mander & E. Goldsmith (Eds.), Harvard project on international climate agreements (Vol. 3, pp. 493–529). World Bank.

  • Hahn R. W., & Richards K. R. (2010). Environmental offset programs: Survey and synthesis. Bloomington: Indiana University School of Public & Environmental Affairs Research Paper No. 2010-12-01.

  • Hall, D. C., Levi, M. A., Pizer, W. A., & Ueno, T. (2010). Policies for developing country engagement. In R. N. Stavins & J. E. Aldy (Eds.), Post-Kyoto international climate policy, implementing architectures for agreement. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heindl, P. (2012). Transaction costs and tradable permits: Empirical evidence from the EU emissions trading scheme. Mannheim: ZEW Discussion Paper No. 12-021.

  • Hof, A. F., Elzen, M. G. J., & Vuuren, D. P. (2008). Environmental effectiveness and economic consequences of fragmented versus universal regimes: What can we learn from model studies? International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 9(1), 39–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Howe, C. W. (1994). Taxes versus tradable discharge permits: A review in the light of the U.S. and European experience. Environmental & Resource Economics, 4(2), 151–169.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IEO (2010). International energy outlook 2010, U.S. Energy Information Administration, Dep. of Energy.

  • Jaffe, A. B., & Stavins, R. N. (1994). The energy paradox and the diffusion of conservation technology. Resource and Energy Economics, 16(2), 91–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, J., & Stavins, R. N. (2009). Linkage of tradable permit systems in international climate policy architecture. In J. E. Aldy & R. N. Stavins (Eds.), Post-Kyoto international climate policy, implementing architectures for agreement. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keeler, A., & Thompson, A. (2010). Mitigation through resource transfers to developing countries: Expanding greenhouse gas offsets. In R. N. Stavins & J. E. Aldy (Eds.), Post-Kyoto international climate policy, implementing architectures for agreement. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, N. O. (2008). Cap and trade, rehabilitated: Using tradable permits to control U.S. greenhouse gases. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 3(1), 42–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kesicki, F., & Ekins, P. (2012). Marginal abatement cost curves: A call for caution. Climate Policy, 12(2), 219–236.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kindermann, G., Obersteiner, M., Sohngen, B., Sathaye, J., Andrasko, K., Rametsteiner, E., et al. (2008). Global cost estimates of reducing carbon emissions through avoided deforestation. Proceedings of the National academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 105(30), 10302–10307.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Kossoy, A., & Ambrosi, P. (2010). State and trands of the carbon market 2010. Washington D.C.: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lederer, M. (2011). From CDM to REDD+—what do we know for setting up effective and legitimate carbon governance? Ecological Economics, 70(11), 1900–1907.

    Google Scholar 

  • Löschel, A., Brockmann, K. L., Heindl, P., Lutz, B., & Schumacher, J. (2011). KfW/ZEW CO2 Barometer 2011: Hoher Anpassungsbedarf im EU-Emissionshandel ab 2013deutliche Defizite bei der Vorbereitung in den Unternehmen. Frankfurt am Main. Retrieved from http://ftp.zew.de/pub/zew-docs/co2panel/CO2Barometer2011.pdf.

  • Meckling, J. O., & Chung, G. Y. (2009). Sectoral approaches for a post-2012 climate regime: A taxonomy. Climate Policy, 9(6), 652–668.

    Google Scholar 

  • Metcalf, G. E. (2009). Cost containment in climate change policy: Alternative approaches to mitigating price volatility. University of Virginia Tax Review, 29(2), 381–405.

    Google Scholar 

  • Michaelowa, A., & Jotzo, F. (2005). Transaction costs, institutional rigidities and the size of the clean development mechanism. Energy Policy, 33(4), 511–523.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montgomery, W. D. (1972). Markets in licenses and efficient pollution control programs. Journal of Economic Theory, 5, 395–418.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Narayanan, B. G., & Walmsley, T. L. (2008). Global trade, assistance, and production: The GTAP 7 data base. Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University.

  • Nemet, G. F. (2010). Cost containment in climate policy and incentives for technology development. Climatic Change, 103(3–4), 423–443.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neuhoff, K. (2011). Climate policy after Copenhagen. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Newell, R. G., & Pizer, W. A. (2003). Regulating stock externalities under uncertainty. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 45(2), 416–432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W. D. (2006). After Kyoto: Alternative mechanisms to control global warming. The American Economic Review, 96(2), 31–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pizer, W. (2002). Combining price and quantity controls to mitigate global climate change. Journal of Public Economics, 85(3), 409–434.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, M. J., & Spence, M. (1976). Effluent charges and licenses under uncertainty. Journal of Public Economics, 5, 193–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sawa, A. (2010). Sectoral approaches to a Post-Kyoto international climate policy framework. In R. N. Stavins & J. E. Aldy (Eds.), Post-Kyoto international climate policy, implementing architectures for agreement. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schneider, L. (2009). Assessing the additionality of CDM projects: Practical experiences and lessons learned. Climate Policy, 9(3), 242–254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skutsch, M. M., & McCall, M. K. (2010). Reassessing REDD: Governance, markets and the hype cycle. Climatic Change, 100(3–4), 395–402.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sohngen, B., & Mendelsohn, R. (2007). A sensitivity analysis of carbon sequestration. In M. E. Schlesinger, H. Khesgi, J. B. Smith, F. Chesnaye, J. Reilly, T. Wilson, & C. D. Kolstad (Eds.), Human-induced climate change: An interdisciplinary assessment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Sterk, W., & Wittneben, B. (2006). Enhancing the clean development mechanism through sectoral approaches: Definitions, applications and ways forward. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 6(3), 271–287.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tietenberg, T. (2006). Emissions trading: Principles and practice. Washington D.C.: RFF Press.

  • Wada, K., Sano, F., Akimoto, K., & Homma, T. (January, 2012). Assessment of Copenhagen pledges with long-term implications. Energy Economics. doi 10.1016/j.bbr.2011.03.031.

  • Weitzman, M. L. (1974). Prices vs. quantities. The Review of Economic Studies, 41(4), 477–491.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood, P. J., & Jotzo, F. (2011). Price floors for emissions trading. Energy Policy, 39(3), 1746–1753.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Henrike Koschel (KfW Bankengruppe), Bodo Sturm (Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW)/Univ. of Applied Science, Leipzig), Andreas Löschel (Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW)/University of Heidelberg), Frank Jotzo (Australian National University), the Klimaschutzfonds of KfW Bankengruppe and the participants of seminars held at ZEW in January 2011, at the University of Heidelberg in February 2011 and at the EAERE Annual Meeting in Rome in June 2011 as well as two anonymous referees for useful comments and discussion.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Peter Heindl.

Appendix

Appendix

See Table 7.

Table 7 Regions and sectors of the PACE model version used for the current analysis

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Heindl, P., Voigt, S. Supply and demand structure for international offset permits under the Copenhagen Pledges. Int Environ Agreements 12, 343–360 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10784-012-9171-4

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10784-012-9171-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation